JPRS ID: 9947 USSR REPORT HUMAN RESOURCES

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9
Release Decision: 
RIF
Original Classification: 
U
Document Page Count: 
26
Document Creation Date: 
November 1, 2016
Sequence Number: 
59
Case Number: 
Content Type: 
REPORTS
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9.pdf1.78 MB
Body: 
APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 Y~OR OI~F'1('IA1. USN: ONI,Y JPRS L/9947 ~ 28 August 1981 f~ ~S R Re ort p ~ h~IJIVi/~1~~ RESOURCES (FOUO 5/81) FBIS FOREIGN BROADCAST INFORMA�TION SER1l~~~w~ ~ FOid OFFICIAI. USE ONLY APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2447/02/09: CIA-RDP82-44850R444444444459-9 NOTE . JPRS publications contain information primarily fx�om foreign newspapers, periodicals and books, but also from news agency transmissions and broadcasts. Materials from foreign-language sources are translated; those from English-language sources are transcribed or reprinted, with the original phrasing and ~ other characteristics retained. Headlines, editorial reports, and material enclosed in brackets are supplied by JPRS. Processing indicators such as [TextJ or [Excerpt] in the first line of each item, or following the last line of a br~ef, indicate how the original information was processed. Where no processing indicator is given, the infor- mation was summarized or extracted. Unfamiliar names rendered phonetically or transliterated are enclosed in parentheses. Words or names preceded by a ques- tion mark and enclosed in parentheses were not clear in the original but have ~c~n supplied as appropriate in context. Other unattributed parenthetical notes with in the body of an item originate with the source. Times within items are as given by source. The contents of this publication in no way represent the poli- cies, views or attitudes of the U.S. Government. COPYRIGHT LAWS AND REGULATIONS GOVERNING OWNERSHIP OF MATERIALS REPRODUCED HEREIN REQUIRE THAT DISSEMINATION OF THIS PUBLICATION BE RESTRICTED FOR OFFICIAL USE 0?~TLY. APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2447/02/09: CIA-RDP82-44850R444444444459-9 FOR OEFICIAL USE ONLY JPRS L/9947 2$ August 1.981 USSR REPORT HUMAN RESOURCES (FOUO 5/81) CONTENTS LABOR ~ Tajik Population Dynamics Ststistics (A. Madzhidov; IZVESTIYA AKADEMII NAUK TADZHIKSKOY SSR OTDELENIYE OBSHCHESTVENNYKH NAUK, Oct-Dec 80) 1 Criteria for Forming, Using Incentive Funde Explored (A. Akhmeduev; VOPROSY ECONOMIKI, Jun 81) 6 Northern Ob' River Region's Changing Manpower Supply Analyzed (S. Ye. Mozgalin; IZVESTIYA VSESUYUZNOGO GEOGRAFICHFSKOGO OBSHCHESTVA, Mar-Apr 81) 16 , _ a - [III - USSR - 38c FOUO] F~1R (1F'FT!'T.1T . i i,CF (1NLY APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02109: CIA-RDP82-00850R400440040059-9 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY LABOR TAJIK POPULATION DYNEIMICS STATISTICS DushaMbe IZVESTIYA AKADEMII NAUK TADZHIKSKOY SSR OTDELENIYE OBSHCHESTVENNYKH NAUK in Russian No 4, Oct-Dec 80 pp 72-76 [Article by A. Madzhidov, USSR Gosplan Council for the Study of Product3.ve Forces: "Tajik SSR Population Distribution and Labor Resources llse"] [Text] Territorial pepulation distribution and l.abor resources use ar~ among the most important national' economic problei:is and di~cectly influence the rates and pro- portions of economic development and the basic directions in which the economic ef- fectiveness of social production is increased. This problem takes on special significar.ce in 7'ajikistan, where the population incre- ment is the highest in the country. Table 1. Dynamics nf USSR and TaSSR Population for 1940-197a (compiled from data in: "Narodnoye khozyaystvo SSSR v 1977 g." [USSR National Economy in 1977], Moscow, "Statistika" Izd-vo, 1978, pp 10-11) USSR TaSSR total population including: total population including: year (in millions) urban rural (in millions) urban rura (in percent) (in percent) 1940 194.1 33 67 1.525 19 81 1959 208.8 48 52 1.980 33 67 1970 241.7 56 44 2.899 37 63 1978 260.0 62 38 3.691 35 65 Thus, whereas the 1978 population for the U~SR as a whole was 33.9 percent greater in 1978 than in 1940, it was 142.0 percent greater for Tajikistan. In 1940, the repub- lic population was 0.~ percent of the national total, in 1959 0.9 percent, in 1970 1.2 percent and in 1978 1.4 percent. As distinct from other Union republics and regions of the country, both the urban and rural population arc growing in Tajikistan. From 1940 through 1978, the total repub- lic population increased 2.3-fold, while the urban populatian increased 4.4-fold and the rural population increased 1.9-fold. Tt~e proportion of rural popu?ation in Tajikistan is one of the highest in the country, 65 percent in 1978. From 1440 through 1978, the rural population proportion decreased 1 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2447/02/09: CIA-RDP82-44850R444444444459-9 FQR OFFICIAL USE ONLY 16 percent in the republic and 29.4 percent in the country as a whole (see: "Narod- noye khozyaystvo SSSR v 1977 g.," Moscow, "Statistika," 1978). The rapid growth in republic population is to be explained by various factors, pri- mary among which are demographic features. The main reason for change in natural population increment as a whole and labor resources in particular is the birth rate. Whereas an unfavorable demographic situation associated foremost with a significant lowering of tha birth rate has evolved in the country as a whole, a high birth rate has been retained in Ta~ikistan. The birth rate per 1,000 people in the republic has increased from 30,6 in 1940 to 38.2 in 1976, while this indicator decreased from 31.2 to 18.4 in the country as a whole.l The formation of labor resources depends iargely on the birth rate. The dissimilar urban and rural able-bodied populations result in considerable measure from the dif- - ferent birth rates. More than half the total able-bodied population is concentrated in rural areas, which is one source for the formation of manpower. The high growth in the Tajik population ~?as facilitated rapid labor resources repro- duction and has had a large impact on the nature, direction and rates of development ~ of branches of the national economy, on deepening specialization in labor-intensive branches. All this has necessitated the efficient distribution of the population within the republic and the planned shifting of labor resources between individual regions. Population distribution .and its efficient deployment within our country are determined by both the geneYal and local specifics of its economic development. Population dis- tribution depends on many factors, among which natural factors, features of historical development and socioeconomic conditions are the most important. Natural conditions are the natural basis for developing production and distributing population within the country. In Tajikistan, an oasis and mountain type of settle- ment has evolved under the influence of natural conditions, the rural population ba- sically being concentrated around water sources, for example. The bulk of the rural settlements are concentrated in valley regions. Extensive mountain areas are sparsely settled, however. The population there is scattered. The territorial distribution of the TaSSR population has its own specific fea~ures resulting from the l� storical conditions under which the economy was shaped and the population grew prior to and after the October Revolution. Since the basic occupa- tion in prerevolutionary Tajikistan was farming, population distribution depended on sources of water. With its arid climate, it was proximity to natural and artiiicial water sources that basically determined population distribution in Tajikistan. Republic population den- sity can be seen in Table 2(following page). In connection with the high rates of population growth, republic population density ' has increased significantly faster than for the country as a whole. Whereas national average population density increased 12.5 percent du:ring 1959-1978, the increase in Tajikistan was 20 percent. l. "Narodnoye Ichozyaystvo SSSR za 60.1et" [Sixty Xears of the USSR National Economy], ~to~c~w, "SLat i st i_k~~" Ircl-~~o, 1977, p 72. 7_ APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 TOR 01~FICfAL USI? ONL~' Table 2. Dynamics of USSR and TaSSR Population Distribution Change (compiled from data in: "Narodnoye khozyaystvo SSSR v 1977 g.," pp 10-11) USSR TaSSR total population population total population population year densit (in thousandsj density (in thousands) y 1959 208,827 9.3 1,981 13.8 1970 241,720 I0.7 2,899 20.3 1975 253,261 11.4 3,387 23�7 1978 260,040 11.7 3,691 25.8 Tajikistan has its own specific natural and economic features which are manifested in its geographic position, t!ie natural-econom~c prerequisites for shapi.tig and de-- veloping tlle economy, its s~ructure and uirection, and opportunities for further de- veloping productive forces. At present, the TaSSR is divided into seven natural- economic zones: Northern, Zeravshanskiy, Gissarskiy, Vakhshskiy, Kulyabskiy, Garm- skiy and Gorno-Badakhshanskaya A0. As a consequence of differences in soil-climate, terrain and other conditions, the republic population distribution and density is characterized by great unevenness. . The population is concentrated basically in the valley regions of irrigation farming~ which are distinguished by high economic utilization of the territory, and also in regions with a high ie~el of development of industrial branches of the national eco- nomy (see Table 3). Table 3. Distribution and Density of TaSSR Population by Zone as of 1 January 1978 (table calculated from USSR Central Statistical Administration data) in percent of population size density zone all republic in percent of urban rural territory total republic (percent) (percent) population Cissarskiy 8.''