WHY INTERESTS RATES HAVE BEEN RISING

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP57-00384R001200010003-6
Release Decision: 
RIFPUB
Original Classification: 
K
Document Page Count: 
4
Document Creation Date: 
December 20, 2016
Document Release Date: 
July 11, 2001
Sequence Number: 
3
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
July 1, 1953
Content Type: 
MAGAZINE
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP57-00384R001200010003-6.pdf421.48 KB
Body: 
Approved For Release 2007/02/24: CIA-RDP57-00384R001200010003-6 Why Interest Rates Have Been Rising E. SHERMAN ADAMS Deputy Manager of the American Bankers Association in charge of the Department of Monetary Policy W. HAROLD BRENTON, presi- dent of the American Bankers Association, re- cently stated: "W e can't expect some 'Of our citizens to understand the justifica- tion for higher interest rates under existing conditions unless they are told the reasons. It then logically follows that bankers should explain to their customers the role of inter- est rates in a free enterprise econ- omy." Businessmen and individuals have been finding that borrowing has be- come less easy and more costly. Some have the impression that either the Federal Reserve System or the banks, or perhaps both, have somehow been "pushing up" inter- est rates. It is hard for them to see how tighter money contributes to the welfare of the American Nevertheless there is widespread people. agreement among competent author- Actually, the whole cause of sound ities on the broad principles of mon- monetary policy is involved. For etary policy, and these fundamentals although the Federal Reserve Sys- can be understood by non-experts. tem has not been "pushing up" in- The essential points which should terest rates, the rise in rates does re- be more widely known and under- fleet the fact that, for several years, stood, can be summarized as fol- the System has not prevented them lows : from hardening. This policy has helped to halt the erosion that had been taking place for years in the purchasing power of the American dollar. It operates today as a safe- guard against renewed inflation. Explaining the role of interest rates to the public is by no means an easy assignment. A whole new generation has grown up which has never before seen anti-inflationary monetary policy in action. The sub- ject is rather technical and on some aspects the experts disagree. (1) Like all other prices, in- terest rates-the price of credit- are the result of supply and de- mand forces, except when they are rigidly dictated by govern- ment. INTEREST rates reflect the relation- ship between the supply of loanable funds and the demand for them. When demand is large relative to supply, interest rates inevitably tend to rise. When the opposite July 1953 Reprinted f roan 1NK[NG--Journa1 of the American Bari , Association.-.fitly 1953 Approved For Release 2007/02/24: CIA-RDP57-00384R001200010003-6 Approved For Release 2007/02/24: CIA-RDP57-00384R001200010003-6 situation prevails, rates decline. For many years before World War II, for example, the sup- ply of funds was large and, with business in the doldrums, demands for money were small. As a result, interest rates persistently declined to the lowest levels on record. During the war, the Government's needs for borrowed money were enormous. To facilitate this bor- rowing and to hold down its cost, the Federal Reserve System, through its open-market operations, main- tained a fixed pattern of rates for Treasury borrowing throughout the war. (2) The fundamental reason for the hardening of interest rates since 1945 is the business boom, which, like all booms, has been accompanied by large demands for credit. DURING a boom, everybody wants to borrow. The businessman wants to increase his inventory, buy new machinery, expand his plant. The public, fully employed and optim- istic, wants to borrow to buy new homes, new cars, new appliances. That, of course, is just what has been happening in this country, on an unprecedented scale, ever since the end of World War II. And the Federal Government, for most of these years has been borrowing too. This huge demand for credit is the basic reason why interest rates have been rising. Market yields on long-term Treasury bonds turned upward early in 1946, and short- term rates started up in 1947. For several years, the rise was gradual. Banks were eager to make loans and, in addition, the Federal Re- serve System, for a variety of rea- sons, kept pumping out more funds in support of the market for Govern- ment securities. (3) The public welfare nor- mally requires that money should tighten and that interest rates should rise when inflation threat- ens. WHEN credit expands at a reason- able rate, it performs a vital func- tion of financing increased produc- tion and consumption. It is when credit expands too fast that we get into trouble. When our economy is operating at full capacity, then a big increase in borrowing and spend- ing is bound to bid up prices. Under these circumstances, a substantial increase in credit, even for "pro- ductive purposes," turns out to be unproductive and inflationary from the standpoint of the economy as a whole. The best way to prevent such an overexpansion of credit is simply to permit the increased demands of borrowers to cause some tightening of credit and some hardening of interest rates. This curbs the ex- pansion of credit in two ways : Some potential borrowers are dis- couraged by the higher cost; others, usually the least creditworthy, are unable to obtain credit accommoda- tion. The alternative would be inflation and instability. The cost of higher rates is negligible compared with the toll taken from everyone's pock- et by inflation. It is infinitesimal measured against the losses of in- come that occur when an inflation- ary boom leads to a depression. Sound monetary policy is in the interest of the entire community. (4) Since the outbreak of the Korean war, the Federal Reserve has permitted credit to tighten in order to combat the threat of in- flation. THE outbreak of the Korean war generated renewed demands for credit. As always, this tended to tighten credit conditions. Bank loans had doubled since the end of World War II, and many banks were beginning to "run out of money." Since Korea, bank