(UNTITLED)

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
C
Document Page Count: 
75
Document Creation Date: 
January 12, 2017
Document Release Date: 
May 20, 2011
Sequence Number: 
2
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
December 1, 1987
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8.pdf2.87 MB
Body: 
Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Directorate of Intelligence ILLEGIB Economic Analysis The Israeli Econometric Model: A Key Tool for A Technical InteWgence Report NESA 87-10051 December 1987 copy 3 4 7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Economic Analysis The Israeli Econometric Model: A Key Tool for Division, NESA, Office of Near Eastern and South Asian Analysis. Comments and queries are welcome and may be directed to the Chief, Issues and Applications This paper was prepared by Confidential NESA 87-10051 December 1987 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Confidential Summary /rt/ormation available as of 1 September 1987 was used in this report. Economic Analysis Model: A Key Tool for The Israeli Econometric The econometric model of Israel, developed in the late 1970s, incorporates and its supporting data files have been revised and updated. information on government policies, international economic conditions, resource availabilities, and other factors. As the economy of Israel has evolved and underlying conditions and policies have changed, the model less reliable are the results of the model. The model, written in the TROLL language, now contains almost 200 equations, each of which describes a different facet of the economy. These equations can be solved for each of the last 10 years or the next 10 years. Because projections depend on data inputs that are inherently less certain than those pertaining to the past, the more distant the year projected, the Most of the equations in the Israeli model, such as those computing the balance of payments and disposable income, are definitional. These equations describe identities that are true for all economies at any time. Twenty other equations in the model represent behavioral and technologi- cal relationships that give the Israeli economy its character and distinguish it from other economies. For example, fuel imports appear to be a function of their average price, Israeli GNP, and capital availability. The specific form of each of these equations has been estimated from observations of the Israeli economy during the last 10 to 20 years or is based on the judgment of economic analysts. Because such relationships are subject to change over time, projections based on these equations assume that the relationships they represent will remain constant for the projection period. of events over time. The model can be divided into several sections, each describing a sector of the Israeli economy. The most important of these deal with the availability and use of resources in the economy, including private and government consumption, investment, exports, and imports. Linkages among the various sections of the model reflect linkages among the different sectors of the Israeli economy. Moreover, the model is dynamic, showing the impact The Israeli model lends itself to a variety of analyses. For example, historical simulations of the Israeli economy in the first half of the 1980s suggest that, as expected, monetary growth was a major contributor to the Confidential NESA 87-10051 December ~/ 987 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Confidential 25X1 Figure 1 Israeli Econometric Model TRANSFERS-~ CURRENT ACCOUNT--~ CAPITAL ACCOUNT l t EXPORTS IMPORTS INFLATION 1 ~a ~ MILITARY MONEY GNP ~ GOVERNMENT triple-digit inflation in Israel at that time. A baseline projection of the Israeli economy over the next two years reveals sluggish growth of output, declining growth of private consumption and investment, and worsening balances of trade and payments as imports rise faster than exports. Scenario analysis with the model shows that increases in investment can speed up growth of production during the next two years but would have little effect on private consumption. Consumption would benefit from a reduction in taxes. Moreover, tax cuts appear to reduce the budget surplus less than matching increases in public investment. The model reveals that increased investment is an expensive way to improve labor productivity. Other approaches-such as better training and placement and productivity inducements-should be explored. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Confidential The Israeli model was evaluated by ex post simulation of 1977-85 economic activities. A comparison of the simulation with actual observa- tions suggests that the model and the supporting data base provide a consistently accurate description of the Israeli economy during that period. The model was also evaluated by comparing ex ante projections of 1985-86 economic activities with actual developments in those years. Performance in these cases, which depended additionally on the accuracy of external projections of certain economic activities, was not as consistently good as in the case of the historical simulation. Performance was weakest for projections of rates of growth and inflation, tax revenues, and international payment balances. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Confidential Summary iii Scope Note ix The Structure of the Model 1 GNP 1 Private Income and Consumption 4 Investment and Capital Stock 5 Labor 6 Government Finances 8 Foreign Trade 10 Exports 11 Imports 12 Balance of Payments 15 Applying the Israeli Model 17 Historical Analysis-Israeli Hyperinflation 19 Projecting the Future-The Baseline Case 19 Scenario Analyses 23 Policy Analysis 23 Goal Analysis 29 Evaluating the Israeli Model 31 Historical Tracking 31 Past Projections 32 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Confidential Scope Note The Israeli economy, like other economies, is a complex set of interacting phenomena. Some of these interactions occur quickly; others take place over longer periods of time. Some involve only one or two factors; others consist of many. The econometric model allows the analyst to study the economy and to gain insights at a level of complexity that is impossible with other approaches. Past, present, and future economic activities can be simulated so that the analyst can look at the roots of current problems, ex- periment with possible solutions, and project future implications. The Israeli econometric model has been in use since the late 1970s.' This paper describes the latest version, explains how it can be used, and presents some illustrative findings. It also explains some of the limitations of this type of analysis and provides an assessment of the validity of model results. 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Confidential Model: A Key Tool for Economic Analysis The Israeli econometric model, written in the TROLL language, consists of almost 200 equations.Z Each describes a different aspect of the Israeli economy. Twenty of these equations contain parameters that have been estimated by econometric analysis of Israeli economic data for the last 10 to 20 years. The model is divided into sections describing Israeli production, private consumption, investment and capital growth, labor supply and employment, government revenues and spending, exports and imports, and Israel's inter- Figure 2 Israel: Real GNP ISGR ISEMI~ ~. ~ -~- ISYRp ISKSY'78E ISNETFR~ \ /~ l /sl \ \\ national financial position. GNP Israel's GNP was $21 billion in 1985. This equaled Egypt's output of goods and services in that year, although the Egyptian population then totaled 48 million while Israel's stood at only about 3.9 million. The model estimates total Israeli output of goods and services in 1980 shekels (figure 2) as aCobb-Douglas function of capital (ISKSM78E), employment (ISEMP), and real government consumption (ISGR):' Log(ISYR) _ -1.288 + 0.04*DUM81 - 0.031*DUM84 + 0.366*Log(ISKSM78E) + 0.597*Log(ISEMP) + 0.037*Log(ISGR) ' ACobb-Douglas function is one in which the variable to be explained, here ISYR, is expressed as a multiplicative function of the explanatory variables: ISYR = a*ISKSM78Eb*ISEMP*ISGRd The exponents add to 1 (b+c+d=1). The equation implies that ISCR: R*.l Co~*rnmmt Con.umpUon 1SEYP: 1Smplo~moat tslcs>.Tea: c.plw sloak LSYRp: cxp ISYRa Roounu A~ait.Dlo ISllnt: Rs*1 ImperL ISIY7R: R*ol ImpoK Tu*. ISIX: R**1 Into.tmont YRRRS: C6on3* b Stoeb IS100t: R*.l [ryorla ISmfSR: Roal 1[zport Subddl*. Variables in black are computed by identities. Variables in blue are computed by historically derived econometric equations. Variables in red are exogenously determined. 1973-85 are explained by the equation specified here, the given parameter estimates, and changes in the values of ISKSM78E, ISEMP, and ISGR during that period. DUM81 and DUM84 represent dummy variables for the years 1981 and 1984, respectively. They are used because Israeli output of goods and services in these years is not fully explained by the other variables in the model. By including a variable for each year explicitly in the model, it is possible to estimate coefficients for them that indicate the influence of the years themselves (or rather the factors implicitly associated with these years) on the value of The function is estimated from data for 1973-85 in its logarithmic form in which the explanatory variables are additive and the "a" term is separated into a constant and two dummy variables. The coefficient of determination-commonly called the R'~f this estimate equals 0.998, indicating that the function explains 99.8 percent of the variation in ISYR during that time. That is, almost all of the changes in the value of ISYR during Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Confidential The macroeconometric model is a toollor studying the economy of a country by simulating its activities. It consists of a number of equations, each describing a separate facet of the economy. Most of the equations are accounting identities, equally true of any country at any time. Thus, goods and services used must equal those produced or acquired in other ways, say imported from abroad or drawn from inventories. If'uses include consumption (CJ, investment (IJ, government services (GJ, exports (XJ, and net additions to inventories (VJ and sources consist of domestic production (Y) and imports (MJ, one identity in the model would be: Other model equations represent behavioral or tech- nological relationships among the various compo- nents of the economy. The exact form of such a relationship is likely to be peculiar to a given country and subject to change over time as government poli- cies, social institutions, economic conditions, technol- ogy, and other factors change. Consumption, for example, may be a function of population (PJ and disposable income (YdJ. A possible form of this relationship is: C/P = bl + b2*Yd/P Here C, P, and Yd are variables, the values of which change from year to year; bl and b2 are parameters that describe the specific relationship among these variables for a given country and time period and are expected to change little, 4f at