DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE PROPOSED REPORT ON H.R. 4836 -- LAND REMOTE SENSING COMMERCIALIZATION ACT OF 1984

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3
Release Decision: 
RIFPUB
Original Classification: 
K
Document Page Count: 
15
Document Creation Date: 
December 21, 2016
Document Release Date: 
September 11, 2008
Sequence Number: 
17
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
March 27, 1984
Content Type: 
MEMO
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3.pdf961.49 KB
Body: 
Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 EXECUTI. - OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT OFFICE OF MANAGEMENT AND BUDGET WASHINGTON. D.C. 20503 March 27, 1984 LEGISLATIVE REFERRAL MEMORANDUM Legislative Liaison Officer Department of Commerce 'Central Intelligence Agency National Security Council Department of Transportatic Office of Science and Technology Department of the Interior Federal Communications Commission General Services Administration Department of State Department of Agriculture National Aeronautics & Space Administration SUBJECT: Department of Justice proposed report on ~ p . U u 4836 -- Land Remote Sensing Commercia~. "IV ' Y/1 4"A 1"'~ D q, ' of' i0 CJ /W? The Office of Management and Budget requests the views of. your agency on the above subject before advising on its relationship to the program of the President, in accordance with OMB Circular A-19. A response to this request for your views is needed no later than COB -- Tuesday, April 10, 1984. Oral comments acceptable. Questions should be referred to William Maxwell (395-3890), ffi ce the legislative analyst in this o Ja e tC Rrlr? /fc$Y Assistant Director for Legislative Reference Enclosures cc: Scott Gudes Tim Sprehe Mike Horowitz Frank Seidl Dan Taft Jeff Struthers Bill Hughes Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 U. S. Department 'Justice Office of Legislative Affairs Washington, D.C. 20530 Office of the Assistant Attorney General Honorable James H. Scheuer Chairman, Subcommittee on Natural Resources, Agriculture Research and Environment Committee on Science and Technology ? House of Representatives 'Washington, D.C. 20515 Dear Mr. Chairman: This is in response to, H.R. ?u4836quthe thRemotee Department of Justice on ^the Act'). The Department of Commercialization Act of 1984 Justice does not object to enactmenof this legislation if amended as suggested herein. 1. Summary of the Bill The bill provides for the transfer to the ate sector of the responsibility for operating erformed by the 'Landsat" system satellites, a function now p operated by the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration. Title I toecobill states mmercializetthoset is the policy of the United States remote-sensing functions that lend tGovernment's hemselves torrivate sector development. Section 103(c). data must, however, acquire adisSectione10land 3(a)remote-sensing be preserved. In general terms, Title II of the bill provides for the Secretary of Commerce to currenttLandsat systeme pTitletlll operate the Government's provisions designed to assure ccontontiainuns continued certaiavailn interim iof the data through private sector operation of new privately-owned land remote-sensing systems Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 after the "practical demise' of the space segment of the Landsat system. Title IV sets the conditions under which private operators of future land remote-sensing systems will be licensed. Title V provides for continued federal research and development. Title VI requires that in all circumstances users are to have "non-discriminatory" access to the data as defined in Section 104(3). 1/ Although by its express terms the bill applies only to the land remote-sensing system, and not to the meteorological system, Title VII specifically prohibits sale of the Government's meteorological system. Specifically, the contract for operation of the Landsat system provided for in Title II will be awarded on a competitive basis. Section 201(b). The Government will continue to own the data marketed by the operator. Section 202(a). Such sales may continue after the "practical demise' of the space segment of the Landsat system. Section 202(b). The contractor may use and replace elements of the system at its own expense. Section 210(c). The1Secretary of Commerce shall award the contract on the basis of financial return to the Government, technical competence, ability to satisfy all conditions of the sale, marketing ability, absence of conflicts of interest affecting access to the data, and ability of the contractor to effect a smooth transition from Government to private operation and "such other factors as he shall deem appropriate." Section 203(b). Under Title III, the Secretary is to award a contract, on a competitive basis, to a private party that will offer for a period of six years the "capability of generating data of a quality at least equal