DIRECTION OF PLANNING AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT IN INDIA AND CHINA BY ALEXANDER ECKSTEIN

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
K
Document Page Count: 
16
Document Creation Date: 
November 9, 2016
Document Release Date: 
December 22, 1998
Sequence Number: 
5
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
April 1, 1955
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7.pdf854.51 KB
Body: 
a Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 RUS3Th.N RESE&RCH CENTER MIRVARD UNIVERSITY Direction of Planning and Economic Development in India and China by Alexander Eckstein A paper read at the Washington D.C. meetings of the Far Eastern Association on March 30, 1955 This manuscript has been reproduced as a convenience to scholars working in this field. All rights of publication and reproduction remain with the author. The manuscript must not be quoted or reproduced in any form without written permission from the author, Cambridge, Mass. Aprils, 1955 Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 4Fr'65d[Oar Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 DIRECTION OF PL&NHING &ND ECONOMIC DEVILO.PMx"NT IN INDIA AND CHINK* India and China .G, the two largest countries in the underdeveloped 3 part of the world with a combined population of close to one billion and an economic inheritance compounded of many analogous elements, are both pursuing programs of economic development within the context of their first Five-Year Plans. Whatever the parallelism in the drive for e.cmpomic. growth which motivates,_:the. ie4er..s and the peo.nle: of the two countries, the paths which each intends to follow are markedly dissimilar. These oaths represent, in a very real sense, two vastly different types of approaches to economic development. India is usually cited as the orototyoe of democratic planning in an underdeveloped area, while China is the carrier of the communist model in Asia. This dichotomy inevitably poses a host of questions as to the power implications and the political aopeal of the two models. Within this broader context, this paper will focus upon an analysis of actual plan performance in agriculture and industry against the background of the two development models, 1. The deve o meet models In China, the new Communist regime formulated an industrialization program patterned largely on the Soviet model, Thus, the Chinese In this paper the author has drawn upon the research he and Professor I4alenbaum of MIT have been enraged in concerning contrasting patterns of economic development in India and China. I am indeed greatly indebted to Prof. Idalenbaum, Mrs. Helen Lamb and Dr. Joseph Froomkin for their comments on this paper, 1 According to the 1951 Census, the population of the Republic of India was 35669 million; official results of the 1953 China Mainland Census point to a population of 581,8 million. pproved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 CPYRGHT Communists envisage a development focused on the rapid expansion of prgducerss goods and defense industries. This is to be accompanied. by a more modest rate of growth in the manufacture of textiles needed for barter with the countryside. At the same time, agriculture is to be developed primarily through mobilization of underemployed farm labor for water conservation and other labor-intensive projects. In essence, it is a model which envisages industrial development at the expense of agricultural development. Industrialization is accelerated. at the outset, by virtue of the very fact that since agriculture is kept on, a short investment ration, a larder share of investment resources can be concentrated in industry. This policy,' in turn, sets up ?-its own vicious circles; just because agricultural development Is sluggish,, while the demand for farm products grows - owing to an increasing population, urbanization, and exports the regime is forced to extract a rising proportion of farm output if this demand is to be met. This very process, however, further interferes with agricultural development so that the screw must be apulied even tighter and under such circumstances ear;a output is sacrificed for control and strong compulsions are set in force that drive the system towards collectivization, Within the framework of this tyre of a development model, the state provides a guaranteed market for the goods and services produced so that deficiency in effective demand is not one of the factors limiting a erowth, except possibly in` short-run frictional sense. On the contrary, l See for instance Chou En-lai s Report on Government work to the First Session of the First National People's Congress NCN Supplement No. 2l8 , Oct. 14, 1954. Approved For Dnlnas 1999/09/7, r`IA_RDPS3_00123 00200025000x._7 Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 CPYRGHT the more effectively consumption can be kept in check the higher will be the rates of growth under cater is ribus asenmotions. Under such conditions, government nolcy will be dedicated to keeping consumption at the lowest levels compatible with (a) political stability, i.e. maintenance of the regime in power and (b) the requirements of raising nonfarm labor productivity. Thus, in this type of a totalitarian model,, changes in consumption need not be a function of changes in income even in a long-run sense. The Indian path, on the other hand, is based upon a more or lees democratic framework. Consequently, freedom of consumer choice and resource allo cation through the pricing and market mechanism plays a