loans have increased another 50 percent, so more and more banks have been approaching the position of being "loaned up." The Federal Reserve System could have kept credit easy if it had de- cided to pump out all the additional funds required to meet the increased demands. Obviously, however, such a policy would have provided no restraint against excessive credit expansion. The Reserve System has therefore followed a policy of trying to supply enough additional funds to finance increased production but, at the same time, to prevent credit from expanding too fast. In short, it has curbed inflationary pressures by permitting the abnormal demands for borrowing to tighten credit con- ditions. Its most dramatic move was in March of 1951 when, with the Treasury's acquiescence, it stopped supporting Government bonds at par. Before that, life insurance companies and other lenders had been able to sell Governments to the Federal at par or better and thereby obtain additional funds to invest in mortgages and new cor- porate bond issues. This made available a virtually unlimited sup- ply of cheap long-term credit. By stopping its support of Government bonds at par, the Federal Reserve ceased to be an engine of inflation. (5) Interest rates are still rela- tively low for this stage of the business cycle. INTEREST rates today appear high only in comparison with the excep- tionally low rates which developed during the long period of depressed business preceding World War II. It was an historical accident that these very low rates happened to prevail at the time of Pearl Harbor and were therefore used as a basis for the low pattern of rates adopted for the Treasury's wartime fi- nancing. When we emerged from the war with a vastly swollen public debt, there was a strong desire to keep rates low in spite of their inflationary effects. This largely explains why rates are still low in comparison with other prosperous periods. Despite more than a decade of almost un- interrupted boom-the biggest in our history-most interest rates are substantially lower than before the Big Depression. For example, as compared with an average rate of more than 51/2 percent for the Twenties, lending rates of banks in principal cities averaged 31/2 per- cent during the first quarter of 1953. The Federal Reserve discount rate of 2 percent today compares with 6 and 7 percent in 1920 and a range of 3 to 6 percent for the rest of the Twenties. sow Approved For Release 2007/02/24: CIA-RDP57-00384R001200010003-6 Approved For Release 2007/02/24: CIA-RDP57-00384R001200010003-6 (6) The trend of interest rates has been upward throughout most of the free world in recent years. I N virtually every country of the free world, interest rates are now higher than they were before World War II, and considerably higher than in the immediate postwar pe- riod. In fact, the rise in long-term rates in the United States has been moderate compared with increases elsewhere. Our long-term rates are well below general world levels. Compared with the Federal Re- serve's discount rate of 2 percent, rates of central banks in the United Kingdom, France, Germany, Neth- erlands, Belgium, and Sweden range from 3 to 4 percent. (7) The present level of in- terest rates does not result in ex- cessive earnings for banks and other lenders. Nqwp~ orbitant profits" for banks and other creditors. This, they say, is a "bare-faced steal" from the pock- ets of debtors and taxpayers. It is true, of course, that low interest rates do benefit borrowers but only at the expense of savers and other lenders. For about two decades, borrowers have never had it so good, but savers have never had it so bad. The long period of low interest rates greatly increased the cost of life insurance and private pension plans. It seriously reduced the income of endowments, hospi- tals, educational institutions, and others. The real answer, however, is that to the extent that higher interest rates contribute to a stable economy and a stable dollar, they are benefi- cial to all groups-and particularly to the taxpayers who must pay for a vast rearmament program. As for the banks, tighter money is by no means an unmixed blessing. It has restricted the growth of their loans and investments and has caused substantial losses and de- preciation in their bond portfolios. Higher interest rates have induced many corporations to draw down SOME of the proponents of always- easy-money contend that higher in- terest rates are resulting in "ex- A their bank balances to invest in short-term Government securities. Finally, part of the Federal Re- serve's restrictive program was a SELECTED INTEREST RATES.1910 -1953 INCREASED DEMANDS FOR CREDIT J HAVE BEEN PUSHING INTEREST RATES UPWARD FOR SEVERAL YEARS High IGrade Bond Yields* 7- Bank Rates on Business Loans 2" - \ I ARE STILL LOW F I COMPARED WITH Prime Commercial Paper BEFORE THE BIG DEPRESSION 0' a I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I l I l i i p 910 1915 1920 1925 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 19530 Composite series: 1900.19 Standard Statistics' High-Grade Railroad Bonds. 192030 Moody's Aaa Railroad Bonds 1931-53 Moody's Aaa Public Utility Bonds i d se A Federal Reserve series, rates on short-term loans in principal cities. R ? series rev V Federal Reserve series, 4.6 month paper in New York City boost in bank reserve requirements in 1951 and this deprived the banks of the use of about $2-billion of their assets. At this stage of the business cycle, with loans at record levels, the banks ought to be showing really good earnings. Last year net profits of all member banks aver- aged less than 8 percent of total capital accounts, and dividends amounted to only 3.7 percent. If this is the best the banks can do at such a time, what will their pos- ition be when the abnormal demands for credit subside and interest rates again decline? This situation is reflected in the fact that most bank stocks are quoted at less than their book values. The verdict of the invest- ment market is that bank earnings are not too satisfactory. (8) The existence of market depreciation in bank bond ac- counts is no reason for objecting to the principle that interest rates should be permitted to rise. THERE are many bank directors- and probably some bankers-who do not