to the quality of multi-spectral scanner data and of selling and delivering such data to the United States Government" in quantities equal to the annual volume of federal usage during fiscal year 1983. Section 302. The Government may contract to prepay to the operator a portion of the capital cost of the system, Section 302(b)(4). but shall not guarantee any data purchases by the United n eaStatesvernment, Government. Section 302(b)(6). unlike other buyers, will recover a rebate of at least five percent on any purchases of data. Section 303(b). The bases for the award of the contract are: (1) the cost to the 1/ According to Section 104(3)(A), the term "non-discriminatory basis" means: without preference, bias, or any other special arrangement regarding delivery, format, financing, or technical considerations which would favor one buyer or class of buyers over another. Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Government of providing the capability; (2) the technical and financial qualifications of the contractor; (3) the contractor's ability to develop the private market for land remote-sensing data; (4) the contractor's ability to supplement the basic system and maintain United States leadership in the industry; (5) the contractor's ability to be licensed under Title IV of the Act; (6) the reliability of the contractor; (7) the contractor's ability to effect a smooth transition to Title III of the Act; (8) the size of the royalty or rebate to the Sectlonfactors United States GoverCee deems and a(other 302(c). Secretary of Commer appropriate. The licensing provisions in Title IV authorize the Secretary of Commerce to license qualified private parties, consortia of private parties, or consortia of federal agencies and private parties wishing to operate their own land remote-sensing systems. Section 403. Licensees must operate any system under the following conditions: (1) operation must preserve and promote United States national security; (2) data must be available to all potential users on a non-discriminatory basis; (3) the system shall be administered by a central entity (in the case of a consortium); (4) the lic-ense shall not protect the holder from 'fair competition" from other licensees; (5) before terminating its operations, the licensee shall dispose of any orbiting satellites in a manner acceptable to the President; (6) the licensee shall make any data available to the Secretary of Commerce for archiving purposes; and (7) the licensee shall provide the Secretary of Commerce with notice of "value-added' activities and a plan for compliance with the non-discrimination requirement. Section 402(b). The Secretary determines the term of any license and has 120 days to approve any application, except that pending issues and actions to resolve them may extend the period. Section 403. Licenses may be revoked for non-compliance with all Title IV conditions. Section 401. The Secretary may also revoke, suspend, or modify a license upon written notice that there has been substantial failure to comply with any provision of the Act, any regulations, any terms, conditions, or restrictions of the license, or any international obligation or national security concern. Section 403(e). Upon request, the applicant or licensee is entitled to an agency hearing and decision by the Secretary on the record, subject to judicial review under the Administrative Procedures Act. Section 403(f). Regulations can be issued after public notice and hearings. Section 404. The Secretary can monitor remote-sensing satellite systems and 'value-added" activities by inspections and, space-related of business records after notice and ground segment -3- Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 hearing,2/ impose civil penalties of $10,000 per day for each violation. Section 405. The Secretary has the power to subpoena materials, documents, records, and testimony under oath, and tinsviolationcof.thecActs. So ectionr405(d)a or likely to be used II. Discussion The determination to commercialize the land remote-sensing system raises difficult issues. A private firm would choose to operate the system only if it believed it could derive sufficient revenues from buyers of land remote-sensing data to more than offset its costs. Thus, if'the initial fixed costs of investing in the system were very high, high prices would have to be paid by data useVeLtOmake commercialization these feasible. Since users pay very little at present data, it is not at all clear.whether the market would be able to support a private Landsat system absent large continuing Government subsidies. 3/ Even assuming, however, that potential users valued Landsat data highly, the system operator could sustain profitable prices only if it could encrypt the data and thereby prevent satellite signal piracy. The questionable outlook for commercialization is further clouded by Sections 103(b). 