~ 29.9 51.8 48.2 92.9 Vakhshskiy 8.~ 18.9 23.1 76.9 61 Kulyabskiy 9.0 11.5 26.1 73.9 33.1 Northern 11.5 27.8 39.4 60.6 62.4 Zeravshanskiy 6.2 4.0 12.2 87.8 16.5 Garmskiy 12.0 2.7 8.0 92.0 5.8 GBAO 45.0 3.3 13.3 86.7 1.2 The most densely populated region of Tajikistan is the Gissarskiy zone. Some 29.9 percent of the republic population is concentrated here, while it contains only 8.3 percent of the republic territory. Average population density in Gissarskiy zone is 92.9 people, 3.6 times more than the republic average. Northern and Vakhskiy zones are also characterized by relatively high density. For example, 2.3-fold more people live per square kilometer in Northern zone than the TaSSR average. Thus, 89.7 per- cent of the Tajilcistan population lives in valley regions comprising 36.5 percent of the republic territory. Ten percent of the population live in the mountain and foot- ttill regions (GBAO, Garmskiy and Zeravshanskiy zones), which comprise 63.2 percent of the total area of Tajikistan. : 3 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/49: CIA-RDP82-00850R040400040059-9 - FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY - The distribution of population and labor resources depend direcr.ly on development of tlie national economy. Spatial development of the economy and the specialization and di~ersity of regional econamies are determined in considerable measure by the nature of population and labor resources distribution, by their concentration in various re- gions. The primary cause of territorial Ghifts in nopu~ation distribution nationally has been industrializ2tion of the economy. The development of industrial production is the economic basis of urbanization. The proportions of TaSSR urban and rural populations in 1978 were 35 and 65 percenty - respectively, while nationally they were 62 and 38 percent.i The republic's urban network is still in the formation stage. The basic category of cities is small and medium-siz~d (20,000 to 50,000) and urban-type settlements. More than half the republic urban population lives in such settlements. According to census results, Tajikistan had 61 urban population centers in 1970 (with a population of 1,076,700), including two large cities (477,100), seven medium-sized cities (204,000), nine small c~ties (108,300) and 43 urban-type settlements (257~200).2 Urban settlements are distributed unevenly wichin the republic. Nine of the 18 cit- ies are in the Northern zone, four are in Gissarskiy zone, and Kulyabskiy zone and the GBAO each have one city. Small and medium-sized cities are still characterized by a relatively low level of in- dustrial development. The predominance of small urban settlements with poorly de- veloped industry in the regublic restricts opportunities for drawing the unemployed population ~~ito social product~on. Labor resources are growing here considerably faster than the number of jobs in industry. In medium-sized and small cities, the number of branches of industry is limited. In a majority of such cities, there are only enterprises of light and foo~' industry. Accelerated economic deveiopment of the republic has led to the formation of indus- trial centers and to the creation of new cities. Thus, 17 urban-type settlements and four new cities were created in the TaSSR during 1959-1977; the urban population in- _ creased 2.1-fold. Changes in the propo~tions between the urban and rural populations in the republic reflect the level of development of productive forces and the economic structure in the republic. During 1959-1978, the proportion of the TaSSR rural popu- lation decreased from 67 to 65 percent. However, the absolute number of rural resi- dents increased by 1,055,500, while it decreased by 10,618,000 nationally. The distribution of the TaSSR rural population has its own distinguishing featr~res. According to census data, the republic had 3,908 rural population centers with a to- tal. population of 1,822,900 in 1970. The Zargest number of population centers was accounted for by the groups with 201 to 500 people and 501 to 1,000 people, in which 19.9 and 27.4 percent of the total republic rural population live. Consequently, "Narodnoye khozyaystvo SSSR v 1977 g.," p 7. 2. "Itogi Vsesayuznoy perepisi naseleniya SSSR v 1970 g." [1970 USSR A11-Union Cen- ~~us ResultsJ, Vol l, Moscow, "Statistika" Izd-vo, 19%2, p 73. 1~ APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/49: CIA-RDP82-00850R040400040059-9 FOR OFFICIAL iJSE ONLY - about half the Tajikistan rural population lives in these two groups of settlements. Population centers with u~ to 200 people are characteristic of the republic. They comprise 42.9 percent of all rural settlements, althou~h 8.0 percent oi the popula- tiot? live in them. The groupings of population centers shows that rural settlecr.ents with up to 200 residents, located basically in the mountain regions, predominate in the republic. The relatively large population centers are generally concentrated in the densely-populated valley regions. Harever, here, too, there are relatively numer- ous villages with large populations. At pre~ent, small population centers are being consolidated and transformed into ur- - ban-type settlements, with a view towards improving the living conditiuns of the po- pu?ation. In 1970, the number of republic rural population centers had decrEased by 962 as compared with 1959. However, the orocess of concentrating and consolidating republic population centers ~ has occurred very slowly. The most widespread form of settlement continues to be the small kishlaks, which retards the development of productive forces and delays the process of concentrating agricultural production. The main directions of population distribution in Tajikistai.i are determined in large measure by the utilization ~f broad expanses of mountain and foothill land to increase the production of valuable agricultural crops such as cottc,n, vegetables, fruit and grapes, and stockraising output, by the involvement of mineral deposits in economic circulation, and also be the accelera*ed development of industrial branches, especi- ally those important to developing cities. Republic population distribution is de- termined largely by the involvement of rapidly growing labor resources in social pro- duction. The unevenness in production and population di~tribution within the region will gradually be overcome in this manner. In order to increase employment in the small and medium-sized cities and urban-type settlements, branches of large enterprises should be located there. In order to draw labor resources into social production, we need to define ways of using them mcre ef- fectively in various types of urban and rural population centers. Along with the demographic features noted abvve, the high proportion of those employed in agriculture testifies to republic reserves for freeing manpower. The devel~pment - of industry, improvement in the forms of agricultural organization and management, development of a system of ineasures to reduce the seasonal nature of labor in branches of the agroindustrial complex and developing the services sphere facilitate reaching this goal. In this connection, rural populati.on centers are being consolidated by concentrating small enterprises based on processing agricultural output; rural popu- lation centers are being transfcrmed into urban settlements. The development of cities and increasing the rates of urbanization in the republic are helping to draw the rapidly growing labor resources into social production. COPYRIGHT: Izdatel'stvo "Donish", 198G 11052 CSO: 1828 /133 5 � FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY i APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2407/42/09: CIA-RDP82-40850R000400440059-9 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY LABOR CRITERIA FOR FORMING, USING INCENTIVE FUNDS EXPLORED Moscow VO~ROSY EKONOMIKI in Russian No 6, Jun 81 pp 41-49 [Article by A. Akhmeduev: "'I'he Material :Lncentive Fund"] [Text] The 26th CPSU Congress Congress posed the task of continuing the improve- ment of the material incentive system with regard to the concrete contribution of each labor collective and individual workman to the result. We believe that the improvement of the procedure for forming the material incentiv~ fund occupies an imPortant place in the realization of this task. The strengthening of its stimulating influence c~ the growth of production demands ~hat the size of this fund be closely linked to the end results of the activity of associations and enterprises, to the tautness of their plans, and to the degree of their fulfillment. The system for forming the material incentive ~und under the 9th and TOth five-year plans did not secure such dependence in full