much more important role. This, in turn, yields a number of corollary effects. Thus, great reliance is placed upon voluntary saving. The nationalized sector of the economy is much teller and generally the state's participation in the economy Is much more modest. As a general rronasition# one may consider the Chinese Communist Program as primarily oower.orientede i.e. designed to maximize the rate it which internal control is extended and consolidated while the external 'u "maki.ng, defense, and international political -potential is augmented, he central focus is upon the develipment of heavy industry, with a ower order of priority assigned to consumer Foods industries and agriculture. In contrast, the Indian -orogram is largely-welfare-oriented, th one of its central objectives the, improvement of rural welfare. is necessarily implies a high order of priority for agricultural develop- vent and the expansion of industries serving agriculture, with less emphasis upon industrialization . ,fie, Thus, while in the Chinese case %e central objective is to maximize the rate of industrial, growth, the Rndian focus is upon maximizing the rate of improvement in standards of living. Apart from these broad ideolog.ct1 considerations there are certain specific factors which account for the much greater rural emphasis in the first Indian .Five Year Plan at least. One of these in certainly the whole C,a dhian tradition and influence. i.nother0 is the serious food shortage problem facing India after Partition. And a third is the comparatively low crop yields per unit of land in India, or instance, rice yields were half, wheat yields were about two-third, and cotton yields were at about 40 per cent of the Chinese mainland levela1 Therefore, the opportunities for raising yields relatively ra,)idly, through improved farm practices and extension of the irrigated area are much better for India than for China. The differing roles assigned to aPriculture and industry in the- development plans of India and China may -oerhaps best be illustrated by a comparison of the pattern of investment allocation in the two countries. This comparison is based on 1934-38 yields for India and 1931-37 yields for 9? provinces of China. Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 CPYRGHT Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423ROO2000250005-7 a Table I I.xzvestment Allocation In India and China Per Cent India China Investment Plane 1951/52-545/56 A-ctual investments., Public 'fly Pub 1953-54 i.gri cul Lure 17 15 ) 1. Irrigation 71 14 ) Transport and Com'Au ications 18 15 Induotry 14 75 49 Other P4 2 24 Sources to Table I: Government of India, PlanningCommission, Live Year Plan Pro,eress Report for 1953?54, New Delhi, September 1954, pa 11. Wilfred Malenbaum: Savines and Investment in India (Mimeogro) CENTS No, C 54.10 May 17r 19549 P. 9. Teng Hsiao-ping: Report of Minister of Finance on the 1954 State Bum at the 31st Meeting of the Central People's Government Council held on June 16 and 17, 1954 -- NCN . Bulletin, London, Supplement No. 704, June ?4, 1954. Before apnraising these figures, it must be pointed out that they are not completely comparable. In China, public investment through the state budget is virtually equivalent to total investments it of course excludes self financed outlays by small entrepreneurs and farmers, however these could not have constituted a very significant item by 1953-54. On the other hand, in India,, about 40 per cent of planned investment was to come from the vrivate sector. As a matter of fact, there are no reliable estimates for private investment, planned or actual, so that the only firm items are planned government outlays. Moreover, sector defini. tions are somewhat different in India and China and the planners in the two countries work with somewhat varying investment concepts. However, Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423ROO2000250005-7 CPYRGHT Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 even if one discounts for all of these possible sources of error, the differences in the two investment patterns are striking. In China, industry?s share of investment resources is twice as high as in India, while the position of agriculture is exactly reversed. A similar picture emerges if one looks at the reverse side of the coin, namely the land tax burden borne by agriculture. In China apnroxi- mately 15 to '0 per cent of net agricultural product goes into direct 1 taxes, while in India the corresponding share is only 1 to 1;5 per cent, plan Performance in Agri. culture The differences in the roles of the rural sector in the development of India and China have been greatly reinforced by the patterns of p^oduction as they actually emerged during the first planning years. Thus, in the case of India, agricultural -production targets were markedly exceeded, while in China farm outout has been lagging below planned levels, By the end of the third planning year (1953-54). Indian grain production targets for the whole Five Year Plan period were exceeded by 50 per cent. By the same time, three fourths of the cotton output increase programmed for 1955/56 was attained.2 In China, on the other hand, on the basis of official figures, the output of grain ro se only by about 4 per cent in two years, as compared to a highly unrealistic five year expansion target of 30 percent. For instance, the official 1953 -production figure is 165 1 These percentages do not, of course, measure the total tax burden borne by agriculture, since they leave out of account proceeds from indirect taxes and quasi--taxes. While there is no way of measuring this total burden with the limited data available, indirect tax rates in India would have to be much higher than in China to make up for the much lower yield from direct taxes. On basis of all of the available evidence this does not seem to be the case. The estimate for China is based oh the Chinese Communist budget figures adjusted for under-valuation of the tax grain price and on the author s estimate of national -product.. For India it is based on aggregate_ land and agricultural income tax revenue of the States, given in the an Prr}rrens ~R-e'9/994;41P-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 App i' MFFTelease 1999/09/24: CIA-R6483-00423R002000250005-7 million tons compared to an annual target of 175 million. In cotton, 1 output actually declined between 195> and 1954, It would, of course, be erroneous to ascribe these divergent tendencies exclusively to "differences in vlanriing techniques or patterns of invest- ment allocation. India, after several successive droughts, was blessed by two exceptionally favorable monsoons. App 4cco rdi ng to the Planning Commissions own tentative estimate, "out of the total increased productio3 of foodgrains of 11.4 million tons, something like 5 to 6 million tons represent a more or less permanent gain" attributable to an extension of irriga tion and land reclamation and to growing use of fertilizer. There may also have been some increase in "invisible" investment in Indian agriculture, i.e. investment which is non-monetary in character, performed with materials and labor available on the farm. These are the types of Investment that are very difficult to measure and thus tend to be greatly underestimated in the national accounts for most of the underdeveloped areas. They are the kind of investments that may be uarticularly responsive to changes in the structure of incentives. `While there are no data that would hermit one to really document this, given the general orientation of planning, the emphasis upon village development, the beginnings of, land reform, and the favorable weather conditions, it would indeed be surprising if there had been no rise in peasant. Incentives in India. On the Chinese mainland, the pattern was almost exactly reversed; three increasingly favorable crop years were followed by a bad drought in 1953 and a very serious flood in 1954. However, just as in India larger inputs of capital and production requisites contributed to the improvement, so the failure to aprly similar measures in China - on any- thing approaching a comparable scale - was undoubtedly a factor in hampe- ring agricultural growth there. Pe ' l rove~FoW g,se~f'9/0 4 : bIA-)4PP8~66~2Shb0`26bn5a~el~rch 1953; .aX y _ , Pek e ne, CPYRGHT 3o Plan Performance in Industry Quite a different picture emerges if one eomnares industrial per- formance under the two plans. As is shown by the data in Table III o:: all products listed - except for cement =- growth was significantly more rapid in China during two years than in India during three. This does not gainsay the fact that in some fields such as textiles and cement significant advances have been registered in India. However, moot of the increase in India could be attained with better utilization of previously underutilized capacity. In China, on the other hand, capacity limits were being approached on the eve of the plan, so that the increases for 1953 and 1954 reouired rapidly expanding capacity. Tab 1e1I Out ,out of Selected Industrial Pr ducts in India and China Product Pr Plain Year P oducti n Production Increase Attained During the Planning Period x die China ndia ni 1: 0 12=2 1201 51` 12 SJ i , . . Pig Iron ; 19572 1,580 79 75 Finished. )i,n steel )000vs 976 1,945 105 756 of metric Coal tons 37,300 57,400 3967- 15,737 Cement ) 2, 69;? 9E, 460 1.336 1, ?- j- Cotton yarn (in 000,000 lbs,) 1,179 341 Electric power (in 000?000 kwh) 5,300 6,811 1,6o0 39764 Sources to Table It Five Year an Progress $eport, op.cit, .The Pronpecte for Communist China, appendix One. 22mmunioue by the State Statistical Bureau Current Events Handbook, Peiping, Sept. 12, 1;54 Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 -9- Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 Thus, the differing rates of industrial expansion reflect to a large extent the differing investment policies pursued in the two countries. Just for purposes of illustration, 1954 industrial Invest- ment in India may be roughly estimated at less than 2 per cent of GNP, For China, on the basis of rather crude calculations, it may be placed at about 6 per cent. Perhaps it may be fair to say that in some respects the Indian plan has been an outstanding success, in that during the past three years output has been appreciably raised in all commodity sectors. However, there is a real question as to what extent the Plan or planning can take credit for these favorable developments, and whether this could not have been accomplished in the absence of a live Year Plan. In a very real sense, the investment program represents the core, the major strategic lever of an economic plan. However, this is precisely the field in which there is a significant shortfall with only about 40 per cent of the total outlay programmed for the five year period, actually Invested during the first three years. For industrial investment, plan fulfillment was even lower, less than one-third of expenditure proerammed for the plan period was dis- bursed by the end of the third year. It is particularly notable that the governments investment plan, which was quite modest to begin with, fell far behind the much more sizable private investment program. A case could be made for the view that the Indian eovernment's economic policy places it in a position where it lives in the worst of two This includes both private and public investment; see Five Year Plan REggress Report, op.cit., p. 164. CPYRCHT By the end of the third year the government bad invested only 19 per cent of the five year outlay programmed for industry; the private industrial sector the other hand, completed about 41 per cent of its program. rive Year Plan Approvedl*= tele id899t6 RDP83edO423RO02A00S5.90D6LA. Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 possible worlds. On the one hand, it has pursued a very cautious and orthodox monetary fiscal and balance of payments policy, has been quite conservative in its own investment commitments, and on the other hand it has done very little to encourage and foster private investment. Behind Indian fiscal and monetary management there always seemed to lur.: the shadow of a feared inflation. Actually, it is very questionable whether an active and vigorous development policy, doesn't almost tably bring with It a certain measure of inflationary pressure, n upward pressure on prices of modest and gradual proportions need not necessarily bring with it the usually cited maleffects inherent in runaway infla- tion. However, there are definite signs that Indian government policy is gradually changing in this as well as in some other respects., Possibly were one viewing this period from a perspective of say 1960 or 1965, one might date development planning in India as beginning in the fourth year of the first Plan and then merging into the second Plan. These indications seem to point to a less orthodox fiscal and monetary policy, combined with higher levels of government investment, and with greater emphasis placed upon industrialization. In the past, the Indian government's policy towards private enterprise has been suite ambivalent. To some extent it is based on a mixture of socialist and populist attitudes, combined with a certain mistrust of the Indian entrepreneur, a fear of large concentrations of private wealth and power, counterbalanced by a recognition of the important managerial and technical contribution to be made by the .: erttrepreneur1, Actually, however, it would be very difficult to establien whether these government attitudes really play a major role in shaping private management and investment decisions. It would seem that Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 insufficiency of effective demand, the narrowness of the market, plays a much more important role than government-enterprise relations. One could go even further and maintain that in a rapidly expanding economy the gains to be made by getting on the bandwagon would more than outweigh the fears and suspicions of private entrepreneurs. In effect, I would argue that the crux of the problem is more active government participa- tion in the Indian economy, both as an investor and as a buyer. Such a policy would not only stimulate growth in the public sector but would also tend to contribute to a much more favorable vrivate investment climate, therefore, it need not be incompatible with objectives of democratic planning or of private entrepreneurial activity. Of course, these are problems which the. Chinese Communist planners need not face. They are, an the other ?.;:i;, confronted with difficulties of an almost opposite kind. That is, the Chinese Communist economy is permanently on the verge of inflation, which is however arrested through a wide network of economic controls. This state of chronic repressed inflation is of course a function of a number of factors. However, the high rate of investment and military expenditure combined with a very marked concentration upon investment in producer goads industries is undoubtedly the most Important single factor contributing to an imbalance between the flow of money income and the flow of goods and services available for consumption. More generally, the economy and the whole society is constantly driven to operate at the very limits of its capacity. Programs are formulated in terms of maximum objectives, with an attempt made to proceed on all fronts at once. In other words, it is an economy and society which is permanently overextended in relation to its stage of development and the human resources at its disposal. All of this Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 CPYRGHT Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 is then reflected in chronic economic and social strain and in structural bottlenecks. 0 nclusions The foregoing analysis has been focused upon an appraisal of agricultural and industrial performance in Tndia and China against the backdrop of the economic development models implicitly or explicitly formulated within the context of the two Five Year.Plans. It was shown that the agricultural sector is assigned a very important role in India, while in China development is identified with industrialization in the narrow sense, with a major emphasis placed uoor the expansion of producer mods Industries. These divergeiatFpatterns of planning have been reinforced in practice by the vagaries of weather and a shortfall in industrial investment in India, On the whole, the Indian Plan has been a modest one, while Chinese Communist targets are very ambitious. This should naturally facilitate plan fulfillment in India as compared