402(b)(2), and 601(a), which require that all potential users be granted access on a "non-discriminatory" basis. It may be that only a system of discriminatory pricing -- under which different users are charged different prices according to the value they pllaceton- the data, and thus the price they are willing to pay for -- would yield sufficient revenues to cover costs and make 2/ We assume that the reference to Title 5 is to the formal notice and hearing procedures of the Administrative Procedure Act, 5 U.S.C. S 551 et seq. Express reference to the apparently relevant the provisions precise Title 5 (5 or should be made, 3/ It is not clear that total demand for land remote-sensing data is sufficient for full commercialization of the land remote-sensing system. See Report of National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration in Response to P.L. 97-324 (January. 1983); The National Academy of Public Administration, Space Remote Sensing and the Private Sector: An Essay (March, 1983). Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 commercialization attractive. 4/ Under such a system, revenues derived from customers willing pay higher the Government. As substitute for the subsidy now provcompetitive advantage to theme, described below, a subsidy gives initial operator. This suggests that, in order to maximize the likelihood of successful commercialization without a4836ernment subsidy and with some prrequirement pothatithenprices charged for be modified to omit any If foreign policy data necessarily be "non-discriminatory." considerations require that foreign governments' concerns about the availability of td be a catodtheseedataeonnequal that foreign governments given access terms could be added. 5/ We also wish to point out that, assuming the aggregate social benefits of operating Landsat exceed the costs, and that commercialization is fe=ivate,hathe ndstransfer inefficientlynrestrict private system from public to the usage of remote-sensing data. Economic welfare iss pay at maximized when a good is sold to all buyers willing 4/ For a good description of price discriminattionain, The "decreasing cost" industries, see generally order for Economics of Regulation 123-58 (1970). ator oppeerrs of discriminatory pricing to be effective, the _ systtheem re --the would have to be able to prevent arbitrage data by customers charged a low price to customers charged a high price. Arbitrage might be such preventreedsalbyesnfore The bill, in contractual clauses prohibiting Section 603, authorizes hdiconditions on sales o scriminatory pricingf data, although the bill prohibits 5/ Under such a "most-favored nation' clause, be due foreign government users would due the terms afforded domestic purchasers overnments would befcharged, to commercialization, foreign g reently phf prices after thedemise UniteddStatesaGovernment pay for the the data governments. explicitly subsidized private sales to foreign gove for If the treatment of foreign datausers soldprivate underrtheesame termsgn policy concerns, they could as domestic users. It is, of course, possible that foreign governments might request preferential tUnitednStates politically influential private ofspecial federaltreatment Government agreement tsuch subsidieswtoltheoLandsat again, require the payment operator. _5_ Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 least marginal cost -- the cost of supplying one more unit of the good. If the marginal cost of supplying remote-sensing data is extremely low, the socially optimal use of these data is assured by charging a correspondingly low price for them -- as the Government may be doing at present. If, under private ownership, higher prices were charged (to ensure that total revenues covered total operating costs), some current users who value the data at an amount equal to or greater than marginal cost -- but at less hathe privately charged price -- would be inefficiently deprived Particularly notable in light of these principles is the language of Section 104(3)(B) stating. that sales will be deemed to be on a 'non-discriminatory basis' only if: (1) any offer to sell or deliver data is advertised in advance and is equally available to all prospective buyers; (ii)?the systeqi policy, not established or charged any price, or other term or condition in a manner which gives one class of buyer de facto favored access to data; and (111) in a case where a system operator offers volume discounts, such discounts are no greater than the demonstrable reductions in the cost of such sales. The sale of data 'on a non-discriminatory basis' does not preclude the system operator offering discounts other than volume discounts to the eanentsuch cofnthisrparagraph inconsistent with any other provision This language raises in precise terms the possibility of rate the bill's of return regulation that most troubles us. First, proposed regulatory structure in Title IV to enforce Section 104(3)(B) and other conditions confirms Second, thererisenonbasisefor regulation may the proposed degree of regulation. 