measure. Thus, the Basic Principles Governing the Formation and Expenditure of Incentive Funds~`,in fixing the planned size of the materia~ incentive fund, favored associations and enterprises that adopted taut plant targets , including targets of improving product quality, that used productive capital more effectively, that brought capacities and new equipment up to standard in a shorter period of time, that realized higher growth rates of labor productivity, etc. However, during the years of the five-year plan, the planned size of the given fund was determined without regard to the end results of the activity of economic links, and the level and rate of their growth. The size of the incentive funds was differentiated primarily by adjusting their planned size depending on the fulfillment of the annual plan and five-year plan targets based on fund-forming indicators. However, experience has shown that such differentiation of payments to the material incentive fund is justified if its planned size is fixed with due regard to the tautness of five-year plan indicators. Otherwise, economic links that dispose over production reserves not ' ~tiBasic Principles Govern~ng the Formation and Expenditure of the Material Incentive Fund and the Fund for Sociocultural Measures and Housing Construction in 1971-1975 (EKONOMICHESKAYA GAZETA, No 23, 1972, pp 15-16); Basic Principles Governing the Formation and Expenditure of the Material Incentive Fund and the Fund for Socio- culturzl Measures and Housing Construction in 1976-1980 in Production Associations (Combines), at Enterprises and in Organizations in Industry Converted to the New System of Planning and Economic Incentives(EKONOMICHESKAYA GAZETA, No 50, 1976, pp 11-14). 6 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02109: CIA-RDP82-00850R400440040059-9 FOR UFFICIAL i1SE ONLY ~ considered in the five-year plan will be placed in a more favorable economic position in that they will have the oppoitunity to significantly increase their contributions to material incentive funds as a result of the adoption of annual counter-plans that exceed five-year plan targets, and by surpassing the indicat~rs of their one-,~ear plans. All this injected an egalitarian element into the system governing the formation of the material incentive fund, which did not sufficientlq motivate associations and = enterprises to adopt and fulfill taut plans. The result was an insufficiently close relationship between the resources utilized from the material incentive fund and indicators of the effectiveness of social groducti~n. Between 1971 and 1979, resources expended from this fund increased 1.7 fold, labor productivity rose 1.5 fold, and the output-capital ratio declined. The material incentive fund as a whole and the material incentive fund per industrial production worker in the 9th Five-Year Plan increased at a more rapid rate than output and labor productivity. iJnder the lOth Five-Year P1an, to the contrary, ~iven a 20 percent increase in output and a 14 percent increase in labor productivity, the material incentive fund increased by 12.2 pcrcent and payments from the material incentive fund per work.er rose by a mere 5 percent". The establishment of a close relationship between the size of the material incentive funds and the performance ot associations and enterprises depends first and fore- most on the improvement of the system underlying the formation of these funds--a system that is based on the objective evaluation of the performance of an economic ' link and the determination of the reward appr�opriate to this performance. We believe that the evaluation of the five-year plan of economic links with due regar~i to the correspondence of plan irdicators to the needs of society and long- range targets in the economic and sociG'. development of the national economy must becc~me a necessary element in the system governing the formation of the material. - incentive f~.~nc~. and the basis for the differentiation of its planned magnitude. Therefore the establishment of the planned size of the material incentive fund corresponding to five-year plan indicators with due regard to the degree of satis- faction of the national economy's requirements and the evaluation of the tautness of these indicators would be an important direction in improving the system govern- ing the formation of this fund. - The guidelines approved by USSR Gosplan for determining the tautness of p.lans~~~~ call for the evaluation of the 5-year and 1-year plans of associations and enterprises according to the degree to which the plans conform to (approximate) normative demands. According to these guidelines, a plan is considered taut when - it ensures the fulfillment of the established targets and the rational use of - production capacities and expenditures of material, labor, financial and other - resources at the normative level. The evaluation of the plan in comparison with the norm~tive level will Promote the rational use of resources if this level of indicators is established on the basis of progressive scientifically substantiate3 technico-economic norms. This fundamentally important point is considered in the ilew document . ~~Czlculated on th~ basis of the statistical yearbook "Narodnoye Khozyaystvo SSSR v 1979 4~." [The USSR National Economy in 1979], Izdatel'stvo "Statistika," 1980, pp ].34, 147, 149, 150, 550. -~~~See "Sovershenstvovaniye khozyaystvennogo mekhanizma. Sbornik dokumentov" [Improvin;; the F..conomic Mechznism. Collected Documents], Izdatel'stvo "Pravda," .1980, pP 37-39. 7 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000440040059-9 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY ' H~wever, the principles specified in the Guidelines for Determining the Tautness of Plans were not fully taken into account in the process of forming incentive funds under the Eleventh Five-Year Plan. The point is that the planned size of the material incentive fund under the llth Five-Year Plan is determined on the basis of norms (differentiated for the various years of the five-year plan) computed on the basis of fund-forming indicators and the sum of the fund, which are adopted in calculations of the control figures for the five-year plan~'. The material incentive fund envisaged in the control figures is corrected degending on the deviation of fund-forming indicators of draft five-year plans from analagous indicators in the control figures. When ministrias, sssociations and enterprises draft a five-year plan whose targets are higher than the control figures, the size - of the incentive funds is increased and when they draft a five-year plan with lower targets, the incentive funds are reduced. Thus the level of the f-und-forming indicators in the five-year plan is evaluated on the basis of their correspondence to the control figures for the five-year plan. The tautness of th~ plans is evaluated by comparing their indicators with the indicators or the control figures and the differentiation of the planned size of the material incentive fund on this basis is economically substan~tiated if the control figures take into account the use of resources at the normative level for all entPrprises, associations and ministries and if there is equal tautness of indicators corresponding to the control figures. If these conditions are not observed, economic links will be nlaced in an unequal situation: those that possess reserves for surpassing control figure targets with regard to the fund- forming indicators will have a significantly larger planned material incentive , fund than those that establish taut indicators in the control figures. In order to assure that all economic links have equal economic conditions for forming incentive funds, the indicator obtained by comparing draft plans with the control figures for the five-year plan should be adjusted to take account of the result of the evaluation of the control figures proper. This means that the control figures for the five-year plan and draft plans should be evaluated on the basis of a single criterion. '+7e believe that the comparison of control figures and draft plans with norms governing the effectiveness of social production could constitute such a criterion. Their introduction is envisaged in normative . documents. In accordance with the decree of the CPSU Central Committee and the USSR Council of Ministers"On Improving Planning and Strengthening the Influence of the Economic _ P'iechanism on Increasing the Effectiveness of Production and Improving Work Quality" (1979), USSR Gosplan approved the Procedure for Devising and Ratifying a System of Norms'`'` which, in addition to the norms ratified in the five-year plan regarding the expenditure of labor, wages, material and energy resources, the use of production capacities; norms governing capital investments, equipment requirements and reserves, and financial~morms, also envisage the introduction of norms regarding ',See Basic Principles Governing the Formation and Expenditure of the Material Incentive Fund and the Fund for Sociocultural Measures and Housing Construction (Incentive Funds) in 1981-1985 in Industry ("Sovershenstvovaniye Khozyaystvennogo mekhanizma" [Improving the Economic Mechanism], pp 142-153]). `See EKONOP4ICHESKAYA GAZETA, ;10 10, 1980, pp 11-14. 