understand, and are unhappy *401 1`11 Approved For Release 2007/02/24: CIA-RDP57-00384R001200010003-6 Approved For Release 2007/02/24: CIA-RDP57-00384R001200010003-6 about, the depreciation in their banks' bond portfolios. The fact is, of course, that rising interest rates mean declining bond prices-they are, indeed, synony- mous. The market yields of Govern- ment securities are the basic inter- est rates which affect the level of all other rates. When these market rates of interest on Government ob- ligations are low, all other rates tend to be low. When they rise, all other rates tend to rise. It would be nice, from the stand- point of lenders, to have both high money rates and high bond prices, but that is literally impossible. We simply cannot have it both ways. One consolation about lower bond prices is that new investments can now be made at higher rates than formerly. Another, for most banks, is that bond depreciation is largely academic because most of those book losses will never have to be- come real losses. The average bank will probably achieve somewhat bet- ter earnings in 1953 than last year or the year before, and it is these actual results, after all, that really matter. Finally, some banks can use bond losses to good advantage for tax purposes. But the real, answer is that it is essential to the health of a free enterprise economy that interest rates should be flexible. That means bond prices will decline under cer- tain conditions as well as rise under others. Moreover, it is not the banker's job to try to outguess the bond market. These fundamental facts about the banking business should be understood by every bank director. (9) Discussion of the Treas- ury's recent offering of long-term bonds has greatly exaggerated its actual importance. THE dramatic and controversial aspects of the Treasury's recent bond issue have attracted much at- tention. The chief significance of the offering is that it indicated a change from the policy of the past seven years. It also unsettled the bond market. Viewed in perspective, however, the offering of $1-billion of long- term Treasury bonds at 31/4 percent is, in itself, something less than Ifto, VW epochal. It will be recalled, for ex- restraint has been in the ample, that during the 13 years preceding 1946, the Treasury was continually bringing out new long- term bond issues-far more, in fact, than had previously been issued in our entire history. Taking taxabil- ity and tax rates into account, many of those offerings involved a higher net cost to the Treasury than the new 31/4s. Moreover, most of them were made when the difference in cost between short-term and long- term financing was considerably greater that it is today. The size of the new issue is, of course, small. It is about one-tenth as large as the last offering of mar- ketable long-term bonds under the Truman Administration. It repre- sents less than 2 percent of the Treasury's obligations due this year. It is about half of 1 percent of the total debt. Its main effect upon the economy is that it has absorbed some savings which otherwise would have gone into capital expenditures. But with private investment now at a $54- billion annual rate and with gross national product exceeding $360- billion, a Treasury bond offering of $1-billion does not look very significant. (10) It is the overwhelming informed consensus that the Fed- eral Reserve has been right in its general policy of permitting credit conditions to tighten. MANY economists would word this proposition even more emphatically. In fact, most would probably agree with the recent assertion of Chair- man Martin of the Federal Reserve Board that the stability of the American economy over the past two years would not have been achieved without the contribution made by Federal Reserve policy. There is some disagreement among the experts, naturally, with respect to certain of the Federal Reserve's actions. Judgments are always bound to differ as to ex- actly how an agreed-upon principle should be applied under various cir- cumstances. However, the main point is that there is almost com- plete unanimity among competent authorities on the broad proposition that a monetary policy of moderate transparently clear when one con- siders the alternative. To keep cred- it easy during such a period would be to invite over-expansion and over-speculation, and thereby sow the seeds for a depression. It would be a public misfortune if monetary policy were to become a political football. Nor would it make sense either logically or his- torically. The principle of flexibil- ity of interest rates has repeatedly received bipartisan endorsement by the Joint Committee on the Econ- omic Report. The present policy of credit restraint was initiated under a Democratic administration and has been developed under three Re- serve Board chairmen who were ap- pointed by Democratic presidents. It has not been basically altered by the shift to a Republican adminis- tration. Conclusion What of the future? As long as the boom continues, the Federal Re- serve intends to adhere to a re- strictive policy. This could easily mean some further tightening of credit. The degree of restraint that is ap- propriate as conditions change is obviously an extremely complex problem which the Federal Reserve authorities are constantly studying. The degree of restriction to date has been moderate. If desired, pres- sure could easily be increased. On the other hand, past experience has demonstrated that there are serious dangers involved in putting on the credit brakes too hard. When the current boom subsides, private demands for credit will slacken and credit will therefore tend to ease. When that happens, it is to be expected that the Federal Reserve will promptly reverse its policy and permit rates to decline. Over the years, this alternative eas- ing and tightening of credit can make an important contribution to the stability of our economy. In a democracy such as ours, sound monetary policy cannot sur- vive and be truly effective without the support of the public, and this, in turn, requires understanding. Bankers have a public obligation, as well as a duty to their own in- stitutions, to do what they can to contribute to that understanding. -Awe Approved For Release `2007/02/24: CIA-RDP57-00384R001200010003-6