6/ This inefficiency probably would exist to some extent whether the land remote-sensing industry became competitive or monopolistic. If several competitors could roficompetition the market -- as H.R. 4836 apparently assumes would somewhat constrain prices (and incidentally, limit the use of price discrimination). Nevertheless, price probably would not reach the very low level of marginal cost, and some would-be users would be denied access to the data. equal to or notwithstanding their willingness to pay exceeding marginal cost. -6- Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Unless the provision of satellite data involvesta natural e is no monopoly, or there is soeother Mofrlandfremote!sensing economic rationale for regulation satellite systems at all. Moreover the existence of natural monopoly would not necessarily j laguntion Rate of return and other forms of ift1egulatory costs do not are economically justifiable only outweigh regulatory benefits. 7/ Public availability of under prices, s, as egwell as the extn~iivbeeusedctoeshuteoffnany Pnrice Title IV that could apparently discrimination possibilities and increase theecosts oftaorateln regulatory process, would discodynamic rnarea such as land addition, in a technologically eatiuc may lanually remote-sensing, the static nature of regulon cause more damage by retarding innovation than would be caused by allowing a temporary monopolist to set prices without constraints. 8/ Title IV of the Act, furthermore, equiremed literally, provides for a panoply of regulatory L ustifiable generally where market failures 7/ Regulation is j result in inefficient levels of Prdomeoductioon forms of of goods and andtion. services or no production at all. however, have counter-productivetendencies. foateffaseeand and rate of return regulation reduces emphasizes service competition at the expense of pricenteed on competition. Since a "normal" rate of return is guara service expenditures that are includedninnaeregulated firm's rate base, the regulated company has aive 'overinvest' in services, with little regardsto cost. Inth the addition, regulation consumes significant regulating regulated firm in supporting rate requests and the renc in sorting out the large volume of data submitted with ty rate requests. A rate. regulatory process can also its these provide a licensee with incentives for inefficiency in investments and operations, and for rigidity in its rate Noll. structures and service offerings. Regulation in Theory and Practice: An Overview, inrey Fromm (ed.), Studies in Public Regulation Regulation and Its Reform 36-59 (1982). from foreign 8/ There are currently prospects for competition launched and operated systems. (e.g.. French and Japanese) enterprises, and may These systems may not be profit-making may, involve significant , senteancompetitivelcheckTonythe exercise of nevertheless, repepra United States firm. monopoly power by -7- Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 well beyond considerations of price and non-discriminatory r access. "Value-addee~a=ctofiCommerce underpSectiont402(b)(7). proposed to the Secretary are subject to imposition by the Secretary of terms, conditions, or restrictlonWeLSdof theSection Secre~aryain Section to the full enforcement hOearing, adjudicatory, and 405. 9/ Investigatory ject , administrative penalty powers are all centerediinvtheeSecretary of Commerce. Unlimited rule-making Secretary. Section 404. In short, a comprehensive new regulatory agency would be created within the Department of Commerce to regulate lcosts every of aspect implementing operations, Not ns. Nonly nly would transactional pricing sales, or developing new value added services skyrocet as each change had to be presented to the Secretary, but assuring would thatattend innovation would be elays a technology newt administrative ve process, virtual would lag in implementation, that better and cheaper data for users would be slower a marketed, tTheseuregulatory commercialization would benefits of such an costs would outweigh, in our view, any extensive regulatory scheme. While we recognize the importance of assuring compliance with our international obligations, IV achievement of this goal does not justify and can be assured by other means. Because the bill as presently drafted would structure the land remote-sensing industry as a pervasively regulated section 5 in 40 y t i o industry, the warrantless desirable be would nalthough it is probably constitutional, limit inspections to 'reasonable predictable and guidednfederale I 452 regulatory 9 Presenc8e)) (n Weed believe, however, that Section 05 405(ee)(1), which provides for seizure authiristat is es tha subjt,ect to in constitutional challenge. Subsection (e)(1) the Sthaetain carrying out his enforcement responsibilities, may "seize any object. record, or report where it reasonably appears that such was used, is being used, or is likely As a used in violation of this Act. . . .' (emphasis added). rule, warrantless searches are permissible only where the 40amake U.S. tthat443cou455 trse mpe1jtive. See exigencies of the situation Coo le v. New Hampshire, situations might involve nnrabandeorestolenloredangerousght, a movable car containing co articles that may never be found again. or misbranded drugs 9/ These enforcement powers do not create in the Secretary an independent power to litigate. Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 that threaten the national health and misbranded U.sbrS.C.anded ? food 334(a) and (grounds drugs). With respect to the present bill, we believe that legislative history specifically establishing that the authority to make warrantless seizures of objects (presumably hardware or software used in satellites), records or reports is both necessary for national security or other reasons and otherwise meets the 'exigent circumstances" rationale would be necessary in order to sustain the constitutionality of this provision. Assuming that there is a legitimate federal need for warrantless seizures, we would nevertheless recommend that, if enacted, the language of Section 405(e) be altered to meet the substantive requirements of the Fourth Amendment. The Supreme Court has generally indicated that probable cause is necessary to justify a warrantless seizure. See Coolidge v. New Hampshire, 403 U.S. at 472-73. We are aware of no Supreme Court case that expressly authorizes warrantless seizures based on less than probable cause. See, e.g., Colorado v. Bannister, 449 U.S. 1, 3 (1980) (per curiam); G M Leasing Corp. v. United States, 429 U.S. 338. 351 (1977). Although the common law "reasonable grounds to believe' standard is the substantial equivalent of the Fourth Amendment's "probable cause" requirement, see Draper v. United States, 358 U.S. 307, 310 n.3 (1959), it is not clear that the "reasonably appears' language in Subsection (e)(1) is the-equivalent of the "reasonable al analog. grounds to believe" standard or its constitutional be l"probable cause." Section 405(e)(1) would have to read: "seize any object, record or report where he has being used, or probable caueineviolationuof this Act. is about to be used Thus, as broadly as it is currently drafted, Title IV pf the bill raises fundamental policy and legal concerns. Title IV is subject to the interpretation that an extensive Title IV regulatory scheme is to be imposed. If so, we oppose and recommend its deletion in substantial part. We are also troubled about the possibility that the contractor who contracts to make data available to the Government during the six-year interim period will be provided, as a result of the contract, with a significant subsidy that will lessen the possibility of competitive entry into the market (assuming no natural monopoly). Section 302 provides that a party or parties contracting for the provision of data to the Government must be capable of providing, at a minimum, the amount of data used by the Government during fiscal year 1983. To encourage such production, Section 302 also provides ebcapital for a prepayment by the Government of aportionmof the cost of providing this capability. This Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 would be at least partially repaid to the Government through the five percent minimum rebate on United States Government data purchases, but might not be fully repaid during the contract period. Although the contractor would have no guarantee that the Government would purchase data, the subsidy could allow it to provide data at a lower cost. The rebate, then, would act as a repayment mechanism encouraging the Government to purchase from that contractor even if others offered data to the public on equivalent terms. Thus, that contractor could enjoy a significant advantage over other potential entrants. While we recognize the possible need for a subsidy to assure that land remote-sensing data will be available, we are concerned that such_a contract may make it difficult, as a practical matter, for any competing systems to be formed. The prepayment of the subsidy, under the bill as drafted, poses other significant problems. It Is unclear whether the limitation on the Title III contract that it 'shall not provide for any guaranteed data purchases by the Federal Government, Section 302(b)(6), means that the United States Government is free to purchase data from other sources or simply that no minimum level of purchases from a sole licensee is anticipated. First, if the contract is not for United States Government requirements, then incentives to repay the initial subsidy may be lessened. Although required to maintain capability for six years, the contractor may find it more in its interest to keep the subsidy and either terminate the contract, not sell to the Government or not compete vigorously for sales that, through rebates, reduce the start-up advantages given by the prepayment. Sales to private users might be substituted as the private market develops. 