8 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 ~ . the effectiveness of social production. In our apinion, this holds great signifi- - cance for raising the scientific level of planning and for increasing the effect- ' iveness of economic stimuli and in particular for increasing the sfiimulating i~zfluence of incentive funds on the growth of production. The point is that the existing norms and norms ratified for the llth Five-Year Plan extend mnre to the process of placing resources at the disposal of economic links azd much less to the use of these resources. 4Jhen society allocates fixed and working capital to an economic link and s-trengthens [it] with material- technical, labor and natural resources, society must determine the normative return on these resources. In our view, such norms must be a most important element in society's monitoring of the complete and effective use of the natior.al ecor.omy's resources and together with other norms must comprise the basis of scientifically substantiated planning and economic stimulation of the development of production. Accordingly, the incorporation of norms of effective- ness of social praduction in national economic planning practice and in the mechanism of economic stimulation is very important and timely. Proceeding from the aforementioned Procedure for Elaborating and Confirming Norms, it is expe3ient to determine the economic content, structure and functions of norms of the effectiveness of sociaZ production. If we approach the given norms from the standpoint of their role in the formation of incentive funds, they must in our opinion include the normative level c~ use of production's basic resources and the degree of satisfaction of the need tor a given economic link's products of a given quantity and quality. The 3etermination of norms of the degree of satisfaction of the need for resources and the use of resources should be based on the national economy's scientifically substantiated requirement for given types of products and on their production potential. Norms must be oriented toward the long-term dev2lopment of production, must stimulate the search for resources and the creation of conditions for the growth of production at enter- orises whose products are needed by the national economy. in the structure of normative effectiveness of social production, a major part must be played by the normative degree of satisfaction of society's requirement for products of each economic link which will make it possible to orient the collectives of enterprises and associations toward the elaboration of plans that ensure the more complete satisfaction of the requirements of the national economy and the population. It should be noted that the tautness of plans, which is determined in accordance with the Guidelines on the Procedure for Determining the Tautness of Plans, characterizes the effectiveness of the use or production capacities, equipment, material and labor resources in any given period of time. But in itself the degree of tautness as a relative quantity does not ancourage the use of zdditional resources in production, the technical improvement of existing fixed capital, the replacement of obsolete equipment with new equipment, the modification of structure an~ the upgrading of the skill level of the work force, etc. As a result of this, the development of production on a higher technical basis, which makes it possible to satisfy the requirements of the national economy more c~mpletely, may not be reflected in the higher degree of tautness of the plans. For this reason, in the elaboration of inethods of evaluating plans, we helieve it important to use the degree of satisfaction of the requirements of the national 9 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY economy for the output of a given enterprise, production association, all-union production association, and ministry as the major criterion. It is expedient to " e~tablish the degree of satisfaction of needs as the ratio of the optimal volume of output to ths scientifically substantiated requirement for output which is the determining factor in the specialization of a given economic link. The requirement for concrete types of products at the normative level must be balanced with production through the determination of concrete production links responsible for such determination, for output of the requisite quantity, mix ar.d ~ yuality. This requires knowledge of the requirement for concrete types of ~roducts and the normative level of satisfaction of this requirement for each - plan:~ed period and the measure of responsibility for the nonobservance of this level. This approach will also make it possible to realize the point in the decree on improving the economic mechanism which states th at responsibility for the satisfaction of the requirements of the national economy and the population for _ ~reducts of the necessary mix and quality is borne by the ministry that is the head ministry in the production of a given product. The evaluation of the five-year plan with regard to the degree of satisfaction of the requirements of the natioaal economy will make it possible to determine the ~ material responsibility of each ministry which is the head ministry in the production of a given product and of its production links for providing the national economy and population with products of the necessary assort~aent and quality since the planned magnitude of the incentive funds of a minist~y and its links will to a considerable degree depend on this evaluation. At the same time, the requirements of the national economy and the population will be determined a~t the level of needs stemming from modern advar,ces in science and technology. The degree of satisfaction of requirements and consequently the evaluation of plan indicators as well will be directly influenced by the scheduled development and production of new types of products. This must promote the material motivation of collectives of enterprises, associations and ministries to accelerate technical progress. In order to make an objective evaluation of the tautness of plans, it is important to ;elect the basic and additional indicators that in each given period are of decisive importance to the economic link and that at the same time make it possible to characterize its activity more completely. The Guidelines on the Procedure for Determining the Tautness of Plans recommend the use of the following as basic inciicators for evaluating five-year and one-year plans: the use of production canacities (areas); labor productivity; the share of output in the highest quality category (or other indicators of product quality); and the enterprise cost of production (profit resulting from the lowering of the enterprise cost of production). If necessary, the system of indicators of plan tautness may also include such indic~3tors as the number of equipment operation shifts, equipment utilizatian, output-c~pital ratio (general or active part of capital), materials-output ratio (or experi~iitures per unit of capacity or labor) as well as indicators that are s~ecific For a given branch or type of production. ~urins~ the development and initial years of quantity production, there is frequently clecl_ine ir~ the ~,rowth r~:.;:~ of ~the volume of production, labor productivitV, -~rofit-s, 3nd the utilization of production capacities and an increase in the 10 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 FOR OFFICIAL IISE ONLY I~ihor-output r3tio, capital-output ratio ar.d production costs i.n general. This can r~.sult in the tem~orary lowering of the tzutness coefficient for a number of indicators and to the lowering of the size of the material incentive fund which lessens the motiv~tion of economic links to master the production of new products ~ and to increase the volume of such production. The basic principles governinp the formation and expenditure of incentive funds in the llth Five-Ycar Plan call for the establishment of higher norms governing contributions to funds for production associations (enterprises) that significantly increase the production of new, highly effective producer goods and new consumer goods. The realization of this point would facilitate the inclusion of - the share of new products in the highest quality cateogry in the overall volume of production among the basic indicators of the evaluat~on of the tautness of the nlans. At the same time, the role of a given indicatcr should be strengthened in the evaluation of the activity of economic links and in the formation ~f material incentive funds. It would be expedient to include two product quality indicators in the plan: the share of output in the highest quality category in the total volume of production and the share of new products of the highest quality cateogry in the overall volume of production. Norms should be established on the basis of the same indicators. The share of new products should be calculated in percent :3s the ratio of the volume of production in the highest quality category mastered in the last three years to the total volume of. commodity output. Since product development and the production ot new products during the first few years increase the tautness of production activity and frequently lower the basic indicators of the work of