GROSS FIXED CAPITAL IN THE USSR 1940-55

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
C
Document Page Count: 
54
Document Creation Date: 
November 9, 2016
Document Release Date: 
December 2, 1998
Sequence Number: 
1
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
December 20, 1957
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4.pdf2.22 MB
Body: 
Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 %~ %..,0 INT I UP C. 01440140" N? 74 RESEARCH AID GROSS FIXED CAPITAL IN THE USSR 1940-55 CIA/RR RA-22 20 December 1957 CENTRAL INTELLIGENCE AGENCY OFFICE OF RESEARCH AND REPORTS %-0 w Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 WARNING This material contains information affecting the National Defense of the United States within the meaning of the espionage laws, Title 18, USC, Sees. 793 and 794, the trans- mission or revelation of which in any manner to an unauthorized person is prohibited by law. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L RESEARCH AID GROSS FIXED CAPITAL IN THE USSR 1940-55 CIA/RR RA-22 (ORR Project 32.1104) Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 FOREWORD The major objectives of this research aid are to develop estimates of total Soviet gross fixed capital, to determine some of its major components, and to analyze its growth and structure during 19)+0-55. Estimates of total gross fixed capital are important in the study of Soviet capabilities for production of capital goods and of economic growth. The estimates developed in this research aid are by no means complete. For reasons stated in the text, these estimates cover in detail neither the nonindustrial sectors of the Soviet economy nor the years before 1940. They do cover, however, the total Soviet economy and some important branches of it. This research aid, therefore, is a partial foundation for analysis of Soviet growth and of total gross fixed capital in the nonindustrial sectors. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 CONTENTS Page Summary and Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 I. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . II. Accounting Practice . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . A. Fixed Capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 B. Depreciation of Fixed Capital . . . . . . . . 7 C. Repair . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 III. Size . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 IV. Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 V. Prospects for Future Growth . . . . . . . . . . . 17 Appendixes Appendix A. Glossary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 Appendix B. Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25 Appendix C. Gaps in Intelligence . . . . . . . . . . 45 Appendix D. Source References . . . . . . . . . . . 47 Tables 1. Total Gross Fixed Capital of the Socialist Sector in the USSR, According to Alternative Sources, Selected Years, 1928-1+0 . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 2. Total Gross Fixed Capital and Major Components in the USSR, in Rubles, 191+0-55 . . . . . . . . 12 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Page 3. Distribution of Total Gross Fixed Capital in the USSR, in Percentages, 1940 and 1946-55 . . . . . 14 4. Index of Gross Fixed Capital in the USSR, Selec- ted Years, 1940-55 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 5. Distribution of Gross Industrial Productive Fixed Capital in the USSR, by Branch of Industry, Selected Years, 1940-54 . . . . . . . . . . . . 16 6. Distribution of Gross Industrial Productive Fixed Capital in the USSR, by Type of Fixed Capital, Selected Years, 1940-54 . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 7. Index of Gross Industrial Productive Fixed Capital in the USSR, by Branch of Industry, 1950 and 1954 ...................... 18 8. Total Gross Fixed Capital Investment in the USSR, 1918-55 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27 Data for Comparison of Magnitudes of Alternative Total Gross Fixed Capital Series with Total Gross Investment in Fixed Capital in the USSR, 1928-40 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 10. Price Index for Total Gross Investment in Fixed Capital in the USSR, 1925-55 . . . . . . . . . . 29 11. Data for Computation of Total Gross Fixed Capital in the USSR, 1940-55 . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12. Annual Depreciation Rates for Gross Fixed Capital in the USSR . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37 13. Index of Gross Industrial Productive Fixed Capital in the USSR, Selected Years, 1940-55 . . . . . . 40 14. Data for Computation of Gross Industrial Produc- tive Fixed Capital in the USSR, 1940 and 1946-55 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 CIA/RR RA-22 C-O-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L (ORR Project 32.1104) GROSS FIXED CAPI'T'AL IN THE USSR* 1940-55 Summary and Conclusions Total gross fixed capital** in the USSR increased from 773 billion 1955 rubles*** in 1940 to 951 billion rubles in 1950 and 1,453 billion rubles in 1955, showing a steadily increasing average annual rate of growth since 1944.**** Productive fixed capitalt increased by 34 per- cent during 1940-50, and its share of the total increased from 58 to 63 percent in the same period. By 1955, productive fixed capital amounted to approximately 67 percent of the total. Since 1940 the fastest growing sector of the economy has been the industrial sector. In 1955, industrial productive fixed capital was 171 percent greater than in 1940, fixed capital in agriculture 94 per- cent greater, and fixed capital in transportation and communications 56 percent greater. Industrial productive fixed capital, which amounted to 29 percent of total fixed capital in 1940, increased to 37 percent * The estimates and conclusions contained in this research aid represent the best judgment of ORR as of 15 September 1957? ** Fixed capital, or basic funds (osnovnyye sredstva), is the stock of durable physical instruments of production used for more than one accounting period. The term fixed capital as used in this research aid refers to gross fixed capital unless otherwise indicated. For a more detailed discussion of fixed capital and for definitions of other terms used in this research aid, see the glossary, Appendix A. *** Ruble values are given in terms of 1 July 1955 rubles throughout this research aid unless otherwise indicated. Ruble values may be con- verted to 1955 US dollars by a ruble-dollar ratio of 4 to 1. **** The periods for which average annual rates of growth are given are from year end to year end, inclusive -- for example, 1942-45 for a period of average annual rate of growth means from the end of 1942 to the end of 1945. This measurement does not hold true, however, for any other dates given in this research aid -- for example, except in cases of average annual rates of growth, 1942-45 means from the begin- ning of 1942 to the end of 1945. t For a discussion of types of fixed capital, see II, p. 5, below. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 in 1950 and 42 percent in 1955. Productive fixed capital outside in- dustry, which also amounted to about 29 percent of total-fixed capital in 1940, has retained a relatively-stable share -- about 25 to 26 per- cent -- since 1950. In 1954, machine building and metalworking was the largest branch of industry, with 25 percent of the industrial fixed capital. The next two branches in size were electric power (11 percent) and ferrous metallurgy (9 percent). During 1950-54, all industrial productive fixed capital increased by 54 percent. Fixed capital in individual branches of industry in- creased-as follows: building materials 92 percent; electric power 88 percent; petroleum 80 percent; coal 76 percent;-ferrous metallurgy, chemicals, and light industry 54 percent; machine building 37 percent; and food processing 37 percent. The Sixth Five Year Plan (1956-60) places considerable emphasis on the replacement of obsolete equipment in industry. The official recog- nition of obsolescence is something of a departure from the past. Much of the equipment which will be retired by 1965 was installed during World War II, when investments* were abnormally low. Therefore, it will be possible until about 1965 for the USSR to maintain the growth of its total fixed capital while replacing some of its existing obsolete assets. It is likely that after 1965 a continuous, widespread program of modernization will be a deterrent to the growth of total fixed capi- tal. 1. Introduction. Fixed capital is distinguished from working capital by the tendency of fixed capital to retain its form during numerous accounting periods and by the special accounting_problems which result from its durability. The most crucial problem in fixed capital accounting is the determi- nation of the original value of items of fixed capital and of the por- tion of an item of fixed capital that is used up during a given account- ing period. * The term investment as used in this research aid refers only to in- vestments in fixed capital. Approved For Release.1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 C-O-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Fixed capital derives its value from its ability to generate income. Therefore, the theoretically correct valuation of fixed capital is the present (discounted) value of the future net incomes which it will pro- duce. It is extremely difficult to value fixed capital practically on the basis of capitalization of income. A number of alternative measures have been used to approximate the value of fixed capital. Some of these measures are based on current market price, on cost of reproduction, and on original cost. For some purposes, one of these alternative measures may be preferable to the capitalization method of valuation. For example, in studies of long-run economic growth, estimates of undepreciated fixed capital measured in terms of costs of reproduction in constant prices may give the best approximation of an index of productive capacity. The reasons for this position will be elaborated below after the discussion of depreciation. The portion of an item of fixed capital used up during a given acr counting period may be approximated. The amount of decline in the value of fixed capital during a given period is termed depreciation. The theoretically correct determination of depreciation follows from the correct valuation of the fixed capital at a given point in time. It was stated above that the theoretically correct valuation of fixed capital is the discounted value of the future net incomes which the fixed capital will produce. At the start of operation of an item of fixed capital, this valuation will be equal to all of the discounted net incomes which the item produces throughout its service life. At a subsequent point in time the valuation will refer to the sum of dis- counted net incomes which the item of fixed capital will produce in its remaining service life. The correct depreciation between two points of time then will equal the valuation of the fixed capital at the first point less its valuation at the second point. It is impossible to compute precisely the depreciation in a given period, because it is impossible to determine precisely the correct valuation of fixed capital at a point of time. Some of the various approximate measures of depreciation used in actual accounting prac- tice are the straight-line method, the declining-balance method, and the annuity method. The straight-line method is probably the most widely used deprecia- tion method. It is the simplest method to apply, although it may be somewhat less accurate than alternative methods. The basic assumption in the straight-line method is that depreciation is divided equally among the years of service life of fixed capital. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 The other methods of depreciation imply changing annual deprecia- tion charges against fixed capital. Some methods indicate a declining amount of depreciation in each subsequent year -- for example, the de- clining-balance method. Others indicate an increasing amount -- for example, the annuity method. It was stated above that a fixed capital series in constant prices may give the best approximation of an index of productive capacity. The productive capacity of any-factor of production may be defined as the maximum annual production which the factor will yield in combina- tion with stated quantities of other factors. The productive capacity of fixed capital, therefore, is properly measured by the production which it will yield in each year. It is customary, however, to measure fixed capital by its total value. Problems requiring measurement of net income or the valuation of productive services remaining in a stock of fixed capital may besolved by the use of estimates of depreciated fixed capital. The use of estimates of fixed capital to measure growth of capacity is valid if the productive services rendered in each year by a given stock of fixed capital are approximately equal. In the absence of ac- curate knowledge, it is assumed for this research aid that capital re- pair offsets depreciation sufficiently for estimates of gross fixed capital to be used. A-major weakness of the estimates presented in this research aid is a failure to take account of the obsolescence of fixed capital. In a dynamic economy, obsolescence becomes a major problem. In the US, business and government authorities recognize obsolescenceas a con- tinuing process. The US Internal Revenue Service allows business firms to set their depreciation rates sufficiently high to cover "normal" obsolescence. In the USSR, however, until recently, the officials have refused to recognize the existence of obsolescence in a socialist econ- omy- It is impossible in this research aid to make adequate adjustment for obsolescence in estimates of the fixed capital for the USSR. Some of the implications of obsolescence, however, should be mentioned. Ob- solescence may occur as a result of shifts either in supply conditions or in the demand structure in a given market or economy. Supply con- ditions may shift because of changes in natural (including human) re- sources or technical changes; the demand structure may shift because Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 .of changing tastes. Undoubtedly, the most important cause of obsoles- cence of fixed capital has been technical innovations. Many of these innovations have resulted from shortages of labor and high costs of labor. The usefulness of estimates of fixed capital as a direct measure of productive capacity depends on the constancy of the capital-capacity ratio.* In a dynamic economy the over-all capital-capacity ratio may remain constant, may increase, or may decline. Changes in this over- all ratio may result from technological changes in individual branches of the economy or from different rates of growth in branches of the economy which exhibit different capital-capacity ratios. The useful- ness of estimates of fixed capital increases if estimates are available for significant sectors and branches of the economy. In the special case of the USSR it is assumed that the output-capac- ity ratio is relatively stable.** Therefore, historical estimates of fixed capital add little or nothing to our knowledge of historical pro- ductive capacity if an adequate output series is available. Output and capital series, however, combined with data on other factors of produc- tion, may be employed in projections of output or capacity for future years. II. Accounting Practice. A. Fixed Capital. An arbitrary division is made between fixed and working capital in Soviet accounting practice. In practice, Soviet accounts include in fixed capital (1) those objects which have a useful life of 1 year or more, regardless of their values, and (2) individual items of fixed This discussion is in terms of capital-capacity ratios rather than capital-output ratios because the latter fluctuate with changes in the degree of use of capital. The concept of capacity is itself somewhat elusive. Capacity must be defined rigidly if the use of capital-capa- city ratios is to be significant. X This statement refers to the absence of sharp cyclical or random shifts in the output-capacity ratio but is not meant to imply that there is no gradual increase in the ratio because of more efficient use of fixed capital. Changes of the former type reflect influences other than changes in productivity. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 capital valued at 300 rubles'per unit,* J** or more, regardless of their useful lives (until 1951, the limit was 200 rubles per unit). The classification of fixed capital according to-function is not uniform among the various sectors and branches of the Soviet economy. The greatest intrasectoraluniformity is found within the industrial sec- tor, where many branches use the following grouping J: 1. Productive Fixed Capital. a. Buildings (shops, offices, warehouses, and the like). b. Other structures. c. Power machinery. d. Production machinery. e. Transmission installations (power lines, pipelines, and the like). f. Mobile transportation facilities (locomotives, rolling stock, trucks, and the like). g. -Tools and attachments. h. Housekeeping inventory. i. Reserve fixed capital (including only composite machines and the like). Items such as individual machine parts for repair are considered working capital. 2. Nonproductive Fixed Capital. a. Housing (including hotels, dormitories, and the like). b. Buildings for cultural and communal purposes (schools, hospitals, municipal and trading enterprises, and the like). c. Equipment and other items required for cultural and communal purposes. * There are two important exceptions to the minimum-value rule. The first is that agricultural machines and implements; adult working, beef, and dairy cattle; and adult poultry are part of fixed capital regardless of unit value. The second is that since January 195+ the Ministry of Trade (Ministerstvo Torgovli), the Central Union of Consumer Coopera- tives (Tsentral'nyy Soyuz Potrebitel'skoy Kooperatsii -- Tsentrosoyuz), and other unspecified ministries and agencies have been allowed to carry on the working capital accounts equipment valued at not more than 500 rubles per unit. ** For serially numbered source references, see Appendix D. -6-- Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Most of the categories of fixed capital listed above are used also in the various nonindustrial sectors of the economy. Additional categories which are peculiar to some of the nonindustrial sectors are as follows: 1. Agricultural machines, implements, and farming inventory. 2. Adult draft and dairy animals, and animals bred for meat, hides, wool, and the like (excluding those being fattened for slaughter). 3. Long-term planting (orchards, vineyards, certain medic- inal and technical crops, parks, and the like). 4. Investments made to exploit the subsoil for land betterment, drainage, and irrigation projects. Some items are counted in fixed capital upon formal acceptance by the purchasing enterprise. They are completed new buildings and other structures, installed new equipment, and completed alterations to fixed capital which increase its value. Equipment not requiring installation, tools, equipment assigned to the reserve, and adult ani- mals are counted upon their receipt at the enterprise. Investments in long-term planting; improvements in plots of land, subsoil workings, forests, and water parcels; and geological exploration directly con- nected with a construction project are counted at the end of the year during which the investments were made. Fixed capital is carried in the USSR at full original cost. For assets acquired by an enterprise from a contracting supplier, the valuation is the actual expenditure including the cost of delivery and installation. Fixed capital made by an enterprise for its own use is valued at its actual cost of production. Fixed capital received free of charge from another enterprise is carried by the receiving enterprise at the same value at which the transferring enterprise carried it. J B. Depreciation of Fixed Capital. Because fixed capital, by definition, is used during several accounting periods, an estimate of the value of fixed capital which is used up during a given accounting period (depreciation charge) must be included by an enterprise in the cost of operations for the period. Depreciation charges for fixed capital in the USSR generally cover both capital repairs and complete replacement. No allowance is made for obsolescence. J Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 The following depreciation formula, used in most sectors of the Soviet economy, is based on the straight-line depreciation method: N = 100 (P+R 0) PL where N = the annual rate of depreciation, in percent; P = the full original cost of the average fixed capital during the year; R = the projected cost of all capi- tal repairs throughout the ser- vice life of the fixed capital; 0 = the estimated salvage value of the fixed capital at the end of the service life; and The depreciation charge is computed as a percentage of the average value of the fixed capital for the year. The value of both new and re- tired fixed capital is prorated according to the portion of the year dur- ing which the respective fixed capital operates. Y/ Depreciation charges are not made for all fixed capital in the Soviet economy. The categories for which no charges are made are the following: 1. Fixed capital held in reserve or storage ?/; 2. Fixed capital of organizations financed entirely from the state or local budgets /; 3. Fixed capital of kolkhozes 10 ;- and 4+. Adult farm animals before the time they are worked. 11 Historically, depreciation practice in the USSR has developed in three distinct stages. Before 1930 there were no national regula- tions setting rates for the various branches of the economy. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 In June 1930 the Supreme Council of the National Economy (Vys- shiy Sovet Narodnogo Khozyaystva -- VSNKh), USSR, established by decree depreciation rates for the various branches of the economy. Individual rates were set for several classes of fixed capital. Moreover, the in- tensity of use of fixed capital was considered. 12 In January 1938, new depreciation rates were decreed by the Council of Peoples Commissars (Sovet Narodnykh Komissarov -- SNK), USSR. SNK was the successor to VSNKh in terms of the right to fix depreciation rates. These rates were established for various peoples commissariats but were not differentiated by branch of economy or by class of fixed capital. For the first time, SNK specified for each peoples commissariat percentages of the depreciation charges which were to be allocated for capital repair. i2/ Some changes have been made in depreciation rates since 1949. No comprehensive data about the new rates, however, are available. It is likely that for most sectors current rates do not differ greatly from those in use before World War II. 14+ The depreciation charges of an individual enterprise in the USSR may be passed on to other enterprises. That part of the charges which represents the depreciation of the original investment in an asset is allocated in full to the financing of the enterprise if the charge does not exceed the limit of investment set for the enterprise. If that part of the charge exceeds the limit of investment for the enterprise, the excess amount is transferred to the organization at the next higher level for distribution to other enterprises. 11 A similar procedure governs the use of that part of depreciation charges allocated to capital repair. C. ReZair. 1. Current. Repairs other than capital repair are sometimes grouped together as current repair. Such repair is on a smaller scale than capital repair and has as its objective the maintenance of fixed capi- tal in operating condition. Under current repair would be included such activities as regulation of equipment and repairs to prevent break- downs. 16 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 2. Capital. Before 1938, capital repair was treated in Soviet accounting as part of investment. Capital repair is now a distinct category not included in plans for investment. _L1 Capital repair is financed generally from depreciation charges. For those enterprises financed entirely from the state or local budgets, the budget itself is the source of funds for capital repair. Profits of the national economy were a supplementary source of-financing capital repair in at least 1940 and 1949. 18 Since 1938 a definite percentage of the depreciation charges-for each peoples commissariat and subsequently for each ministry has been allocated to capital repair. Fixed capital in the USSR is carried on the books at the full original cost. Expenditures for capital repair are treated as an offset to depreciation. These expenditures do not affect the fixed capital account but only the depreciation account. J Soviet publications contain some information about the size and composition of fixed capital in the USSR during the plan years, 1928-40. Data showing the total fixed capital of the socialist sector in the USSR in several key prewar years are shown in Table 1. Total Gross Fixed Capital of the Socialist Sector in the USSR, According to Alternative Sources J Selected Years, 1928-40 Year of Ruble Value 1928 1932 1937 19)40 1933 J 51.0 91.7 192.1 N.A. 1945 J 140.0 285.0 564.0 709.0 a. All values refer to fixed capital existing at the ends of the years. b. 20 c. 21 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Differences between the two series in Table 1 should be reconcil- able on the basis of price changes and, perhaps, adjustments in the coverage of the data. An attempted reconciliation* indicates that the fixed capital series in 1933 prices is reasonably consistent with pre- war investment data but not with the postwar investment data and the official indexes of growth of fixed capital since 1940. The fixed capital series in 1945 prices, however, agrees with the postwar data but not with the prewar data on investment.** In the absence of postwar data on fixed capital in terms of value, the 709.0,billion rubles for 1940 shown in Table l' has been used as a base for estimating the total fixed capital in the USSR during 1940-55- The method* is to add the estimated gross additions of fixed capital in a given year to the fixed capital existing at the beginning of the year and to deduct the estimated retirements and losses of fixed capital during the wartime years 1941-42. The resulting estimate of fixed cap- ital at the end of a given year then becomes the base for estimating the fixed capital existing at the end of the following year. The esti- mates are shown in Table 2.**** The estimates shown in Table 2 indicate that total fixed capital in the USSR declined during the German invasion of 1941-42 to about 75 percent of the 1940 total of 773 billion rubles. In the 13 years from 1943 to the end of the Fifth Five Year Plan (1951-55), total fixed capital increased by about 135 percent. Since 1944 the annual rate of growth of fixed capital has been rising steadily. Estimated average annual rates for three signifi- cant periods are as follows: Years Average Annual Rate of Growth (Percent) 1942-45 5.5 1945-50 6.8 1950-55 8.9 * For detailed methodology, see Appendix B. ** Because inconsistencies in the prewar data prevent the development of a continuous series for 1928-55, the following analysis deals only with the estimates for 1940-55. * P. 10, above. **** Table 2 follows on p. 12. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Total Gross Fixed Capital and Major Components in the USSR, in Rubles 1940-55 Billion 1 July 1955 Rubles Non- Non- Year ,~ Industrial J industrial Total J productive =/ Total 1940 223 222 445 1941 N.A. N.A. N.A. 1942 N.A. N.A. N.A. 1943 N.A. N.A. N.A. 1944 N.A. N.A. N.A. 1945 N.A. N.A. N.A. 1946 223 N.A. N.A. 1947 247 N.A. N.A. 1948 275 N.A. N.A. 1949 310 N.A. N.A. 1950 352 245 597 1951 394 262 656 1952 437 285 722 1953 489 304 793 1954 541 336 877 1955 604 371 975 328 773 N.A. 582 N.A. 582 N.A. 619 N.A. 650 N.A. 683 N.A. 724 N.A. 773 N.A. 827 N.A. 885 354 951 367 1,023 387 1,109 412 1,205 445 1,322 478 1,453 a. Taken from Table 1 _,, p. 42, below, and rounded. b. Obtained as residual. c. For methodology, see Appendix B. d. Taken from Table 11, p. 31, below, and rounded. Total Soviet fixed capital regained its prewar (1940) level in 1947. By the end of the Fourth Five Year Plan (1946-50) it was 23 percent greater than in 1940 and by the end of the Fifth Five Year Plan 88 per- cent greater than in 1940. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 IV. Structure. Changes in the structure as well as in the size of fixed capital of the USSR during 1940-55 are useful in the assessment,of Soviet eco- nomic strength. Data published in the 1956 statistical handbook of the USSR 22 permit a partial examination of the structure of postwar fixed capital. Estimates of some important components of total fixed capital are shown in Table 2.* Total fixed capital is divided into productive and nonproductive components. Productive fixed capital is subdivided into industrial and nonindustrial components.** Table 3P which is based on Table 2,* shows the percentage distribution of fixed capital, by major component. Table 3 indicates that productive fixed capital, which was about 58 percent of total fixed capital in 1940, increased to 63 percent in 1950 and to about 67 percent in 1955. Industrial productive fixed capital, which amounted to about 29 per- cent of total fixed capital in 1940, increased to 31 percent of the total in 1946 and to 42 percent in 1955. Productive nonindustrial fixed capital, which also amounted to about 29 percent of the total fixed capital in 1940, has amounted to about 25 to 26 percent of the total since 1950. The relative share of industrial productive fixed capital in total productive fixed capital increased from 50 percent in 1940 and 59 per- cent in 1950 to about 62 percent in 1955. The indexes of fixed capital published in the 1956 handbook ?.I are shown in Table 4.**** Table 3 indicates that, despite severe war losses, the USSR finished the Fourth Five Year Plan (1946-50) with 23 percent more total fixed capital than in 1940. As would be expected, productive fixed capital has grown more rapidly in the postwar years than has nonproductive fixed capital. Of productive fixed capital, that in the industrial sector has grown more rapidly since 1940 than that in the nonindustrial sector. P. 12, above. Although some of the basic data exist for estimating productive fixed capital in the agricultural and the transportation and communi- cations sectors, these data are a first approximation and it is not considered feasible to attempt estimates for them. For a detailed methodology on estimating these components, see Appendix B. Table 3 follows on P. 14. Table 4 follows on p. 14. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Table 3 Distribution of Total Gross Fixed Capital in the USSR in Percentages 1940 and 1946-55 a/ Year Industrial Nonindustrial Total 1940 29 29 58 1946 31 N.A. N.A. 1947 32 N.A. N.A. 1948 33 N.A. N.A. 1949 35 N.A. N.A. 1950 37 26 63 1951 39 26 64 1952 39 26 65 1953 40 25 66 1954 41 25 66 1955 42 26 67 Nonproductive Total 42 100 N.A. 100 N.A. 100 N.A. 100 N.A. 100 37 100 36 100 35 100 34 100 34 100 33 100 a. Derived from Table 2, p. 12, above. Because of rounding, percent- ages may not add to correct totals. Index of Gross Fixed Capital in the USSR Selected Years, 1940-55 1940 = 100 Type of-Fixed Capital 1940 1950 1954 1955 Productive 100 134 197 219 Industrial 100 158 243 271 Agricultural 100 105 169 194 Transportation and communications 100 117 146 156 Nonproductive 100 111 140 150 Total 100 123 171 188 - 14 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 During 1950-55, productive fixed capital increased by about 63 per- cent; and agricultural fixed capital increased by about 85 percent, which was a higher rate than the increase (72 percent) in industrial fixed capital. The distribution of productive fixed capital, by branch of indus- try and by type of fixed capital, shown in Tables 5 and 6,* is only an approximation because the percentages given in the source are based on valuations at original cost. Nevertheless, the estimates seem to give a fair picture of the increase of fixed capital for individual indus- tries.** Table 7*** shows an index of growth for industrial branches, based on the data underlying Tables 5 and 6. The branches of industry, with the exception of the category of residual, are listed in order according to rates of increase from 1940 to 1954. During 1940-54, industrial productive fixed capital increased by 143 percent. Fixed capital in ferrous metallurgy increased at about the same rate as that for all industry. Fixed capital in four other branches of industry increased at a rate exceeding that for all indus- try. The branches were, in order of-largest growth, coal, petroleum, construction materials, and electric power. In the heavy industrial group, fixed capital in only the machine building and chemical indus- tries increased at a lower rate than that in all industry. Fixed capi- tal in the combined residual industries (see footnote c to Table 7***) increased at about the same rate as that in all industry, whereas fixed capital in the light and food industries increased at a lower rate. During 1950-54, productive fixed capital increased by about 54 per- cent. Fixed capital in the coal, petroleum, construction materials, and electric power industries increased at a higher rate than that in all industry. The construction materials and electric power industries, however, replaced the coal and petroleum industries, respectively, with the highest rates of growth. Fixed capital in ferrous metallurgy, in the chemical industry and in light industry increased at about the same Tables 5 and 6 follow on pp. 16 and 17, respectively. The validity of the analysis of rates of growth in individual industrial branches depends partly on the constancy of the definitions of the branches. Although it is not certain, the data on the branches appear to have been adjusted for major organizational changes. # Table 7 follows on p. 18. P. 18, below. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Distribution of Gross Industrial Productive Fixed Capital in the USSR, by Branch of Industry a/ Selected Years, 1940-54 Billion July 1955 Rubles Branch of Industry 1940 1950 1954 Heavy industry Ferrous metallurgy 20.0 31.7 48.7 Coal 8.9 24.6 43.3 Petroleum 8.9 21.1 -37.9 Electric power stations and networks 20.0 31.7 59.5 Chemical / 15.6 17.6 27.1 _. Machine building and metalworking c/ 62.4 98.5 135.3 Construction materials 8.9 14.1 27.1 Other/ 1/ 37.9 63.3 92.0 Subtotal 182.6 302.6 470.8 Light and food processing industries Light 15.6 17.6 27.1 Food processing 24.5 31.7 43.3 Subtotal 40.1 4 70.4 Total 222.7 351.9 541.2 a. Derived from Table 14, p~ below. Quantities-reflect the rounding of original data and may not add to the totals shown. b. Including the rubber-asbestos industry. c. It is not known whether the defense (conventional weapons) in- dustry is included in Machine building and metalworking or in Other. d. Including the following industries: lumber, nonferrous metal- lurgy, paper, and construction. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Table 6 Distribution of Gross Industrial Productive Fixed Capital in the USSR, by Type of Fixed Capital J Selected Years, 1940-54 Billion July 1955 Rubles Type of Fixed Capital 1940 J 1920 1954 Buildings 1111 4 98.5 146.1 Installations . 80.9 135.3 Power equipment 20.0 28.2 48.7 Production equipment 69 0 95.0 135.3 Transmission facilities . 1. 14.1 27.1 Transportation facilities 13.4 24.6 32.5 Instruments, implements, and other industrial productive fixed capital 8.9 10.6 16.2 222.7 351.9 45 1.2 a. Based on percentages given in source b. Figures for 1940 are based on percentages for 1939? rate as in all industry during 1950-54, whereas fixed capital in the machine building, in the food processing, and in residual industries increased at a lower rate. V. Prospects for Future Growth. An objective of the Soviet Sixth Five Year Plan (1956-60) is the following: To carry out on a wide scale measures for increased stand- ards of production in all branches of industry on the basis of the further development of electrification, complex mech- anization, and automation, introduction of modern and high- productive equipment and advanced technology, and the exten- sive replacement and modernization of obsolete equipment. 25/ Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 H c3 H Cd Iii 4-3 O LL\ N- O H H O ~~ C6 w c ON rc) H yq U rd H 0 0 H LC\ II H 0 H \ O 0 No0 N-N- -_ U\\1O M N-00 ON co Lf\ M M LI\ Lr\ --I- U-\ -t U-\ HHHHHHHHHHHr-iH \O \,O -Zf m . N- t-- --I -t Mco \'O M 00 N 0 O\-:t H N- N- N-- Lr\ N-- I- i- MNNNHHHNNHN N- N- 00 CO co co a\ M M N M :YO N M L(\ L[\ UN U\ N H H\O"O N Lr\ N N H H H H H H H H H H H 0 O N U Q+ (D b.0 U) 43 -P al N U ?O N 0 0 0 -(I H w w rT, u E-I E-I 40 O rd v R4 -P U SA U O U H O H O ? ~+~.~ Ul U F' P Q) aj cd -H (D -N U ad rd cd 0 rd bO H 0 Lf\ ? Lf\ ~ U r I O 01\~ ?rI 0 c$ I~ ?rl -I-3 (D M O 0 01 U) 0 U Ul O U r U O -rl $4 c3 Ld u X v tv rd (1) (U ro P4 r-I f) Ul O Cd O U 0 H ?r1 F-i Pa ?r4 0) O U -H r-4 ;j r-4 0 O cF.i U ri O (D U Cl) t y U $i rd U O ? S + Sul. U) F- 0 rC j Ul d Ul '~ 10 Ul rd ?r-I U rd rd ~: ?rl a) + rl H U rl ~" Cd Lc\ -p Ord O O E Q) r-A w ?rLQI O (D to Ski O j c d C N CH 0 E-I -P _ r, 514 Q) Id rd , (D o ?r I -N -P CH rQ, 5-1 -P r-I X b.0 a) bD (DPIrd ?Hrd r~ A 0 0 04 , H 1 AEl H ~ P U Cd 0 rd ccd Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 The problem of the obsolescence of fixed capital has now received official attention on a large scale. This change in the official view is related to the drive to increase the productivity of labor, a drive which has received emphasis throughout the postwar years. During 1956-60, agriculture is envisiored as being the most favored sector in terms of the relative gain in investment just as it was in the Fifth Five Year Plan (1951-55). Industry., of course, still will get the major share of investment funds. If the plan for investment in industry is met, industrial productive fixed capital should increase by about 60 percent. It is impossible to estimate accurately the effect of the new em- phasis on technological change and replacement during 1956-60. On the basis of very rough estimates, it appears that total fixed capital (in- cluding nonproductive fixed capital) will increase by about 55 percent by 1960 if the plan for investment is met and if the emphasis on techno- logical change does not result in retirements of existing fixed capital earlier than anticipated. The period from 1957 to about 1965 is a favor- able time for the USSR to modernize because it will be replacing much of the equipment which went into service during World War II, when invest- ment was abnormally low. It will be possible for the USSR thus to modern- ize to some extent without any increase in the ratio of retirements to investment. It is almost certain that in the years after 1965 replacements of fixed capital will require a substantially larger share of Soviet in- vestment for several reasons. 1. Average annual investment, which grew at a very rapid rate from 1943 through the early postwar years, has been increasing generally at a declining rate throughout the postwar period. 2. Investment in short-lived fixed capital has accounted for a substantially larger percentage of investment since World War II than previously. A continuation of this trend is implied in a statement of Bulganin that "large allocations are being made for new, more efficient equipment. Though capital investment generally is being increased 67 percent, appropriations for new machinery and equipment will increase 80 percent." 26 3. The recognition of the obsolescence of fixed capital will result in shorter service lives for many items of fixed capital. The Council of Ministers (Sovet Ministrov), USSR, has directed a general - 19 - Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 revision of amortization rates to be completed by 1959. The new rates will be set sufficiently high to cover the obsolescence of fixed capi- tal. =.L1 The above factors indicate a reduction in the rate of growth of fixed capital in the immediate future. C-O-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 C-O-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L APPENDIX A GLOSSARY Any discussion of gross fixed capital in the USSR entails the use of numerous technical terms. The technical terms used in this research aid are defined in this glossary. Accounting period. Any period of time for which economic flows (pro- duction, costs, income, and the like) are totaled. Annuity method. A method of computing depreciation of an asset which provides a series of equal periodic amounts including depreciation allow- ances and interest on the depreciated value of the asset for each period throughout the service life of the asset. Asset. The stock of economic goods and claims to economic goods of an economic unit. The terms fixed assets and fixed capital may be used interchangeably. Capacity. The maximum production possible from a given combination of productive resources in specified quantities under stated conditions of operation during a given period (usually 1 year). Capital-capacity ratio. Tee value of the fixed capital required in an industry or economy for each unit of annual capacity measured in terms of value. Capitalization of income. The process of determining the present value of a given amount of income due at some future date. This process in- volves discounting the income from the maturity (collection) date back to the present time by some known or expected rate of interest. Capital repair. In Soviet accounting terminology, relatively large- scale renovating projects involving the replacement of a large number of parts or of the most important parts of an item of fixed capital. 28 The object of capital repair is to restore the item of fixed capital to full working power. If the object of renovation is to increase the capacity of tie item of fixed capital, such renovation is termed capital reconstruction rather than capital repair. 29/ Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 C-O-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Current market price. In this research aid, the price at which an item of fixed capital would sell at a given time. Declining balance method. A method in which the annual depreciation of an asset is computed as a constant percentage of the net value of the asset. Depreciation. The amount of decline in the value of a fixed asset dur- ing a given period. Depreciation charge. The amount of depreciation which is charged as a cost of production during a given period. Depreciation rate. The ratio of the annual depreciation charge to the gross or net value of the asset or assets against which the chargeis made. Factors of production. The productive services of economic resources. Fixed assets. See Fixed capital. Fixed Capital. The -stock of durable, physical instruments of production that is used for more than one accounting period. In this sense the term instruments of production is defined broadly to include such social over- head capital as housing which is necessary to, but not used directly in, production. In Soviet terminology, this social overhead capital is termed nonproductive. The terms fixed capital, stock of fixed capital, and fixed assets may be used interchangeably. Gross fixed capital. The total value of fixed capital without any de- duction for depreciation. Gross investment. As used in this research aid, the output of fixed capital during a given period of time -- usually 1 year. Income. Goods and services produced in -a given period. Net fixed capital. The depreciated value of fixed capital. Nonproductive fixed capital. In Soviet accounting terminology, fixed capital which is used for social and cultural purposes but not used directly in the productive process -- for example, houses and educa- tional buildings. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 Obsolescence of fixed capital. The functional supplantation of fixed capital by superior substitutes or supplantation because of a decrease in demand for its products. Original cost. In this research aid, the cost of fixed capital when it first enters service. Output-capacity ratio. The value of output in an industry during a given period of time divided by the capacity of the industry during the same period of time. Present (discounted) value. The value of a sum due at the end of a given number of periods as determined by discounting the sum from the due date back to the present by a stated rate of discount per period. Productive fixed capital. In Soviet accounting terminology, fixed cap- ital which is used directly in the productive process. Reproduction cost. In this research aid, the cost of reproducing a given stock-of fixed capital in prices of the current year or some other specified period. Retirements. The value of fixed capital removed from service in a given period. Service life. The economic life of an item of fixed capital. Stock of fixed capital. See Fixed capital. Straight-line method. A method of computing depreciation of an item of fixed capital which provides equal periodic depreciation allowances that accumulate to the original cost of the item of fixed capital, less the salvage value, by the end of its service life. Working capital. Resources used in a productive process which are con- sumed within a short time, usually in one accounting period. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 C-O-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L APPENDIX B METHODOLOGY 1. General. The 1956 statistical handbook J2J published in the USSR contains two categories of data which give a basis for estimating the value of fixed capital in the USSR. First, there is a set of indexes of fixed capital shown in Table )+,* covering the following categories: total fixed capital, productive fixed capital, industrial productive fixed capital, agricultural productive fixed capital, transport and communi- cations productive fixed capital, and nonproductive fixed capital. Second, there is an investment series, giving total investments during 1918-55, as shown in Table 8.** The general equation used in the estimation of fixed capital is derived as follows: Sb+N=xSb xSb - Sb=N N (1) Sb = x-1 where Sb = fixed capital at the end of the base year, valued in prices of a given year; N = the net additions to the fixed capi- tal accumulating from the end of the base year of the period to the end of the terminal year of the period. N is valued in the prices of the same year used in the valuation of Sb ; and * P. 14, above. ** Table 8 follows on p. 27. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79S01046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L x = the numerical expression of the amount of fixed capital at the end of the terminal year of the period, relative to Sb. When both Sb and x are known, fixed capital stock at the end of the terminal year (St) can be determined by equation (2), St = xSb. Both the indexes of total fixed capital and investment data cover all the years of the Five Year Plans. 2. Total Fixed Capital. The first problem in estimation of total fixed capital is establish- ing a base. There is no figure for total fixed capital for any year since 1940. For the prewar plan years, there are two-fixed capital series. The data from the two series are shown in Table 9.* Little is lnown about the coverage and accounting procedures used in the development of the two fixed capital series shown in columns (1) and (3) of Table 9. According to the sources, both series include the socialist sector but do not include livestock. If the coverage of the two series were identical, adjustment to a common price base would make the series identical. A comparison of columns (1) and (3) of Table 9 shows, however, that the adjusted series in column (1) runs approxi- mately three times that of column (3). This result indicates that cover- age of the two series might not have been identical or that the price index, shown in Table 10,x' used to adjust these series to prices of 1 July 1955 is erroneous. A comparison of the net additions to fixed capital with a series of gross additions may also be made on the basis of Table 9. Net additions in columns (2) and (4+) were derived from the data for fixed capital in columns (1) and (3), respectively. Gross additions were estimated from the official Soviet investment series, shown in Table 10, and a Soviet source L2J which states that gross additions to fixed capital amounted*** Table 9 follows on p. 28. Table 10 follows on p. 29. The price index in Table 10 is based on the ratios of investments in current prices of a given year to in- vestments for the same year in prices of 1 July 1955? XXX Continued on p. 30. C-O-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Total Gross Fixed Capital Investment in the USSR J 1918-55 Billion 1 July~55 Rubles Total Total Year and Period Excluding Kolkhoz Kolkhoz Including Kolkhoz 1918-28 17.0 17.0 1929 7.6 0.4 8.0 1930 12.7 1.0 13.7 1931 18.4 0.7 19.1 1932 21.6 0.7 22.3 1J33 16.0 1.1 19.1 1934 23.7 1.3 25.0 1935 27.8 1.7 29.5 1936 38.1 2.3 40.4 1937 33.8 2.7 36.5 1938 35.1 2.v 37.9 1939 40.8 3.3 44.1 1940 43.2 4.0 47.2 1941 37.4 3.1 40.5 1942 23.0 2.2 25.2 1943 23.1 2.8 25.9 1944 31.7 3.9 35.6 1945 39.2 3.7 42.9 1946 46.8 4.8 51.6 1947 50.8 5.9 56.7 1948 62.1 6.2 68.3 1949 76.0 5.2 81.2 1950 90.8 6.9 97.7 1951 102.1 8.5 110.6 1952 113.8 9.9 123.7 1953 119.2 10.9 130.1 1954 140.3 13.3 153.6 1955 149.9 18.8 168.7 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 to to W 41 U2 O 0 C~`2 O 4H V2 0 Ol N I, ~ ?rl ?rl u -P 0 CH rd H DUI NI c3 rl .r{ 4--1 r-I cO 0 rd cn O H O 4 1-11 u\ O\ Oa\ ? rs U r-I d U2 r H r-I O U Q) N cd P4 -p Lr CC) N I N c ?rl U .rq . 0 -H -P CC) ~ rci \ O1 H 4a CH U2 s1 I'J H Cd (1) Q) x! 4i O H U L-- CO co N O -t CU LC\ H H N- H M \ C- m(v .0 N C-0CO N C- N M Cfl N M (Y) O\ (31\ m 01\ ON ON r-I H r-I H H H H cd 'Q U rd a) 4-1 bJ) Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Price Index for Total Gross Investment in Fixed Capital in the USSR 1925-55 a/ 1950 = 100 Industrial Total 1925 44 62 1926 48 68 1927 47 66 1928 45 64 1929 43 62 1930 43 61 1931 60 66 1932 74 73 1933 62 82 1934 85 81 1935 74 80 1936 85 76 1937 62 80 1938 N.A. 83 1939 N.A. 68 1940 71 72 1941 N.A. 66 1942 N.A. 66 1943 N.A. 69 1944 N.A. 75 1945 75 75 1946 82 82 1947 86 86 1948 91 91 1949 121 121 1950 100 100 1951 98 98 1952 92 92 1953 93 93 1954 91 91 July 1955 81.4 81.4 a. The price index for total state investment and post- war industrial investment is based on source . The index for prewar industrial investment is base on source /. In computing this index, rubles of 1 July 1955 were used. - 29 - Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 to 73.5 and 89.8 percent of investments,* respectively, in the periods of the First Five Year Plan (1928-32) and the Second Five Year Plan (1933-37). Columns (4) and (5) appear to check reasonably well. Al- though the difference between gross additions and net additions in 1932-37 appears somewhat high (35.4 billion rubles), this difference might conceivably approximate retirements plus investment items not counted in fixed capital. Comparison of columns (2) and (5) of Table 9, however, indicates gross inconsistencies between the unofficial series of fixed capital in column (1) and the official series in column (3). Because the data in column (3) of Table 9 appear to agree-reason- ably well with the investment information, the possibility of using the 1937 figure (190.8 billion 1 July 1955 rubles) for fixed capital as a base will be tested further. The recently published official in- dex U J shows an increase of 23 percent in total fixed capital during 1940-50. This figure is used below in a test of the 1937 base. The following assumptions are made for the purpose of this test: a. The ratio of net additions of fixed capital to gross invest- ments in 1938-40 was the same as the ratio in the Second Five Year Plan (see Tables 8 and 9**); and, in 1941 and 1943-50, gross additions were as shown in Table 1l.*** b. According to unofficial figures 40 war losses in 1941 amounted to about 30.3 percent of fixed capital in 1940. In 1942, war losses plus retirements were just equal to gross additions of fixed capital. c. Retirements in 1943-50 were the same as shown in Table 11. Trial computation of fixed capital in 1950 is in chronological order, as follows (in 1 July 1955 prices): fixed capital (190.8 billion * Gross additions are less than investments in a given year because some of the investments are added to fixed capital in a later year -- for the example, when a structure is completed and formally enterprise for which it is built. accepted by * Pp. 27 and 28, respectively, above. Table 11 follows on p. 31. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 r~ O L; (D E-~ a) o r-i r H o r1 cd P4 O 0 ~i 0 a3 W N cO CO O IIR -7 N N l1OO of u\ m~u}~ u~ rn N~00 H 0% 0~ N r-- Nco 0 N O0 NU\ u\ u\\O C- r-co ON O H m r r-i O N\O Nm TO H 0 C- 0 m O, O\ m C-\O ON mmm u\ If\\O 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 rn --t U\ ,f\ N N \O 0 0 0 -~' O N 0000000OOOU C-0\000 0 -t IO N ID A co 0 O\- (Ij cn r1 r- 0 (n 0 O\ nico . _:I, m m m _t v\ u\ C NN NNC- H\O C-\O co O\ -:I, CM H MOD O -G- ri co O\O cmmH ..7 0 d. 00000 01 OO N rl O\~ -3 N to\,O\O H N C-c0 O\H 0 - \O N m N C O\ u\. O m H ri - O\ C- ri O\ ri -7 . m N N m u\ u\ C- C- u\ N -O O\OO ri L \0 ri N lO m HH rHirI u\ 00 rnrn a\ rnrnrnArnrn rirl A ri ririH r i H H HNC *u\ u\ u\ u\ u\ u\ O\ O\ O\ O\ O\ rIIi H rlri Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 0 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 rubles) in 1937 plus net additions (85.6 billion rubles*) during 1938-40 minus war losses (83.7 billion rubles**) during 1941 plus gross additions (43.4 billion rubles*) during 1941 minus retirements (3.2 billion ru- bles***) during 1943-50 plus gross additions (371.9 billion rubles*) during 1943-50 yield fixed capital (604.8 billion rubles) in 1950. This computation indicates that the total stock increased between 1940 and 1950 by about 119 percent, compared with the increase of 23 percent indicated in the official index. It is concluded that the prewar base used for postwar estimates of fixed capital must be much higher than the above figure if consis- tency with other postwar data is to be maintained. The only prewar bases available at higher figures are the unofficial figures for fixed capital shown in Table ll.**** Although this fixed capital series fails to agree with the 1928-37 investment data, it is consistent with the deflated series for post-1940 investment and with other information about the wartime and postwar years. The inconsistencies in the prewar data preclude a continuous fixed capital series from 1928 to 1955. The estimates of total fixed capital which are developed below use as a base the 1940 unofficial data from column (1) of Table 9t -- 772.8 billion 1 July 1955 rubles. It is difficult to estimate the value of Ntt because little-is known about retirements of fixed capital in the Soviet economy. Consequently, * It was assumed (p. 30, above) that the ratio of net additions of fixed capital to gross investment in 1938-40 was the same as the ratio in 1933-37 and that, in 1941 and 1943-50, gross additions were as shown in Table 11 (p. 31, above). ** It was assumed (p. 30, above) that war losses in 1941 amounted to about 30.3 percent of the 1940 fixed capital and that, in 1942, war losses plus retirements were just equal to gross additions of fixed capital. *** It was assumed (p. 30, above) that retirements in 1943-50 were the same as shown in Table 11 (p. 31, above). **** P. 31, above. t P. 28, above. tt All symbols used in the discussion are identical with those de- fined in 1, p. 25, above. All the value data are presented in Table 11, p. 31, above. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 equation (2)* will be employed in the estimation of total postwar fixed capital. The elements of the equation are established as follows: a. The fixed capital (Sb) at the end of the base year (1940) is assumed to be 772.8 billion rubles, in prices of 1 July 1955. This is the unofficial figure, given in Table 9, converted from 1945 prices by means of the index in Table 10.*' b. The indexes of total fixed capital for 1940, 1950, 1954, and 1955 were 100, 123, 171, and 188, respectively. c. If Sb equals 772.8, the following values of St are estab- lished: 950.5 for 1950, 1,321.5 for 1954, and 1,452.9 for 1955. Net additions to the fixed capital for several periods may be determined as follows, from equations (1) and (2)*: N=xSb Sb N=St Sb From this formula the following values are found for N: Period N 1941-50 1951-54 1955 177.7 371.0 131.4 * See 1, p. 25, above. P. 28, above. xxy, P. 29, above. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 C-O-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Estimates of -fixed capital for the interim years are also derived as follows by application of equations (1) and (2): xSb = Sb + N St = Sb + N Because value of N is known only for the periods indicated above, its value for the shorter periods must be estimated from the following equation: (3) N = G - (R+W) where G = gross additions to fixed capital in the current year or period; R = fixed capital retired from service during the current year or period; and W = war losses of fixed capital during the current year or period. Estimates of the elements in equation (3) will be made, first, for 1940-55. The following assumptions govern the computations: a. "Normal" gross additions to fixed capital in a given year are equal to one-half the sum of investments in fixed capital during the 2 years preceding.* This lag assumption was determined purely on the basis of trial and error. A lag of 1 year was clearly too short for consistency with the other data, and a lag of 2 years was clearly too great. * For 1950 and earlier years a deduction of 5 percent was made from the investment data to adjust for items which were counted in investments but not in fixed capital. The adjustment for lag was made in order to arrive at "normal" gross additions. -34- Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 b. Estimated war losses of fixed capital are based on a state- ment 41 that "as a result of occupation, fixed capital of socialist enterprises declined during the second half of 1941 by 215 billion rubles (in 1945 prices) and remained virtually at that level in 1942." From this statement, it was estimated that losses of fixed capital in 1941 amounted to 234.4 billion 1 July 1955 rubles and in 1942 to G - R. For reasons stated below, the actual value of R in 1942 is assumed to have been zero. Consequently, in 1942, W was equal to G. c. From equation (3), the value of R may be determined as follows: R = G - (N+W) Because G, N, and W can be established for 1940-55, the value of R for that period may be obtained as a residual. For 1940-55, the com- putation for determining retirements is'as follows: G (1,006.3 billion rubles) for 1941.55 minus the sum (956.1 billion rubles) of N and W yields the retirements (50.2 billion rubles) for 1941-55. For the distribution of the retirements among individual years, fixed capital is conceived as consisting of two categories: long- lived capital, which will be referred to as "structures," and short- lived capital, referred to as "equipment." Data on Soviet investment are reported for "construction and in- stallation work" and for "equipment, tools, and the like." During the prewar plan years, construction and installation averaged about 80 per- cent of total costs of investment. To estimate retirements, the cost of installing equipment should be considered part of the investment in equipment. Precise data on the proportion of investment going to equip- ment, including installation, are not available for all prewar plan years. Scattered data for the early 1930's however, indicate that the percentage was about 30 to 40 percent. / On this basis, it is assumed that the proportion of investment going to equipment, including installation, amounted to one-third of the total investment. Estimation of retirements from data on investment requires an esti- mate of the service life of fixed capital. It is assumed in this re- search aid that the average life of equipment is approximately 20 years, which is, of course, an extremely rough estimate of life of equipment Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 in the USSR. This estimate is 3 years longer than the estimated aver- age service life of US equipment* and is intended to reflect the Soviet tendency to keep equipment in operation for a longer time. Although some data are available concerning Soviet depreciation rates (primarily those established in 1938), these data are difficult to analyze because they are composite rates which reflect individual rates for various classes of fixed capital with greatly different ser- vice lives. The determination of composite rates requires data on the rates for each class of fixed capital as well as on the percentage of each class in total fixed capital. The determination of service lives for each class of fixed capital from composite depreciation rates or composite service lives requires similar data for each class of fixed capital. A rough estimate was made of the implied service life of structures, and equipment was estimated to have a service life of 20 years. For this purpose, a rough estimate of the weights of equipment and struc- tures in terms of fixed capital in 1940 was made. An estimate then was made of the sector composition of the fixed capital. Composite depre- ciation rates, by sector, as shown in Table 12,** were then applied to the percentages of total fixed capital in the appropriate sectors. The average service life for structures thus obtained was approximately three times that estimated for equipment. This result is accepted as reasonable because the ratio of the service life of structures to that of equipment is also 3 to 1 in the US. The war losses of fixed capital in 1941 and 1942 amounted to approx- imately one-third of total fixed capital existing in mid-1941. It is assumed that the relative losses of fixed capital of all ages were equal. Because much equipment was evacuated to safe areas before the German attack in 1941, however, it is further assumed that losses of equipment were relatively smaller than losses of structures. Consequently, esti- mated retirements of equipment in any year Y (on the assumption of a "normal" service life) would be equal to investment in equipment in the year Y minus 20 less losses of equipment which entered service in the year Y minus 20. It is assumed that retirements of equipment for 1941-55 * Studies of the fixed capital of all US business indicate an average life of 17 years for equipment and of 50 years for structures. / ** Table 12 follows on p. 37. It should be noted that rates used are those for replacement and not the total rates for depreciation which include an allowance-for capital repair. - 36 - Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 C-O-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Annual Depreciation Rates for Gross Fixed Capital in the USSR a Sector of the Economy Replacement Capital Repair Total Heavy industry / 3.2 2.4 5.6 Machine building industry b 3.3 2.2 5.5 Defense industry J 2.9 2.6 5.5 Forest industries b 3.0 3.0 6.0 Light industry b 1.9 3.6 5.5 Food processing industry b 3.2 2.8 6.0 Local industry Republic and oblast industry J 2.3 3.3 5.6 Rayon industry J 2.0 4.0 6.0 State procurement / 3.2 2.8 6.0 ~ Communal services e 2.7 3.3 6.0 State farms J Trade 3.0 4.0 7.0 Buildings and structures gl 2.0 3.0 5.0 Commercial equipment / 0 12.0 12.0 Railroads h 0.5 6.0 6.5 Construction industry J 2.0 4.5 6.5 a. All rates are those established in 1938 unless otherwise indicated. b. 44 c. 4 d. e. f. g. J h. These rates were in effect in 1952. The date of establish- ment is uncertain. ;_/ ~~~ i. The rates were established in 1945. L/ Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 C-O-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L equal 80-percent of the investments in equipment in the years 1918-35, or 41 billion rubles. Because retirements for 1941-55 were 50.2 billion rubles,* retirements of structures for the period would equal 50.2 bil- lion minus 41.0 billion, or 9.2 billion rubles. Retirements of struc- tures were allocated to individual years in the same ratios as were re- tirements of equipment. The above procedure assumes a constant service life for each class of fixed capital throughout 1941-55. It is likely, however, that war losses and wartime production requirements necessitated some deferment of retirements and a more rapid completion of investment projects. The data in Table 12** indicate that some adjustment actually occurred dur- ing the war and immediate postwar years. For example, estimates of fixed capit-al already derived indicate that the net additions to the stock during 1941-50 were 177.7 billion rubles. When net additions are computed from "normal" values of G. W, and R,** the resulting figure is 145 billion rubles. For 1951-55, the net additions derived from the stock series are 502.4 billion rubles and 535.1 billion com- puted from the "normal" factors. Consequently, for estimating the fixed capital of the interim years, the following modifying assumptions were made: a. No retirements were made during the war years. b. After 1942 the period of completion of fixed capital was shortened so that G was equal to the investment of the previous year. From 1949 to 1954 the period of completion was lengthened. By 1954 this period was back to normal. Estimates of total fixed capital are shown in Table 11.**** 3. Total Productive and Nonproductive Fixed Capital. Official indexes of fixed capital which were published recently 52/ allow a breakdown between productive and nonproductive fixed capital. For the purpose of making the breakdown, the following symbols are employed: See p. 35, above. ** P. 37, above. MXX P. 34, above. X"M P. 31, above. - 38 - Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Sy = total fixed capital at the end of year y. Py = productive fixed capital at the end of year y. Uy = nonproductive fixed capital at the end of year y. The official indexes, shifted to a 1950 base, follow: 1940 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 Sy 81.3 100.0 139.0 152.8 Py 74.6 100.0 110.0 121.0 133.0 147.0 163.4 Uy 90.1 100.0 126.1 135.1 By definition, Sy = Py + Uy. The values of Sy, given in Table ll,* are 950.5 billion rubles for 1950 and 1,452..9 billion rubles for 1955. The official indexes give relationships between 1950 and 1955. The following relationships have been established: a. P1950 + U1950 = 950-5 b. 1.634 P1950 + 1.351 U1950 = 1,452.9 These two equations are solved simultaneously as follows: b. 1.634 P1950 + 1.351 U1950 = 1,452.9 c. 1.351 P1950 + 1.351 U1950 = 1,284.1 Thus 0.283 P1950 = 168.8 P1950 = 596.5 Estimates of Py for 1940 and 1951-55 are obtained by multiplication of P1950 by the index. For each year, Uy is obtained as a residual be- cause Uy equals Sy - Py. The resulting estimates are given in Table 2. P. 31, above. Derived by multiplying a by 1-351- P. 12, above. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 4. Industrial Productive Fixed Capital. Official Soviet data permit the construction of an index of indus- trial productive fixed capital with a postwar base. An index for se- lected years, 1940-55, is given in Table 13. Table 13 Index of Gross Industrial Productive Fixed Capital in the USSR Selected Years, 1940-55 19+0 = 100 Year Index 1940 100 a~ 1952 196 J 1946 100 1954 243 a 195 1 158 1955 271 1 195 177 1/ b b. 5.~ C. There is no base figure for industrial-fixed capital. Such a figure may be derived, however, by equation (1).* The value of the percentage increase in fixed capital (x) may be determined for several postwar periods from Table 13. Net additions (N) must be estimated. The period of the estimate is 1947-52, and the following assumptions apply: a. Gross additions to industrial productive fixed capital (G) during 1947-52 areequal to investments in industrial productive fixed capital during 1946-51, inclusive. b. Investments in industrial productive fixed capital in 1946-51 averaged 85 percent of total industrial investments during the same period.** * See 1, p. 25, above. ** This assumption is based on data on Soviet industrial investments from source. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 c. Retirements (R) in 1947-55 equaled investments in industrial equipment in 1927-35 minus 20 percent for estimated war losses. It is assumed that retirements of industrial structures were negligible, be- cause the structures being retired were erected when industry in Russia was a small part of the economy. The total retirements of industrial equipment for the period were distributed among the individual years in the same proportions that the total retirements of equipment in the economy were distributed.* Two additional figures are available from Soviet sources. Industrial investments were 46.4 billion current ru- bles in 1948 Z/ and 320 billion 1950 rubles in 1946-51. 1=! With the known data and the foregoing assumptions, certain relation- ships, useful in the computation, must follow: a. The sum of gross additions during 1947-52 in 1955 prices, is 221.4 billion rubles (see column (3) in Table 14**1. b. The total net additions for 1947-52, in 1955 prices, are equal to gross additions less retirements, or 213.8 billion rubles. The data required to establish a base figure are included in Table 14. The following procedure was used: a. From Table 14, net additions in 1947-52 were 213.8 billion b. The industrial productive fixed capital in 1952 was 1.96 times that in 1946 (from Table 13"*). c. Substitution in equation (1) * gives the following: 2 ~.._ 51946 - 1 8 0.96 = 222.7 d. Once the base was established the estimates of fixed capital in 1940 and 1950-55, excluding 1953, were derived by multiplication of the base by the index in Table 13. The estimates are shown in column (6) in Table 14.** See 2, p. 26, above, and Table 11, p. 31, above. * Table 14 follows on p. 42. P. 40, above. See 1, p. 25, above. Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/08 : CIA-RDP79SO1046A000500110001-4 Cd