10/ Second, if the contract is, in fact, a requirements contract, then it raises the possibility that it may provide the contractor with an. unnecessary competitive advantage continuing beyond the term of the contract. The bill should balance generating the necessary incentive for the provision of the Government's data needs with the creation of undue competitive advantage. The foregoing discussion highlights the broad competitive issues raised by the bill. There are also more specific definitional issues raised by the bill as currently drafted. Section 203(b)(5) imposes as a criterion for selection as a provider of land remote-sensing data the "absence of any 10/ Required repayment by the end of the contract period or over a longer period might correct for this built-in disincentive. Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 conflicts-of-interest which could inhibit non-discriminatory access to such data.' While, standing alone, could be construed to bar the system operator from providing 'value-added" services regardless of whether it is a regulated monopolist, the specific reference to "value-added' activities in Sections 402(b)(7) and 405(b) may be sufficient to counter such a narrow intepretation. Leaving to the Secretary of Commerce the power to define 'value-added' may, however, by implication, impose a type of public convenience and necessity test for new services, similar to that required for facilities such of construction underctiAs notedf Communications 1934, 47 U.S.C. S 214. extensive regulatory scheme is needed here. Furthermore, Title II as whole raises serious definitional problems. There is no specification of when the Landsat operator's activities are to end and when the Title III operator's activities begin. The language in Section 201(b) concerning renewal implies a continuing contract. It is also unclear what the source of compensation for an operator will be -- whether this compensation will take the form of fees from Government appropriations alone or sales to private users or both. Our concern with competitive issues in Titles III and IV would extend to Title II were the same operator to gain a continued competitive advantage from its Title II licenseaand cop.initiativeskbyiitselfforoothers. competitive Additionally, the criterion in Section 402(b)(4) that no license shall protect the holder from 'fair competition' should be clarified, so as to fulfill two distinct and important functions. First, specific language should be added to the general language of Section 607, that '[t]he requirements of this Act are in addition to, and not in lieu of, any other ' to"insure against any implicit repeal of tovi iitsrustolaws. We suggest of saw, est the following language: 'Nothing in this Act shall be deemed to create an exemption or defense to any action under the federal antitrust laws, as defined in Section 1 of the Clayton Act (15 U.S.C. S 12),ordthehFederal Trade Commission Act (15 U.S.C. S 41-58); provided, contract entered into by the Secretary in accordance with this Act shall not be deemed to violate such statutes.' Second, Section 402(b)(4) should preclude an unduly restrictive licensing process that might exclude potential entrants. The section should specifically provide that the Secretary is not to grant exclusive licenses, or to consider the economic effects of entry of additional firms into the land remote-sensing or "value-added" business. Thus, replacing the "fair competition' language with a provision clarifying the the antitrust clause Secretary's powers and insertion would more effectively serve competition. -11- Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 ia, Moreover, the participation ofederal ubstantiveeandndefinitional even with private parties, raises both s problems. Section 406(b) limits such activities to those that "will not compete with other United States private sector activi- ties." However, both operational and "value-added" services of such mixed public and private sector cosortiactivitieeeininherlntly likely to compete with purely private sector s remote-sensing industry. Moreover, the possibility of xed sec- consortia may in itself distort the incentives of the private vts for to develop land remote-sensing services. potential private entrants would be semightdentailepublicesubsidiesefor the consortium of federal agencies g suggests that indivi- dual which they would have to compete. This sdual Government agency needs shoulmet d be the private sector alone, not through Gove rangements, so that all potential providers may have the oppor-sub tuntity to compete for any nesatticilpationein consortia appears balance, permitting Government p unnecessary and possibly damaging to competition. Finally, apart from those policy concerns set forth above, we have several reservations regarding the bceduresuctAddition di- cial review and required administrative procedures. several of the provisions concerning the eosalecandodisseminatio of data and the procedures for awarding a ion of the land remote-sensing system are vague so as to invite initial litigation over their meaning. provides that before granting a license to quali- fied S private tn sector parties, the Secretary of Commerce must deter- mine that the applicant will comply with the Act, regulations, in- conc cre- rnational obligations andornmodifylaslicense issuednunder the Act te fory may revoke , suspend , for failure to commplly. Upon timely request after an adverse action, an applicant or licensee is entitled adjudication on the record by the Secretary. A final is subject to judicial review under the Administrative Procedure Act. Under Section 606, the Secretaryits required to consult with e the Secretary of Defense on national obsecurity 1igations~ncThesSecretary Secretary of State on international of Defense and the Secretary fState theeSecretaryboflnationalec- tively, for identifying and notiying security concerns and international sobligations relating toacti- vities under the Act. However, Se 6( )(l) em eps errs tteeson- Secretary of Commerce to determine the appropriatens ableness of conditions based on national security. or''hnternational o ~ obligations to be imposudicialnreview in Section 606. express provision for j - 12 - Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 We oppose judicial review of those Secretary of Commerce deter- minations under the Administrative Procedure Act involving national security and compliance with international obligations. in the national security and foreign relations areas are largely within the authority of the Executive Branch and should not be subjected to judicial review. We recommend that language be in- serted to provide that to the extent the decisions of the Secre- tary of Commerce concern national security and compliance with international obligations, they are committed to the Secretary's discretion and are not subject to judicial review. Section 404 of the bill authorizes the Secrtay provides to ohprosul- gate appropriate regulations. Section 404(b) regulations "shall be carried out only after public notice and hearings in accordance with the provisions of title 5, States Code." The language of this provision is ambiguous and may be read to require the Secretary to employ notice-and-comment, and perhaps other, procedures for all regulations, including those that would otherwise be exempt from the required procedures. 5 U.S.C. 4553(a),(b). This ambiguity can be removed simply by deleting the phrase "only after public notice and hearings." Some provisions of the bill are so vague that they invite litigation over their construction, with the prospect of ceding to the courts what should initially be determined bFiCongress, and subsequently be interpreted by the Secretary. t, e provisions relating to a contract for the operation of the exist- system liarte ing land remote-sensing kelsatellite These provisions are likely to generate more than one bidder and a disappointed bidder wishes to prevent an award of the contracts. The bill fails to indicate whether t other statutes and regulations relating to governmenttprocure en t r are applicable to this type of contract. See, e.&., Disputes Act, 41 U.S.C. 3601 et se .; the Federal civil procurement statute, 41 U.S.C. 3251 et se q., and the Federal acquisition regu- lations promulgated thereun er. Additionally, the provisions relating to the sale and dissem- ination of data have been drafted without regard for the copy- right law of Title 17. For instance, section 202 statesttiatun- "title" to the data is retained by the United States. clear whether the data aoocopyrightwork can subsisttin thendata, no of 17 U.S.C. 3105, so that or that the copyright is obtained by theicontractor actoraand assigned to the United States. In either event, force the copyright. Section 202 also provides that the cnrtoriissentitled tt oher the revenues from the sale of data. A question Thif the e billgdoesnnottaddress the contractor is entitled to Chtitlerevenues data to which the government has should someone else sell the the contractor's remedy, if any, data. Another problem is that although "digital remote-sensing - 13 - Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3 data" is defined, the general term "data," as used in section 202, is not. By implication, the term "data," is broader than "digital remote-sensing data" and would include copyrightable subject matter. For the foregoing reasons, the Department of Justice believes that this legislation raises questions that should betheoroughly mconsidered. to enactment of suggested thiselegislation. notiobjectamended men The Office of Management and Budget has advised this Depart- ment that there nofobjection Administrationbsiprogramf this report from the standpoint Sincerely, Robert A. McConnell Assistant Attorney General Approved For Release 2008/09/11: CIA-RDP86B00338R000200290017-3