the economic link, we believe that the share of new outpu~ should function as a compensatory indicator. In such a case, considerably more caei~ht should be given to the share of new products in total output in compar- ~ ison with other indicators in the calculation of the overall coefficient of plan tautness. When the share of new products is appropriately reflected in the integral evaluation of the tautness of plans, this will permit economically justifi~d increases in the planned size of the material incentive fund and the establishment of higher normative contributions for production associations and ~nterprises that pian the development and production of new products. Normative indica-tors determined by the method indicated above will be technically and economically substantiated norms of effectiveness of the production of economic links. '!'hey may be individual for each enterprise (association) or uniform for a grcup of enterprises or subbranch and in the case of individual indicators--for the branch as a whole. In our opinion, the evaluation of indicators in the draft five-year plan will be objective when it is made through comparison with production effectiveness norms elaborated and ratified for the five-year plan for each enterprise, association and ministry before work commences on the drafting of the five-year plan. The experience of plan evaluation in Minsel'khozmash [Ministry of Tractor and A~ricultural Machine Building] and Minelektronprom [Ministry of the ;~lectroilics Industry] confirms the practical possibility and expedience of such an ~ipFroach . The Basic Principles Governing the Formation and Expenditure of the Material Incentive Fund and the Fund for Sociocultural Measures and Housing Construction in 1981-1985 specify that the planned size of the funds in industry be calculated in two st-ag~s on the basis of a system of norms differentiated for individual years 11 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY oF tr~e fiv~-ye~r ~lan which in turn are crj.l_culated on the basis of fund-forming in~~licator_~ -ind tf~e sum of Funds indicated in the cocitrol figures for the five-year Plan. 'Ctie rr~gnitude of the control f~gur~s for t'~? funds is not linked to the tautness of control figures according tc fur~d-forming figures btit, as noted above, is adjusted according to deviations between them and the adopted p]_an indicators. Under such conditinns, there may arise economically unjustified differences in the planned size of funds and in the norms governing their formation. At the same time, stable norms governing the formation of material incentive funds (which are calcul~ted on the basis of adopted planned fund-form~ng indicators) cannot play an active, stimulating role or motivate enterprises to consider the total utiliz- ation of production reserves in the five-year plan. Moreover, the differentiation of norms governing the formation of incentive funds for various years of the five- year plan withou~t regard to the tautness of plan indicators means that enterprises establish rewards of varying magnitude for the attainment of one and the same result during the five-year plan. We made tentative calculations that indicate that the norms governing the formation of the material incentive fund depending on the dynamics of the growth rate and level of indicators will ceteris paribus differ substantially for various years of the five-year plan (see following table). 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 l. Growth of labor product.ivity in � oL plan for 1980.......... 103.8 107.8 112.1 116.9 122.2 2. Ditto for year (increment)..... 3.8 4.0 4.3 4.8 5.3 3. Share of products in the highest quality category in total outplit (in o) 15 18 21 24 26 4. The part of the material incent- ive fund that is earmarked for the stimulation of each fund- forming indicator (in millions of rubles) 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 5. Total pro.fits (in millions of rubles) 50 50 50 50 50 6. ^dorms governina tYie form~tion of material incentive funds (in o of profits): (a) for each percentage point oF increase in labor c~roductivi ty (Line 4:2:5X100).......... 1.316 1.250 1.163 1.042 0.943 (b ) for each percent~~~;e ~~oint of increase in thc share of tiroducts ir. the hi~hest qu~l.ity category in total output (I,ine 4:3:5X100).......... 0.333 0.278 0.238 0.208 0.192 _l2 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 FOR OF ~L USF. ONT~ i~ :1:~ th~_ fri.ven exami~,:le shows, the greater the plani-ied results on thc Uasi~ of fund- Forming indicator~, the lesser the significance of the reward relative to profit and hence the lesser the reward for each percentage point of increase in labor oroductivity and the share of output in the highest quality category in total output, Since differences in the levels and growth rates of indicators at the enterprise may be directly associated with the effectiveness of the activity of the work force, such differentiation of norms for various years of the five- year nlan may reduce the dependence of the size of the reward on the performance of the en~terprise collective. In our view, the planned size of the material incentive fund and differentiated norms governing its formation for various years of the five-year plar~ should be established on the basis of the material incentive fund calculated on the basis of a unirorm national economic norm with due regard to the objective evaluation of - indicators in the plan of a given year (according to the degree of satisfaction of the recitiirement for products of a given economic link and the degree of tautness of the ~lan). ~de believe ttiat aii .important part in the determination of the planned magnitude of ' incentive funds should be played by the calculated material incentive fund, the magnitude of which should taken for the basic initial norm governing the formation of funds for all branches. It may be the measure of reward for attaining normative ir.dicator5 of the effectiveness of production and may be uniform for all ministries and within ministries--for enterprises and associations. We agree with those economists who propose that the initial calculated magnitude of funds and the norms ~overning th~ir forma+_ion be based on a single magnitude for all branches and that this ma,gnitude be differentiatec~ depending on the tautness of the plans and the results oF economic activity". Th~ calculated material incentive ~und and the corresponding initial norm should be determined in percent of the wase fund on the basis of national economic proportions adopted in the five-year plan between the size of the material incentive fund and the size of the wage fund with due regard to the share of the wages of engineering-technical personnel and blue-collar workers in the latter. Such an aporoach will make it possible to establish and maintain planned proportions between the incentive fund and the wage fund. The normative calculated fund like the normative effectiveness of production should be determined and communicated to ministries, associations and enterprises before work begins on the drafting of the five-year. plan. Th~ ratification of the normative effectiveness of. production and the normative calculate~l mat~~rial incentive fund for.economic links will make it possible to create a more effectiv~ mechanism for forming incentive funds. The following seqtience can be proposed for the development of this mechanism. %~See, f=or example, A. I. Milyukov, "Pooshchritel'nyye fondy na predpriyatii (Problemy obr=~zovaniya i ispol.'zovaniya)" [Incentive Funds at the Enterprise (Problems in Their Formation and Use], Izdatel'stvo "Ekonomika," 1974, p 113; G. M. Siluanov, "Metody stimulirovaniya povysheniya effektivnosti proizvodstva" [P9ethods of Stimulating the Increased Effectiveness of Production], Izdatel'stvo "Finansy," 1976, p. 29. - 13 FOR OFFICIAL USF. ONLY APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 FOR OFFICIAL l1SF ONLY Ministries, associations and enterprises whose five-year plan indicators corres~ond to the established norms of production effectiveness must articulate planned material incentive funds ir. the volume of the calculated fund, i. e., the established normative percentage of the planned wage fund. Since the attainment of normative indicators of the degree of satisfaction of requirements and tautness of plans is equal to the normative magnitude of the contribution of each economic link to social production and to national income, the sum of the reward in the amount of a un.iform norm for the national economy must correspond to this contribution. An increase (decrease) in plan indicators compared with normative indicators means an increase (decrease) in the actual contribution to social production, which must be properly reflected in the planned size of the material incentive fund. Therefore, if the indicators adopted on the basis of the five-year plan deviate from the normative effectiveness of production, it is necessary to correct the normative calculated fund and the planned material incentive iund in comparison with the calculated volume accordingly. The comparison of plan indicators with normative indicators makes it possible to determine particular coefficients on the basis ~f indicators and integral ccefficients for evaluating five-year and one-year plans which should be used as the basis for correcting tlie norma~tive calculated material incentive fund. The norms derived as a result of the corrections will be norms used to determine the planned material incentive fund of a ministry, association and enterprise for various years of the five-year plan. Then it is necessary to establish stable norms on the basis of ~und-forming indicators. The planned material incentive fund should be determined for various years of the five-year plan on the basis of the planned norm and planned wage fund with regard to the share of the wages of engineering-technical personnel and white-collar ~rorkers in the total wage fund. It should be distributed into the agpropriate shares that form on the basis of each fund-forming indicator and stable norms for the formation of the fund based on an individual indicator should be determines accordingly. The substantiation of stable norms and the formation of the material incentive fund in the course of a five-year plan depend on the correlation in which the planne~l material incentive fund is divided by each indicator for the calculation of no.rms. A more precise approach and substantiation are required here. For example, the ciivision of the material incentive fund into two equal parts (50 percent for the growth of labor productivity and 50 per.cent for quality) may in z number of cases result in unjust differences in norms and actual size of rnaterial incentive funds from one enterprise to another. This stems primarily from the fact that the quality indicator (the share of products in the highest quality cate~ory from enterprise to enterprise) fluctuates within a substantial range. Thus the formation of 50 percent of the incentive fund on the basis of the share of output in the highest quality category at an enterprise where this indicator is 1-2 perc~~nt and at an enterprise where it is 95 percent or higher is evidently without economic justification. In our view, the substantiation of norms can be increased if the planned material incentive fund is divided into two parts and if we determine the share of products in the hi~hest quality category in total output in order to calculate the normative quality indicator. For example, let us say ttiat 25 percent of the enterprise's outout is in the hi~;hest :~uality category. The material incentive fund should be divided between the share of output in the highest quality category and the growth of 1a'.?or ^ro~iucti~~i.ty in a orooor~lion of 1:3. At the same time, it is advisable that ~ perr*~issible sh~r~, in t~ fuzd betweeri 1C and 60 per^ent, for exarnpiE, b~: established ~or the aroduct quality indicator. ~ince a considF,rable part oi the ' 14 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 T~OR OF'FICiAL USF. ONLY material i.ncentive Fund falls to the share of the labor productivity indicator in thc event '~he share of output in the highest quality cate~ory is stnall, norms gover~ning additional contributions for~ overf~ilfillment and reduction norms for underfulfillment of the ,iven indicator must be established with due re~ard to this circumstance. Thus the planned material incentive fund is divirled into parts that form on the basis of each of the fund-forming indicators that must be the basis for determining stable norms governing contributions based on fund- forming indicators for various years of the five-year pl.an. According to the methods proposed by us, the calculated size of the material incentive fund for a five-year period and for the various years of the five-year plari will depend on this fund's single initial norm, on the size of the wage fund and the share of wages of engineering-technical personnel and white-collar workers in the wage fund, which will ensure equal "starting" conditions for enterpri~es in all branches of industry. ~s already noted, the uniform calculated size of the fund is ~lifferentiated depending on the evaluation of the level of indicator.s f~r various years of the five-yeai~ pla_n according to the degree of satisfaction of needs and the tautness of basic plan indicators. The size of the fund will subsequently differentiated for various years of the five-year plan depending on the growth rates and level of fund-forming indicators and the planned volume of profit for the corresponding year. This will orient enterprises, associations and ministries toward the maximum satisfaction of the needs of the national economy for their products, toward the effective use of modern advances of science and technoloay and all production reserves in production, and toward the ~doption and fulfillment of taut five-year plans. COPYRIGHT: Izdatel'stvo "Pravda", "Voprosy ekonomiki", 1981 5013 CSO: 1828/127 - 15 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 FO12 OE~F!('1�~1. ii~I: OtiI.V Lt1BOR UDC 911.3:31.2 NORTHERN OB' RIVER REGION'S CHANGING MANPOWER SUPPLY ANALYZED Moscow IZVESTIYA VSESOYUZNOGO GEOGRAFICHESKOGO OBSHCHESTVA in Russian No 2, Mar-Apr 81 pp 130-136 _ (Article by S. Ye. Mozgalin: "Some Problems in the Formation of Population and Labor Resources in the Northern Ob' River Region"] (Text] One of the major aspects of the development and distribution of productive forces in the USSR in accordance with CPSU economic strategy is the extensive use of the natural resources of underdeveloped regions. An important part of this work will be th~ development of oil and gas resources in West Siberia, where a massive territorial production complex is being established in the north ([1], p 226). Economic construction in this regionl is being conducted in little-explored terri- tory. During the initial stages of its exploration, the area was almost unpopulated. Now it has a fairly large population and the settlement patterns have essentially taken on distinct outlines and centers. The experience in the settlement and forma- - r.ion of manpower resources in this region has been unique; in terms of scales and speed, it is unparalleled in Soviet and foreign practice. It is also interesting because the population of the northern part of West Siberia, although essentially new, is nonetheless settling in the territory that has been populated for a long time and was extensively explored by minor northern ethnic groups. 1'he devclopment of the oi1 and gas resources of Tyumenskaya and Tomskaya Oblasts cuincided almost exactly with the interval between the population censuses of 1959 znd 1979. In these 20 years radical changes took place in the scales, structure and settlement patterns of the population (see tables 1 and 2). When the extensive development of the region's natural resources began, nine-tenths ~~f its entii-e population was concentrated in its southern half. By that time there was a fairly l~~rge population here (Table 2) and nine cities (two of which could be cl.assified as large cities). The scales of the subregion's industrial development were not great and the level of urbanization was low: Due to the small number of cities, there were no settlements of the urban type, the urban population represented less than 40 percent of the total and there was no urban population whatsoever in the majority of administrative zones. Rural population density in farming areas was 2-4 per.sons per square kilometer, or close to the average indicator of the West Siberian steppe and forest steppe zones. 1. The definitive name for this region has not been specified in scientific litera- ture, bul the one we use is employed most often. 16 ~ ~ .Y APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 GOR O[~!'!('I,U. I'SI' (}'~t.l' In 1959 only ]_0 Percent of the population lived in the northern subregion, including 7.6 percent of ttie total urban population, whicil was c~ncentrated in the centers of the national districts. The rural population was confined to river valleys (the new population, primari.ly Russian) and the traditional pasture lands, cattle drives and huntin~ grounds (the native population). The industrial development of natural resources had a significant effect on the size, structure and settlement patterns of the southern subregion's population and radically changed the population in the north. In the south these changes were primarily of a quantitative nature. They resulted fr.om this subregion's evolution into the center of oil and gas resource development in the northern Ob' zone. Here the urban population and oblast centers grew, par- ticularl_y Tyumen'. The absolute size of the rural population decreased somewhat. Table 1 Dynamics of Territorial Population Structure in Ob'-Irtysh Region, % P o p u 1 a t i o n Total Urban Rural Region Territory 1959 1979 1959 1979 1959 1979 Entire Ob'-Trtysh region 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 Breakdown: Souttier.n subregion 25.7 89.9 73.6 92.4 69.4 88.4 80.6 _ Tomskaya Oblast 18.1 40.6 31.5 50.9 33.0 34.5 28.8 Southern Tyumenskaya Oblast 7.6 49.3 42.1 41.5 36.4 53.9 51.8 Northern subregion 74.3 10.1 26.4 7.6 30.6 11.6 19.4 Khanty-Mansiyskiy Autonomous Okrug 31.4 6.7 20.7 4.6 25.9 8.0 11.0 Yamalo-Nenetskiy Autonomous Okrug 42.9 3.4 5.7 3.0 4.7 3.6 8.4 Fundamental qtialitative changes took place during this time in the northern subr'egion. An urban network sprang up here--it has not evolved into a system as yet, and all of its future li.nks have not yet come into being, but this is already an obvious terri- torial network of urban settlements. There are 28 urban settlements within this subre~,ion (22 of. them founded after 1960), includi.ng Surgut, which has not only become an important regional organizational and economic center of new develop- ment [7J, but al.so the first large city in tt-~is vast territory. 13etween 1959 and 1979 the population of the Khanty-Mansiyskiy Autonomous Okrug increased ].3.3-fold and that of Yamalo-Nenetskiy Okrug increased 3.7-fold. The dif- ferences in tile population growth rates were connected with the scales and priori- Cies oi= itati~ral rE:source development: The oil and gas deposits of the Khanty- Mansiysl:iy Autunomous Olcrug were developed first because they were situated more convenientl.y in the economic and geographic sense. The development and, consequently, thc~ settlement of the Yamalo-Nenetskiy Autonomous Okrug did not speed up until the 1970's. 17 HOR OFFICIAL USE O?~LY APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007102/09: CIA-RDP82-00854R000400040059-9 FOR O[~ FEC1:~L t~SE: OtiLI' a~ ~ rn I DD 4J t~ N O~ Vl ~7 N CO rl R7 L.r ~ ~D ul ~O ul f~ 1~ ifl Cd 1.J �rl ~-1 . N O R1 O~ W G C U p u'1 00 Q~ 00 N O ^ 'n N~ ~ fa 3-i O~ M M ~T r'1 M N N ~(n 41 ~ r-1 a ~n c~ cd ~ ri ~7 ~1'1 M M V1 ~ ~-1 r~ M 1~ I~ M ~O N O�rl Q'i O~f1 GY ~ 00 I~ ~ ~ ~-1 r-1 �rl fn ~ ~ 1.~ �rl O~ ca a ~ ~ a~ rn r~-I w ~ ~ ~ ~n u1 ~ c+~ �~-1 f~ ~-~-1 ~ i-i ~-I 7 O ,c] N N f~ M � O � O � O L~+ N a ~ ao ~n rn ua c~ w M~ ~o a~ O\ ~ N rl r-1 N ~,i-' a rn~~ ~ .o rn o ~ b ~ b ~ v ~ G~+-~ rn ~-I ~o r-1 u~ ~-i ~ ~ o ~ rn 1-~ rn N irl a0 � O � O O ~ ~--i O ~7 N rl N M W ~t N W 41 O J-~ r--I H r-i r-i r-1 '-1 ~ ~ N A ~ N O~ O~ ~O u'1 O~ ~D r-I N ~ O~? ~ .--1 I~ M M O~ M O ~ 1.~ rl Q~ O 00 N u'1 N ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ fA fY.~ O~ M r-I I~ ~t N rl r-I ~d ~ C rn '-1 O ~ ~O ~-I ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ a.J R1 ~'-I r-1 r-I P4 O�ri ~ ~ ~ ~ 'b ' ~ a ~ rn r~ ~ ~ ~ �o .o o i~ u p 1J 1~ rl O~ ~D N N ~Y' 00 U a a rn I ~ ~ ~n .o ~n s d G ro ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ b ,c ~ a~ m u G ~ v1 O v1 ~O o~ ~tl ~ N al 1.~ 1~ O O~ I I~ ~D M N ~ N ~ H �rl r-I p~ N U a0 ~ ~ ~11 rl r~ O~ O~ a ~d ~-i ~ ~ r-I tA U ~ o ~ rnI ~ o a~o ~ ^ ~ ~zab a ro ~ N N ~ 4J 1.l . ^ ~ N W E-+ Q~ Q~ c'~1 1~ ~D ~O .7 N N M~�rl O u1l M u'1 ~7 O o0 N ~ ~rl O~ CO ~O I~ O~ ~-1 O N r~ r-1 r-I N 1~ P~ lJ ~ M �rl td 4~ ~ ~ ~ I ~ ~ I~ ~O ~/1 O ~rl N ~ O ~ G ~ .-I ~ N r~ O ~ ~ ~ ~ O m �r-1 o O" R~ �r~ O M 00 N 1.1 1.1 ~ N a) 3a u"~ O ~O M ~ r-I N O a' U1 rl p(nj C~ �1n, ~ I rl C~l N ~D O O ~ O C7 (1~ !n ~~0 ~ O ~ RS ~ f~ @ N ~ ~ U O~.5L 7~ O N~ ~ ~ O U U u1 tn F-~ �rl Ul N r-i 1~ ~7 r-1 ~-I O a) O u ~ 3-+ ~!A v1 u'1 r-I M O ~ ^ fn ,'F'., O S.+ O r~ ~7 M ri ~ ~ ~ ' �ri ~ ,C 4-+ r-~ _ . y,l H +-i O pp ~d b0 R'.+ r-I ~ O cn C~ ~ c~ r~ a ~ p, ~ H cn rn O i~a'~o ~ o .x o .x o ~ o = c~ ~ a ~ G�~ ~tl C m G�~-1 at C~ .o p.,' O 3~+ 00 T L S-+ S-+ b0 I 9, O I t1I O O 'U 41 N c0 tn ~ N~ N Ol 7, ~ oD O+~ p o0 N .C .yG .`l ~U .C ~ ctl .C 3-+ u uI O~ r--1 41 O~ ~ C N t1~ td t~ '-1 ~ ~ .-1 .O ~ G RS ~ ~ F+ u ~ O ~n al ~ 7 E ~ ~ ~ ~ cU N ~ `~L ~ G1 7 aG u ~ W tl~ ~ E-~~ cAHO ~ u~ ~~~0 ~7~0 ~ ~ ~ W ~ E-~ 1~ R ONFIC(AL USE O~LY APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400044459-9 i~c~i< c~~~~~tc ~:~t. t~~t' ~~`t.ti T!~~~ inclu~;trinl cl~~v~~l~~mc~uf c~l the territi>ry af hoth okru~;s brou~;liC al~out the raE~id c;roweh ot th~ urban population. The need to conduct exploratory work and huild Iin~ar facilities, however, led to the relatively raPid growth ~f tht~ rural ~~n~~~il~tion as wet] (Tabl~: 2) . The ethn~.c composi.tion of thc~ pc7~ul~~t t~~n ~~f hutf~ diti~ri~~Ls ch;~nged: Northern ethnic groups accounted for a lower percentage (par- ticularly in cities) while Russians, Ukrainians and Belorussians accounted for a l~igher one. In connection with the specific economic specialty of this subre~ion, representatives of al.l union and autonomous republics in the nation took an active part in its development, and the groups from Azerbaijan, Tatariya and Bashkiriya were particul.arly large. Tt~e development oF the northern Ob' region radically changed the social structure. ' The corresponding data of the 1979 census have not been published as yet, but a comparison of the information taken from the 1959 and 1970 censuses and numerous sur.veys conducted in ttlc siibregion indicates the basic trends. A change in ciemo~raphic patterns is characteristic of the entire region and, in E~:~rticular, of the norther.n subregion: The oldest and youngest age groups are decreasin~ in size, the working-age groups are growing younger and men account for a higher percentage of the working-age population, particularly men over the age of 2A (this is due to the fact that women between the ages of 18 and 29 are more often involved in migration and are more likely to stay in new regions). Tl~ere is an~ther tendency toward a change in the employment structure. The rela- tive numher of persons employed in indiistry, construction and transportation is constantly rising in the Oh'-Irtysh region as a whole, and the relative number of persons employed in the non-pruduction sphere began to rise at a more rapid rate in the 1970's. In the southern subregion the rise in the relative number of indus- trial workers has been particularly rapid, especially in the processing branches. In the northern subregion the absolute and relative numbers of persons employed in industry are rising, but more slowly than in the southern part of the region. This is a result of the present massive scale of construction work in the northern Ob' zone. Construction is the leading element in this subregion's employment structure. The northern subregion is also distinguished by a relatively high number of persons emplo~~ed in transportation, which is typical of the initial stages of development. I~1 comparison to ttie new settlements, the oil and gas regions in the northern Ob' -r.one are di5tinguished hy the need to constantly exploit more and more new depos- its (2~. For this reason, rhe initial stage of development will continue here in the f~reseeabl.e future and, consequently, there will be a high relative number of persons emplc~yed in construction and transportation. This will preserve the above- mentioned features of the sex and age structure of the population for a long time. Chan~es in the size and structure of the population of the Ob'-Irtysh region are the resulr of the rapid rise in the demand for manpower and are connected primarily with the recruitment of people from outside the region. In the southern part of the region, the hi~h rates of economic construction have created certain difficul- ties in the recruitmc~nt and maintenance of a labor force (the shortage of comfort- able housing, the underdevelopment of the public service sphere, long delays in the SZt15f1CC1011 of demand and so forth). On the whole, however, the natural and sor_ioeconomic conditions here are typical of developed regions in West Siberia. 19 hOR OFF'ICIAL USE: ON1.Y APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 rc~k c~i~t'!('I:~1. U~F: O`L1~ Therefore, tiie problems connected with finding manpower for the southern subregion are neither distinctive nor particularly acute, in our opinion. In other words, we do not feel that they call for any lcind of special approach. The situation is different in Che northern Ob' areas: The low level of economic development has created several local problems in satisfying the demand for man- power. Additional local problems are connected with the region's specialization in the oil and gas industry. On the whole, to provide the northern Ob' region with manpower, it will be necessary to not only recruit workers for the region but also to keep them here. The recruitment of manpower for the northern Ob' region must be examined in its following basic aspects. 1. The quantitative aspect: The extensive nature of development calls for the recruitment of hug~ numbers of workers. Besides this, the unfavorable natural and socioeconomic conditions here require additional manpower for the public service sphere [4]. In all, the development of oil and gas resources in the northern Ob' region will necessitate the recruitment of hundreds of thousands of workers. 2. The qualitative aspect: The northern Ob' region has specific manpower require- ments. Just as any other region of new development (particularly those with a severe climate), it will require more young men. But the region also needs many qualif.ied personnel. This is connected, firstly, with the need for intensifica- tion in all types of economic activity to minimize expenditures of living labor and, secondly, with the great variety of economic activities that will be conducted h~re on a sizeable scale.2 - 3. The geographic aspect: Different parts of the norther.n Ob' region are on dif- ferent levels of economic development [3]. Territorial production complexes are already taking shape in some parts (ancillary and service branches and a relatively developed public service sphere already exist in addition to the extractive indus- ~ try). Oil and ~as f-iel.ds in other areas require the minimum production and social infrastructure. In stil.l other areas the construction of industrial facilities and liiiear ~inits plays the main role. In a fourth category the territory and mineral resources are only being studied. Each stage makes specific demands on personnel and determines the need for manpower. 