all, over time. When the model is run, the economy is simulated one year at a time for the entire simulation period. For each year, each equation in the model is solved for one distinct variable. To do this, the computer must know the values of all the other variables and any parameters in the egi:ation. Variables computed by equations in the model are said to be endogenous. Each must appear in at least one distinct equation, and the model must have as many equations as there are endogenous variables. The values of other variables, termed exogenous, are taken from external sources and must be supplied to the model for each year of the simulation period. Estimates of these values are taken from several sources: ? Extrapolation of current trends. ? The judgment and research findings of other ex- perts, both within the Intelligence Community and at other government, academic, and research institutions. ? Official country publications. Projections of exogenous variables involve dlfjerent degrees of uncertainty. In general, the most confi- dence resides in those input values subject to little, if any, policy manipulation and those that reflect long- term trends not likely to be quickly reversed. The least certain input data are those strongly Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Confidential ir~uenced by factors such as policy decisions and international market forces that may change abruptly. Where uncertainty is greatest, alternative input val- ues would indicate the sensitivity ojmodel output to the value ojthe variable in question. When irtforma- tion for an input variable is absent, the model can be used to estimate likely values by indicating the range in which they must fall to be consistent with other known data. Econometric modeling encourages the collection of a diverse body ojir~formation concerning the economy and provides a means of checking its consistency. This helps to assess the value ojexisting intelligence and research activities and to suggest where addition- al eh`orts may be needed. Parameters are values that are expected to change slowly or not at all during the simulation period. These may be coefficients ojvariables in behavioral and technological equations or values appearing in identities. Projections with such equations are valid only for the period in which the parameters are expected to remain constant. While coe,~cient estimates may be based on analyst judgment or taken from other sources, most are derived by econometric techniques from recent his- torical data. The period involved varies from equa- tion to equation, the goal being to find estimates that cause the equation toht the historical data best while meeting various consistency, bias, and other criteria. In general, parameter estimates are consid- ered unsuitable unless the resulting equation explains at least 95 percent ojthe variation in the value ojthe endogenous variable over the historical estimation period. Estimates attained in this way are likely to be incorrect to some extent because of problems in the underlying historical data base and limitations in the estimation procedure. The procedure itseU, however, assesses the probability ojany deviation ojthe true coefficient valuejrom its estimated value.a It there- fore is possible to estimate the probability that the true value falls within any given range around the estimate. In most cases an estimate is accepted only iT there is less than a S percent chance that the devi- ation is so large that the true value may be zero or of the opposite sign. a Statistical estimation of a parameter also yields the standard error of the estimate. In general, there is less than a 5-percent probability that the true value of the parameter is more than two standard errors from the estimated value. This statistical rule of thumb allows us to assess the validity of the parameter estimate. If the standard error is greater than half the value of the parameter itself, the probability that its true value is zero or of the opposite sign is greater than 2.5 percent. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Confidential Government consumption is not a factor of produc- tion. It is a demand variable. The public sector, however, plays an important role in the Israeli economy: ? It directly produces goods and services that account for a large share of the total output of the economy. ? Government agencies provide entrepreneurial ser- vices that facilitate the efforts of other sectors of the economy, making their capital and labor more productive, thus helping to increase their total out- put along with that of the economy as a whole. ? Government spending, as large as it is in the economy, almost certainly influences the decisions of other producers. Increases in such spending prob- ably encourage those producers to increase output. It is, therefore, reasonable to expect the level of government activities to be significant in explaining the level of GNP. It might be more appropriate to measure these activi- ties by some government variable that reflects output rather than demand. Government consumption, how- ever, appears to be a good proxy for that variable. It significantly improves the fit of the model to the historical data, raising the expectation of more accu- rate GNP forecasts. Each coefficient in aCobb-Douglas function provides an estimate of the relative change in GNP associated with a 1-percent change in a factor of production. Thus, a 1-percent increase in capital stock is associat- ed with a 0.37-percent rise in real output. The coefficients also indicate the share of total