to China. What impact do these trends have upon the aggregate rates of growth in the two countries, and what are their implications for an assessment of the economic race -- real or imagined -- between India and China? In looking at the two countries, it is natural to focus on the most dramatic, i.e. the rapid rate of industrial advance in China. It is essential, however, to bear in mind that the moddtrn industrial sector is suite small in both countries. It contributes less than 10 per cent to national product, and possibly its relative size is smaller in China than PYRGHT ? B more rapid in China, this does not necessarily mean that in the short run the economy as a whole Is growing more rapidly. Since we have as Approved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 pproved For Release 1999/09/24: CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 yet no firmly based measures of Communist Chinas GN? for successive years, all statements in this realm are necessarily speculative. However, in view of the marked agricultural expansion in India, it is perfectly conceivable that the increase in India's GNP was greater than that of China's during the past two years, on the other hand, we may be confronted with an entirely different outlook in the long run. Unless the present gap between the rates of investment in the two countries is narrowed, the Chinese economy as a whole is bound to grow much more rapidly than the Indian. Moreover, in China the whole process of economic growth is intimately and consciously linked to rapid and far-reaching changes in the social' structure, One could say that the Chinese Communist regime is bent uuon systematically undermining and bombarding traditional social institutions in order to extend its controls and bring about changes in the society. It to a orocesss in which the whole system is gradually changed through the interaction of social, political and economic dynamism mutually reinfor- cing each other? Thus the institutional barriers to economic growth are Preatly diminished. A system such as this, pursuing the types of-polities the Chinese Communists are engasred in, in obviously faced with a number of ?roblemss the most crucial in our context here involves agricultural development, In a more or less closed economy, where rates of population growth are high and increasing economic growth continuously focused upon industrial development to the neglect of agricultural expansion will tend to strain the economy to a point at which a major crisis may be in the making, In India, this whole process of change is proceeding at a much more leisurely pace. The comparatively low rate of saving and investment is but one of its economic symptoms as well as one of its determinants, auelf~rtleleen~8s981Qiled~`ldeR,~83d~Q2~(i1~S25Q(Mfied in its broadest CPYRGHT Approved For Release 1999/09/24 CIA-RDP83-00423R002000250005-7 ?-i4_ long-run perspective may perhaps be stated in form of a question; Are current plans and governmental measures of a sufficient scope and mag- nitude to impose the kind of all.pervading dynamism in the system which is one of the prerequisites for sustained economic growth? In a sense. one could view the Chinese Comr.-unist and Indian develop- ment models as representing two extremes. The first involves such high rates of aggregate and industrial investment that there is not too much room left for agricultural development and for raising per-capita standards of living, Moreover, such a pattern threatens to undermine peasant and worker incentives and tends to subject the Tsystem to severe structural strains. In the Indian case, the problem is almost reversed. Rates of aggregate investment may be too low to insure a sustained rise in per-capita product and consumption amidst rapid rates of population growth. At the same time, industrial investment may be too low to permit a rate of industrial expansion sufficient to provide an avenue for relieving agricultural population pressure, the relief of which is an essential prereouisite for the-very program of agricultural development. Beyond this, one may legitimately question whether the aggregate rate of growth as reflected in GNP is the sole or most relevant criterion for comparing performance in two or more countries. Obviously, from the standpoint of military and war waging potential, the rate of industrial growth is of prime importance. From an economic welfare point of view the rate of growth in per-canita personal consumption may be the most meaningful criterion. In terms of political appeal, both, rising standards of living and dramatic industrialization programs accompanied by an aggressivenower posture may be competing with each other. Thus the out- come of an India-China eomnarison may yield different results depending A v4Af&I 1Rf'le es*999/QAfd&4.r &3 O 25O( 5. are applied. _ ~i~-~~3 - 423ROb20002500~ ET Approved F~+~aTs~ i 999/09/2 :cd BUILDING ROOM NO Quarters . Eye 1902 2211 ApprovedSF Pflease 1999/09/2~r-Wf -F PP. P3AQ0423ROO20002~5~O~Q~~5~7~TED FORM NO . 57-29 I (20-40) DEC i951 ROUTING AND CONTROL RECORD DO NOT DETACH FROM 'ON LOAN' DOCUMENTS 8 July 1955 DATE TO: CIA LIBRARY ATTN: BUILDING ROOM NO. TITLE Paper read at Wash., D. C. meetings for the Far Eastern Association on March 30, 1955 by Alexander Eckstein, entitled "Direction of Planning and Development in India and China". REMARKS Attachment is EMW RETAIN L] ON LOAN DOCUMENT(S) MUST BE RETURNED TO DOCUMENT(S) CONTACT DIVISION/00 FOR RETENSION BY-(DEADLINE) BY ADDRESSEE FROM: BRA CONTACT DIVISION/ 00 25X1A9a 25X1A8a