2. It woul.d be impossible to list all of them here. We will list just the main "blocks": 1) explor.atory work, connected not only with the prospecting of new deposit~, but also with the establishment of oil fields and other industriaZ facilities, supply lines and cities; 2) various types of construction (includ- ing a high percentage of pipeline and oil field construction projects); 3) oil and gas extraction; 4) other types of industrial activity (including logging); 5) all types of transport (with a higher percentage of moror and air transport); G) public services; 7) research, planning and design. In different parts of the nortl~ern Oh' region these types of activity will be combined in different ways, but on tlie whole they create a greater demand for personnel in a broad variety of professions and specialties. ?_0 , O\LY' APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 rc~u ot~E~[c~t~~i. ~~~F~ o`t.ti~ In the northern Ob' region the problem of keeping manpower is particularly acute. Manpower must be recruited on a massive scale, the new population is highly mobile and there is a significant positive balance of migration, but the migrants are also less likely to stay, particularly in some cities and oil and gas zones. The reasons for this are evident. In the initial stages of development the severe weather has a significant effect on the stability of the population. But the effect of this factor should not be overestimated: The example of a number o� cities in the north (especially Noril'sk) proves that the unfavorable effect of natural conditions on population formation is surmountable. There are reliable ways of doing tliis: a reduction in the proportional amount of work out~oors, the mechanization and automation of labor processes, the more extensive use of organ- - ized forms of manpower recruitment (particularly from regions in the central belt of the RSFSR and Belorussia), the priority development of residential, cultural and consumer construction (according to "special northern" designs), the more - compact layout of cities and settlements to reduce time spent outdoors in the cold, aiid a developed transportation network in cities and production areas to reduce the amount of time spent traveling to and from work and cultural and consumer establishments. Obviously, not all of these measures are equally suitable in various regions, but they can be effectively used on a much broader scale than at present. For example, much more comfortable house trailers could be used exten- sively, not only dtiring the construction stage of development or in special resource exploitation assignments, but also in geological prospecting work (for example, highly comfortable prefabricated residences could be brought in by helicopter). Tt~is would require larger initial expenditures, but it would help to keep personnel in the region (including qualified personnel with local work experience) and heighten the efficiency of geological prospecting. The lowest rate of personnel stability is found in regions characterized primarily by the construction and establishment of industrial facilities (where there is a prevalence of work in the open air with a relatively low level of inechanization and uncomfortable living conditions); here the number of new arrivals is only slightly in excess of the number of departures. The acute manpower shortage - increases the volume of incomplete construction, lowers the use coefficient of equipment, disrupts construction schedules and so forth. The actual cost of con- struction exceeds the estimated cost of some facilities in the northern Ob' region by 30-40 percent or more, and around one-fourth of this rise in costs is connected with the manpower shortage and the discrepancy between the qualifications of this manPower and the requirements of construction. In cost terms, the negative effect of the l.ow 1eve1 of manpawer stability considerably exceeds the expenditures needed to establish living and working conditions that would guarantee a stable labor force. [dith a view to just these examples, we should note that when the manpower problem is beinb solved in the northern Ob' region, stability must be given priority over recruitment, and this is even more important in the earlier stages of development. It should be stressed that the recruitment and stabilization of manpower are closely related. For example, most of the newcomers in the north are young people, generally without any skills: They usually undergo a brief training course and are then often used in unskilled work which does not correspond to the educational level of the younK workers and their ideas about the prestige and appeal of dif- ferent jobs. 21 FOR OFF(C'IAL USE ONI.Y APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 r�oh o~~r��i:~i. 'Tt?e resulting problem has several aspects. In the first place, the mechanism and structure of manpower recruitment must be improved. For example, among young workers the highest rate of stability is characteristic of those who arrive either as soon as they are discharged from the Sov~.et Army or within 3 years after this discharge. Apparently, this should be taken into consideration in the practice of organized recruitment. The stability of manpower will also be promoted by the furtr.er development of the system of vocational and techni~al personnel training in the Ob'-Irtysh region through a network ^f ~pe~ialized state vocational training - institutes. But there is also another side to the problem: At present the machine- labor ratio in new regions of gas and oil resource development is still inadequate. This means that there is still a significant demand for unskilled labor and, con- sequently, there are still prerequisites for a highly unstable labor force. Higher teclinical standards of de-:elopment and the rating of work positions in each zone and center of development constitute one of the main ways of reducing personnel turnover. In summation, we can stress the following. l. In a short period of time, a large population and labor force have taken shape in the northern Ob' region, largely satisfying the local demand for manpower and ensuring the successful attainment of objectives connected with the creation of a major oil and gas production base in the region. 2. The basic settlement patterns of the nor.*_'~ern Ob' region have now been estab- lished; production centers are being rapidly developed in oil and gas regions and the city of Surgut has become the production center of the entire northern Ob' zone. 3. The main tasks involved in supplying the region with manpower in the foreseeable future include the following: the consideration of regional peculiarities in the practice of manpower recruitment; the reduction of proportional expenditures of living labor in total social expenditures (higher technical standards of development and the rating of work positions, including jobs in the least developed regions); the stabilization of the labor force through the improvement of living and working conditions, specialized vocational and technical training for personnel, the improvement of terri.torial settlement patterns and the improvement of urban planning. BIBLIOGRAPHY [1] "rlateri.aly XXV s"yezda KPSS" [Materials of the 25th CPSU Congress], Moscow, Gospol.itizdat, 1976. [2j Volnev, P. V., "An Inquiry into the Choice of Methods of Developing Tyumenskaya Oblast's Oil Resources," in "Priroda i ekonomika Tyumenskogo Priob'ya" [The Natural and Economic Conditions of the Tyumen' Cis-Ob' Region], Tyumen`, 1978. [3] Vorob'yev, V. V. and riisevich, K. N., "Problems Connected with Population and Labor Resources in Regions of New Development in Siberia," in "Geografiya naseleniya v sisteme kompleksnogo ekonomicheskogo i sotsial'nogo planirovaniya" [Population Patterns in the System of Comprehensive Economic and Social Plan- ning], Leningrad, 1979. {~t)R OFF'[CIr1L USE OtiI..Y APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9 APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/49: CIA-RDP82-00850R040400040059-9 rok orN~c~n~. iJSE ONI.v [4J Vorob'yev, V. V., Ishmuratov, B. M., Kosmachev, K. P., Misevich, K. N. and Mikhaylov, Yu. P., "The Znitial Development of Territory as a Geographic Problem," in "Geograficheskoye issledovaniye i problemy ekonomicheskogo i sotsial'nogo planirovaniya v usloviyakh zrelogo sotsializma" [Geographic Research and Problems in Economic and Social Planning in the Mature SocialisC Society], Leningr3d, 1980. [5] "Itogi Vsesoyuznoy perepisi naseleniya 1959 g. RSFSR," Moscow, Gosstatizdat, - 1963. [6] "Naseleniye SSSR. Po dannym Vsesoyuznoy perepisi naseleniya 1979 g." Moscow, Politizdat, 1980. [7] "Prognozy rasseleniya i planirovki krupnykh gorodov Kraynego Severa" [Forecasts of Settlement Patterns and Layout of Large Cities in the Far North], Leningrad, Stroyizdat, 1974. COPYRIGHT: Izdatel'stvo "Nauka", "Izvestiya Vsesoyuznogo geografich~skogo obshchestva", 1981 8588 CSO: 1828/119 END 23 FOR OFFIC[AL USE ONLY APPROVED FOR RELEASE: 2007/02/09: CIA-RDP82-00850R000400040059-9