output attributable to the individual factors. This equation portrays an economy where labor inputs play a bigger role than capital in determining output. Not surpris- ingly, government spending is also important. Net real additions to stocks (YRRES) are derived from the difference between total availability of goods and services~utput plus imports and import taxes (ISIMR and ISIMTR) and total uses-private con- sumption (ISPCR), total investment (ISIR), govern- ment spending, exports (ISEXR), and export subsidies (ISEXSR): ISYR =ISPCR + ISIR + ISGR + ISEXR + ISEXSR -ISIMR -ISIMTR - ISNETFR + YRRES Real additions to stocks are converted to current terms using the investment deflator. Additions in current terms along with consumption, investment, government spending, exports, and imports in current terms are used to arrive at GNP in current shekels (ISY). A comparison of real and nominal estimates of GNP yields the GNP deflator (ISYDEF) and the rate of inflation: ISYDEF = ISY/ISYR Private Income and Consumption Private consumption in Israel was two-thirds the level of GNP, $13.7 billion, in 1985. In the model real consumption in the private sector is estimated by a behavioral equation from real disposable income (ISDISPR), lagged private consumption, and the in- flation rate for imports (DDIMPDEF) (figure 3):? ISPCR = -2.74 + 0.216*ISDISPR + 0.825*ISPCR(-1) - 0.029*DDIMPDEF Here the marginal propensity to consume out of additional disposable income appears to be quite low. But the rate of inflation in the import sector is a significant inducement to private spending. The rate of inflation for private consumption (DDPCDEF) is estimated as a behavioral function of the rate of growth of the money supply (DDM2) and that of total military consumption (DDG2), both of Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Confidential which are projected outside the model by analysts. The rate appears to have trended upward during 1973-85 (DUM7385O) apart from the influence of the other explanatory variables (TIME is an index for year):5 DDPCDEF = 0.767*DUM7385O*TIME + 143.395*DUM7385E - 21.363*DUM78 + 0.697*DDM2 + 1.216*DDG2 Changes in military spending appear to be twice as important as those in the money supply in determin- ing the rate of inflation. The deflator derived from the inflation rate is used to determine the nominal value of private consumption. Private disposable income in current shekels (ISDISP) is arrived at by subtracting direct taxes (ISDT) and those on domestic production (ISTDPFY), public- sector business income (ISGBUSIN), and private- sector loans to the government (ISNETCL) from GNP (figure 4). Subsidies to business (ISBUSSUB), other government transfers to the private sector (ISG- TRAN), and personal remittances from abroad (ISF- TRANP) are then added: ISDISP = ISY - ISTDPFY - ISGBUSIN - ISDT -ISNETCL + ISBUSSUB + ISTRAN + ISFTRANP This is converted to real disposable income by using the deflator for private consumption. Investment and Capital Stock Total Israeli investment in 1985 was $4.1 billion- about 20 percent of GNP. Capital stock was valued at almost $50 billion, giving an average capital-output ratio of 2.4. The model calculates total investment, in current shekels, as the sum of private and public housing investment (ISINHI and ISPUBH), private and pub- lic nonresidential investment (ISINS and ISPUBI), ` DUM78 and DUM7385E are dummy variables for 1978 and 1985, respcctively. R' = 0.998; estimated with 1975-85 data. investment in ships and planes (ISVSP), and changes in stocks (ISINSTOK): ISI =ISINHI +ISPUBH +ISINS +ISPUBI + ISVSP + ISINSTOK The private housing and nonresidential investment components are both computed in real terms (figure 5). Real private housing is a behavioral function of past values of real personal transfers from abroad and government transfers to the private sector:b 0.569*(ISFTRANP(-1) + ISFTRANP(-2)1 25X1 ISIDEF(-U ISIDEF(-2) J + 0.127*rISGTRAN(-1) + ISGTRAN(-2)1 ISIDEF(-1) ISIDEF(-2) J Changes in foreign transfer payments are far more important than those in government transfers in de- termining the level of private housing investment. The investment sector deflator (ISIDEF) is derived from the sector rate of inflation (DDIDEF), a behav- ioral function of the rate of growth of the money supply and of total military consumption (figure 6):' DDIDEF = 104.67*DUM7385E + 0.841 *DUM7385O*TIME + 0.685*DDM2 + 1.369*DDG2 As with the rate of inflation for private consumption, changes in military spending are twice as important as 25X1 changes in the money supply in determining inflation in the investment sector. The investment deflator is used to convert current private investment into real investment.~~ 25X1 b DUM7385 is a dummy variable for all years after 1972. Rj = 0.930; estimated with 1967-85 data. ' RZ = 0.996; estimated with 1975-85 data 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/20 :CIA-RDP88T00096R000800960002-8 Confidential Figure 3 Israel: Private Consumption DD1~2 DDG2 ISDISPR DDIMPDEF Figure 4 Israel: Disposable Income ISY ISYR ~ ISGTRANt ISGTRANR ISPC ISBUSSUT}--i ISDISP~~ ~ ISFTRAND ~ISFTRAN~ DDM2: Money Supply Rate of Growth DDG2: Percent Chaa`e in Total Military Consumption ISTDPPY: DemasUe Production Tasee ISDISPR-- ISPCDEF TIME: lade= for Yesr ISCBUSIN: Pubao-Sector Business Income DDPCDEF: Private Coaaumptton Inflation Rate ISYR: Real CNP ISPTRANP: Personal Tramfen from Abroad ISDISPR: Real Disposable Income ISYD6r: GNP DaMlor ISPTRAND: Penenal Tnnsfen lrom Abroad (Dollars) DDIMPDEF: Inflation Rate is the Import Sector ISN6TCL? Nat Compubeq bane 13XR: E: