USSR: SHARPLY HIGHER BUDGET DEFICITS THREATEN PERESTROYKA

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP91S00056R000400110002-6
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
K
Document Page Count: 
33
Document Creation Date: 
December 27, 2016
Document Release Date: 
January 18, 2013
Sequence Number: 
2
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
September 1, 1988
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP91S00056R000400110002-6.pdf1.66 MB
Body: 
STAT Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91S00056R000400110002-6 Ne v- loe eNext 1 Page(s) In Document Denied Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91S00056R000400110002-6 st Intelligence .:- ? / . . , USSR: Sharply Higher Budget Deficits Threaten Perestroyka A Research Paper 0048553 S0V*10043U4:88 SOVA*11962)8E 1499-1499 SPECIAL ASST FOR DISSEMINATION ANALYSIS CPAS/CSG/ISS (A-1: ROOM 7G50 HQS SOV 88-10043U September 1988 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18 : CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 This publication is prepared for the use of US Government officials, and the format, coverage, and content are designed to meet their specific requirements. US Government officials may obtain additional copies of this document directly or through liaison channels from the Central Intelligence Agency. - , Requesters outside the US-Government may obtain subscriptions to CIA publications similar to this one by addressing inquiries to: Document Expediting (DOCEX) Project Exchange and Gift Division Library of Congress Washington, D.C. 20540 or: National Technical Information Service 5285 Port Royal Road Springfield, VA 22161 Requesters outside the US Government not interested in subscription service may purchase specific publications either in paper copy or microform from: Photoduplication Service Library of Congress Washington, D.C. 20540 or: National Technical Information Service 5285 Port Royal Road Springfield, VA 22161 (To expedite service call the NTIS Order Desk (703) 487-4650) Comments and queries on this paper may be directed to the DOCEX Project at the above address or by phone (202-287-9527), or the NTIS Office of Customer Services at the above address or by phone (703-487-4660). Publications are not available to the public from the Central Intelligence Agency. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 iiirecturatv ut Intelligence Reverse Blank USSR: Sharply Higher Budget Deficits Threaten Peres troyka A Research Paper SOV 88-10043U September 1988 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Summary Information available as of 2 September 1988 was used in this report. USSR: Sharply Higher Budget Deficits Threaten Perestroyka The Soviet state budget deficit has increased dramatically during the last three years. We estimate that 1987's deficit, six times the level recorded in 1984, was equivalent to some 7 percent of Soviet GNP. (For comparison, the highest US Government budget deficit represented 3.5 percent of US GNP in fiscal year 1986.) Moscow is essentially financing its deficits by printing money, and the resulting inflationary pressures are clearly visible. Growth of wages almost doubled in the first half of 1988, while annual increases in savings deposits have doubled since 1985 and have continued to surge in 1988. There has been a marked increase in the prices of consumer goods sold in collective farm markets, along with higher prices and increased shortages of consumer goods in state stores. Excess purchasing power also has probably led to an expansion of the underground economy, which results in resource diversions from the state sector. Increased inflation probably has under- mined current attempts to spur state worker productivity by higher wages and salaries. General Secretary Gorbachev's policies are partly responsible for the deficit rise: ? State spending has risen substantially as a result of large boosts in state investment and the rise in total state subsidies on food and livestock products. ? Receipts from stiff sales taxes on alcoholic beverages are down substan- tially as a result of the regime's antialcohol program. ? Revenues from the large markups imposed on the retail prices of imported food and consumer goods have fallen sharply as a result of the cutback in such imports. ? Proceeds from enterprise profit taxes grew slowly last year because of production problems due to retooling, reforms, and quality control measures. Moscow has taken a number of steps over the last year to absorb excess purchasing power or to manage the resulting shortages of goods and services, including rationing and issuance of a new series of savings bonds. These policies, however, do not address the budget deficit itself and thus ig- nore the source of the purchasing power problem. 111 SOV 88-10043U September 1988 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Leadership concern over the issue seems to be mounting. The General Secretary first noted stresses in the state budget in a June 1987 speech to the party leadership in which he criticized the Brezhnev regime for relying on alcohol sales and oil exports as revenue sources. More recently, Gorbachev acknowledged in his opening speech to the 19th Party Confer- ence in June 1988 that the state budget has been in deficit for many years and that its current level reflects in part "our mistakes." Gorbachev has a wide range of policy options available for bringing the deficit under control, but they basically involve either cutting spending or increasing state revenues: ? Substantial price increases for consumer goods and key industrial materials, such as fuel and raw materials, would reduce government subsidies. Indeed, doing away with food subsidies alone would bring the budget back into balance. But the specter of Polish unrest weighs heavily on the leadership, with good reason. ? Several high-ranking political and military spokesmen have stated publicly that the Soviet Union plans to reduce spending on defense. But the level of cuts needed to make a major impact on the budget deficit is unlikely. Similarly, state investment outlays could be trimmed, a remedy suggested by Gorbachev in his July 1988 speech to the party leadership. Although investment requirements remain high in energy and other critical sectors, potentially large savings are available through halting low-priority projects and eliminating waste. ? Higher tax rates are a possibility, particularly in the context of increased wage differentiation and the expansion of private-sector activities. But the increases would have to be large to make a dent in the deficit, and they would have their own disincentive effects. Moscow is considering relaxing the antialcohol campaign because increased state sales of alcohol would reap large tax revenues. Finally, much greater consumer- good imports sold at high prices domestically would raise substantial tax revenue and soak up purchasing power. Such imports could be easily financed through foreign borrowing, but Moscow traditionally has preferred to finance imports of machinery and equipment that expand domestic production capacity rather than imports for current consumption. iv Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 ? A currency revaluation (for example, 1 new ruble for 10 old rubles) could effectively wipe out much of the savings overhang and devalue cash hoards. Although not without precedent, this would appear to be an especially heavyhanded and politically risky approach. Moreover, unless accompanied by price revisions, increased taxes, or reduced state spend- ing, currency reform would not solve the budget imbalance. Only large-scale imports of consumer goods or relaxing the antialcohol campaign offer Moscow opportunities to address the budget deficit without gouging an important interest group. Each option, however, has other undesirable consequences. The leadership is concerned that five or 10 years hence the Soviet Union would have to service a much larger foreign debt with little to show for it. And Moscow is reluctant to ease the antialcohol campaign because it could undermine efforts to improve health and worker discipline. In any event Gorbachev must act quickly. Because the inflationary impact of the budget deficit exacerbates current consumer problems, the leader- ship is fighting an uphill battle in trying to improve the quality of life for average citizens. If the budget deficit is not brought down, it could lead to inflation much worse than the Soviets have experienced in the postwar era. Reverse Blank v Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Contents Page Summary iii Scope Note ix Budget Deficit Balloons Under Gorbachev 1 State Spending Surges 1 Revenue Shortfalls 2 1988 Budget Plan: No Relief in Sight 3 Money Creation Finances the Deficit 3 Impact on Prices, Shortages, and Savings 4 Prices Increase 4 Shortages Intensify 5 Forced Savings Increase 7 Increased Soviet Recognition of the Problem 7 Leadership Concern 7 Economists' Statements 8 Official Acknowledgement 9 Limited Policy Measures So Far 9 Rationing 9 Savings Bonds 9 Insurance 9 Charity Funds 9 Increased Role for Collective Farm Markets 10 Cooperative Housing 10 Encouraging Private Business 10 Costs of Continued Inaction 10 Resource Diversions From the State Sector 10 Labor 10 Consumer Goods 11 Producer Goods 11 Weakened Workers' Incentives 11 Price Reform Constrained 11 Gorbachev's Options 12 Removal of Subsidies 12 Increased Sales of Consumer Goods 13 vii Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91S00056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Page Spending Cuts on Defense and Investment 13 Currency Reform 13 Outlook: Perestroyka Threatened 14 Appendixes A. Key Tables 15 B. State Revenue From Foreign Trade 21 C. The Official Balance as an Indicator of the Estimated Deficit 23 viii Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Scope Note Largely using Soviet official data and statements of Soviet officials and economists, this paper documents the existence of sharply higher state budget deficits in the Soviet Union that are being financed to a large extent by money creation. We are confident that the deficit has increased greatly in the last two to three years, but are less sure about its exact size for sever- al reasons: ? Moscow traditionally has treated many elements of government finance as state secrets. For the purpose of estimating the budget deficit, the most important information gaps are on the revenue side. Moscow does not provide a full breakdown of revenues, and, although we have tracked down and used as much information as the Soviets publish, conceivably we could be missing an important tax source altogether. ? Most Western analysts agree that one major source of state revenue missing in the official breakdown is revenue from foreign trade. We have made estimates of such revenue based on the best available Western information. Nevertheless, we could be underestimating it by perhaps 10 percent, or about 8 billion rubles. Our estimates of the deficit would thus be too high by the same ruble amount. ? Moscow publishes virtually no information on the money supply, which could be used as an independent check on our estimates of the deficit. Because of rising Soviet concern over the deficit, we may soon see an improvement in the availability of official financial statistics. Meanwhile, a September 1988 Soviet newspaper article gave the first hints of Soviet estimates of the deficit, implying a range of 65 to 75 billion rubles. This range encompasses our estimate for 1988 and suggests we are close to the mark. Western analysis of Soviet budgets and their financial implications has a long history. Some of the more recent treatments of this area of the Soviet economy include: Igor Birman, Secret Incomes of the Soviet State Budget (1981); Raymond Hutchings, The Soviet Budget (1983); James R. Millar "Financing the Soviet Effort in World War II," Soviet Studies (January 1980); and Mark Harrison, "The USSR State Budget Deficit Under Late Stalinism," Economics of Planning, Vol. 20, No. 3 (1986). ix Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Figure 1 USSR: Estimated State Budget Deficit, 1981-88 Billion rubles 80 Percent of GNP 10 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 317634 6.88 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 USSR: Sharply Higher Budget Deficits Threaten Perestroyka . all of our radical reforms are doomed to failure if Estimating the Budget Deficit we are unable to realize success in our financial policies. Vladimir Il'ich Lenin 18 May 1918 Budget Deficit Balloons Under Gorbachev General Secretary Gorbachev's policy of greatly in- creased state spending on investment, coupled with the tax losses from his antialcohol campaign, has intensified other negative fiscal trends and produced large budget deficits. Indeed, we estimate that the Soviet state budget deficit increased from 11 billion rubles in 1984 (1.4 percent of Soviet GNP) to 64 billion rubles in 1987 (7.4 percent of GNP) (figure 1 and inset).' In contrast, the peak US Government deficit in fiscal year 1986 of $148 billion represented 3.5 percent of US GNP. Relative to GNP, the Soviet deficit is roughly two times the size of the peak US deficit in 1986.2 State Spending Surges General Secretary Gorbachev assumed power in March 1985 in time to push for faster investment growth in the 12th Five-Year Plan (FYP), then being drafted. He did not have an easy time convincing the planners to accept his program, suggesting that they believed his investment objectives would push the economy beyond its capabilities. Nonetheless, he won out. According to the FYP, budgetary outlays on ' Throughout this paper we define the budget deficit as the amount of total government spending per year not met through ordinary revenues (tax revenues and service fees) and which therefore must be financed through government borrowing. The percentage shares of GNP are rough estimates derived by adjusting CIA estimates of Soviet GNP in constant 1982 established prices, using an assumed average annual rate of inflation equal to 2 percent. 'The Soviet state budget is a consolidated budget that takes into account incomes and spending of the central government, the republics, and local governments. A comparable figure for the United States thus includes not only the federal deficit ($205 billion in 1986) but also the surplus run by the 50 states ($57 billion in 1986). 1 Soviet official budgets almost invariably show a surplus because, by Soviet convention, short-term loans from the State Bank (which are the equivalent of printing money) are counted as a revenue. Conse- quently, the officially reported surpluses have little economic or financial meaning and are extremely misleading concerning the extent of money creation. A Soviet economist acknowledged this in a December 1987 interview in Izvestiya, stating: "In my opinion, the formation of a significant share of budget reve- nues using short-term loans from the State Bank was intended to ensure the deficit-free functioning of the state budget. As a result, the budget no longer reflected the true state of affairs in the national economy." Our estimates of Soviet state budget deficits are based on a complete accounting of ordinary budget revenues (nonloans) (see appendix A). Essentially: ? We assumed Soviet official data on total state spending are accurate. ? We calculated total Soviet ordinary revenues using official data on tax revenues and estimates of state revenue from foreign trade (see appendix B). ? We calculated the deficit as the difference between total spending and total ordinary revenues. The key uncertainty in the calculations is the esti- mates of revenue from foreign trade. We believe, however, that they are accurate enough to reflect substantial changes. Moreover, comparing the esti- mates of such revenue for 1985 and 1987 shows a decline of 11 billion rubles, which is roughly consis- tent with Gorbachev's statement in February 1988 that such revenue fell by 9 billion rubles. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 investment were to increase a huge 10 percent in 1986, although followed by much smaller average annual increases during the period 1987-90 (1.2 per- cent per year). Soviet planners were probably concerned about the budget-busting implications of Gorbachev's invest- ment push, since other budget commitments were not relaxed: ? Under Brezhnev's Food Program, procurement prices paid to farms were raised on 1 January 1983. Since retail prices for the most part were not raised, unit subsidies increased. But higher unit subsidies, Figure 2 USSR: Annual Changes in State Spending and Revenues, 1984-88 Billion rubles 35 coupled with increased meat and food production, Spending have greatly increased the burden of this expendi- ture on the state budget. State appropriations for Revenues the subsidy of food prices increased from 24 billion rubles in 1980 (8 percent of state expenditures) to 58 billion rubles in 1986 (14 percent of state expendi- tures), according to a Soviet agricultural official. ? We estimate defense expenditures also have been increasing since 1985. Perhaps reflecting the un- evenness in weapons procurement cycles, defense spending has been driven by procurement of such major strategic systems as the new Blackjack bomb- er and the Typhoon and Delta IV nuclear-powered ballistic missile submarines. ? Budget spending on social-cultural measures (edu- cation, health services, pensions) increased an aver- age 7.5 billion rubles per year during 1986 and 1987. ? While certainly unanticipated, the Chernobyl' disas- ter cost the state budget 4 billion rubles, according to a January 1988 Politburo announcement. Consequently, given the leadership's decision to push investment spending at all costs, total government spending rose by a record 30 billion rubles in 1986 and by another 18 billion rubles in 1987 (figure 2). -5 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 317635 6.88 Revenue Shortfalls Meanwhile, Soviet state revenues have had to absorb a number of major impacts that have held growth of revenues during 1986 and 1987 to less than 5 billion rubles: ? Until 1985 the Soviets increasingly counted on a hefty indirect tax on retail alcohol sales to generate substantial budget revenues, but a major impact of the antialcohol campaign has been to cut this inflow by roughly one-fourth. ? Planning mistakes, retooling, implementation of re- forms, and establishment of a new quality control system disrupted industrial performance in 1987, slowing growth of revenue from enterprise profit taxes. In the context of discussing strains on the state budget in 1987, Finance Minister Gostev remarked in his speech on the 1988 budget (October 1987) that the machine-building, petrochemicals, and light-industry sectors all had failed to meet their profit targets in 1987. 2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 ? The collapse in world oil prices in early 1986 led to a sharp fall in state revenue from foreign trade as hard currency oil exports fell from an average of $15 billion during the period 1982-84 to just $7 billion in 1986 (see appendix B). Moreover, Moscow's decision to reduce consumer goods im- ports by 10 percent that year contributed substan- tially to the overall fall in state revenue from foreign trade. 1988 Budget Plan: No Relief in Sight According to the current budget plan, total state spending is to rise 8 billion rubles in 1988. However, in line with Gorbachev's new emphasis on the con- sumer, spending on "social-cultural measures" (edu- cation, science, and health care) is to rise 9.2 per- cent?an increase of 13 billion rubles.' Apparently finally recognizing its tight revenue constraint, Mos- cow plans to cut spending for "financing the national economy" (capital investment, capital repair, in- creased circulating capital, and subsidies) by 6 billion rubles. This would be the first time in over 25 years that this spending category actually declined. On the revenue side, Finance Minister Gostev said in October 1987 that the 1988 budget contemplated a reduction in foreign trade revenue. Turnover tax receipts also are scheduled to fall (compared with the 1987 plan); Gostev stated, "Income is built on a healthier footing?revenue from the sale of alcoholic beverages is reduced by 11.5 billion rubles." The Finance Minister did not make clear how these shortfalls, which?along with the planned spending level?imply a 1988 budget deficit of some 70 billion rubles, would be made up. His vagueness is under- standable, however, since we believe the revenue shortfall will be made up by money creation. Money Creation Finances the Deficit By necessity, the large deficits since 1986 have had to be met by government borrowing from the State Bank (see table 1). In the past, Moscow also relied on large- scale sales of long-term bonds to the population as a The average annual increase was 4.9 percent during 1981-85 and 6.4 percent in 1986. The state science budget, however, is believed to finance a large portion of military and civilian research. Thus, some of the increase in spending on social-cultural measures may be for defense and investment purposes. 3 Table 1 USSR: Sources of Finance of the State Budget Deficit Billion rubles 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 a Budget deficit 11.0 17.0 49.8 64.4 68.4 Known sources of finance Long-term borrowing (bond sales) 1.0 1.4 1.9 2.2 2.5 Short-term borrowing from the State Bank (savings receipts) 15.2 18.7 22.0 24.0 26.0 Residual Implied other short-term borrowing from the State Bank ?5.2 ?3.1 25.9 38.2 39.9 a Estimated. Source: Appendix A, table 5. means of finance. But sales of mass subscription bonds were stopped in 1958 because of the leader- ship's concern about rising debt service charges. The government's large levels of borrowing from the State Bank since 1986 are equivalent to injecting like amounts of money into the economy and therefore are inflationary (see inset).4 The money creation takes place when the government uses these loans to pay for pensions, teachers' salaries, military pay and allow- ances, and other purposes.' While taxes and sales of long-term government bonds result in reductions of consumers' purchasing power, government loans from the State Bank effectively result in many more rubles chasing roughly the same amount of consumer goods and services. ? The inflationary impact of these money supply increases partly depends on how fast money is turned over (the velocity of money). The Ministry of Finance has some control over the rate of spending of enterprises and thus could reduce money velocity. For example, spending on weapons procurement or state housing or new factories all result in incomes for workers and managers responsible for producing these goods and services. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Monetary Expansion in the USSR The Soviet State Bank (Gosbank) maintains and monitors the accounts of the government (Treasury), state enterprises and farms, and the population. The bank takes in cash from state retail stores and issues cash to state enterprises for payments of wages. The bank debits and credits the accounts of state enter- prises and the Treasury to reflect the millions of noncash monetary transactions that take place throughout the economy. The bank attempts to keep cash balances segregated from noncash balances but is not always successful. Like any bank, Gosbank has assets and liabilities that must be in balance. Its assets largely consist of short-term loans to enterprises and also to the Trea- sury. Its liabilities largely consist of the deposits of the Treasury, enterprises, and the population. The Treasury takes in taxes and other revenues and deposits them in its account at Gosbank. Similarly, as the government makes expenditures, Gosbank debits the government's account and credits the ac- counts of the payees or, as in the case of pensions, pays out cash. When state revenues are less than expenditures, Gosbank makes short-term loans to the government that are then credited to the government's account. The government can then pay its bills for procure- ment of weapons, pensions, education expenditures, and investment just as if the money came from tax revenues. Gosbank's balance sheet is undisturbed by the transactions: the increase in its short-term loans to the government (an asset) is exactly duplicated by an increase in liabilities (some combination of in- creased cash in circulation and deposits of enterprises and the population). Money has been created from thin air. A portion of the short-term loans used by the govern- ment to cover its deficit is balanced by additions to the population's savings accounts. The population's willingness to increase its savings deposits reflects a mix of factors: interest rates of 2 to 3 percent per year, absence of consumer credit and hence the need to save for big-ticket items such as cars, and lack of desirable consumer goods. In the short run, the population's willingness to set aside funds in savings accounts, rather than attempt to spend them, relieves some of the inflationary pressures of government deficit financing on the consumer sector. On the other hand, the population's accumulated savings accounts represent an enormous purchasing power overhang over the longer term, since savings are subject to immediate withdrawal by their owners. Impact on Prices, Shortages, and Savings The impact of rapid monetary expansion on consu- mers' purchasing power is confirmed by recent trends in prices, shortages, and savings, which indicate rising inflationary pressures. Prices Increase Evidence on Soviet retail prices show a marked acceleration since 1985 (see table 2). Although Soviet official price indexes have long been criticized by both Soviet and Western economists as understating actual price changes, recent data suggest the official retail price index grew 1.7 percent per year during 1986 and 1987, almost double the average 0.9 percent per year reported for 1981-85. Moreover, CIA's estimates of inflation in retail prices also show an acceleration in 1986 to 3.4 percent compared with 2.1 percent per year during 1981-85. Similar trends are evident in collective farm market (CFM) prices. Official Soviet data on prices in CFMs in 264 cities suggest prices rose by 9 percent in 1987 contrasted with an annual average of 2.2 percent 4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91S00056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Table 2 USSR: Selected Measures of Retail Price Changes Average annual growth, percent 1981-84 1985 1986 1987 1988 State retail prices Official 1.0 0.7 1.8 1.6' NA CIA estimate 2.2 1.7 3.4 NA NA Collective farm market prices Official e 2.6 d NA ?0.1 e 9.3 1 8s Derived h 2.2 4.3 ?3.1 e NA NA Narodnoye khozyaystvo SSSR (hereafter referred to as Narkhoz) for various years. h Estimated by comparing Soviet data on retail sales through October in nominal terms with corresponding data in constant terms. Narkhoz za 70 let (1987), p. 485. d 1981-85. e The decline in collective farm market prices in 1986 may reflect large supply increases in a year of good growing conditions, as well as a likely timelag between the increase in the budget deficit that year and the resulting expansion of money demand. I Based on collective farm market prices for 12 commodities in 264 cities, weighted with Moscow collective farm market shares of those commodities sold. Vestnik statistiki, No. 3 (1988), p. 61. g January-March 1988 as compared with January-March 1987, Pravda (26 April 1988). h CIA estimates using Narkhoz data. during 1981-86. The official plan fulfillment report for January-June 1987 contained a rare reference to higher prices in CFMs: As a result of shortages of potatoes, fruit and vegetables, meat, and butter in the trade net- work, high prices were established and are being maintained in the kolkhoz markets at levels 2.5 to 4 times higher than state retail prices. Despite improvements in meat supplies in 1986 and 1987, prices of meat in Moscow's collective farm markets were 18 percent higher in September 1987 than in September 1985 (see figure 3). Moreover, the plan fulfillment report for January-March 1988 again made reference to rising prices in collective farm markets, indicating they were 8 percent higher than in the same period in 1987. 5 The absence of free markets for industrial goods and services as well as lack of information concerning the extent of shortages make it very hard to determine whether inflationary pressures have risen in the large- ly noncash producer goods and services sector of the Soviet economy. We expect, however, eventually to see evidence such as the bidding up of workers' wages, increased prices of machinery and other goods, in- creased hoarding of industrial materials, and declines in product quality.6 Already, according to official statistics, average monthly wages increased 5.7 per- cent during January-June 1988. In contrast, in the first half of 1987, the increase was only 3.2 percent. Shortages Intensify Although the Soviet press almost invariably blames shortages in state stores on supply problems, current shortages probably reflect increases in effective de- mand as the money supply has grown quickly.' In the first instance, consumers' purchases of state goods increased. Even more important, store employees and others with access probably have increased their claims on state goods (whether through theft or purchase at low official prices) for resale in the black market. 'Results from a CIA contractor's research on inflation in official Soviet investment statistics strongly suggest the presence of signifi- cant inflationary tendencies in the investment sector of the econo- my. Producers are able to meet production targets through price increases and customers with plentiful funds are willing to pay premiums to obtain producer durable goods that are in short supply. The system is particularly vulnerable to this inflationary process when prices are set for new and custom-made machines which, according to one Western authority, represent "a large proportion" of investment equipment. The contractor's study reports Soviet estimates of the annual rate of inflation in investment ranged up to 2 percent in the 1960s, 2 to 3 percent during 1971-75, and 2 to 4 percent during 1976-85. 'Two other factors also have contributed to the current shortages. First, Moscow cut back consumer goods imports by about 1 billion rubles (foreign trade prices) in 1986. Second, the antialcohol campaign probably has caused drinkers to shift some of their purchasing power from vodka to other goods. However, this is not likely to have been a major shift since vodka consumers are probably much more inclined to turn to purchases of homebrew rather than purchases of more food and clothes. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Figure 3 Moscow: Collective Farm Market Prices of Selected Goods a Rubles per kilogram Note scale changes Beef State store price 10 Pork 10 Apples 4 1970 75 80 85 86 87 1970 75 80 85 86 87 a Data are for purchases made in Moscow in August or September of each year. 1970 75 80 85 86 87 Anecdotal evidence suggests that consumer com- plaints of shortages of a variety of goods have in- creased markedly since 1986, when money expansion increased dramatically: ? A study conducted by the Ministry of Trade's research institute and described in the Soviet paper Trud noted that shortages of toothpaste, women's panty hose, lotions, eau de toilette, sugar, cassettes, and batteries "broke records for being in short supply" last year. ? Food shortages in particular appear to have wors- ened in 1987. In his March 1988 speech to the Collective Farm Congress, Gorbachev said that the Central Committee "is flooded with letters com- plaining about shortages of livestock products in many of the country's regions." ? Letters in the central press complaining of wide- spread shortages of fruits and vegetables were also more frequent in 1987. 317636 6-88 The 1987 Plan Fulfillment report (published in late January 1988) also details a litany of woes implying shortages may have increased: 6 . . . But the population's incomes increased fast- er than trade turnover and the consumption fund, and there was consequently an increase in unsatisfied demand. An unsatisfactory situation developed in the supply of potatoes, fruits and vegetables for the population, and their range and quality often fail to satisfy the population's demands. At the same time, the population's demand for many types of clothing and knitwear was not fully satisfied, while the shortage of footwear in the trade network remained acute. The situa- tion is aggravated by the imbalance between demand and supply in terms of range and quality. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18 : CIA-RDP91S00056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 In 1987, various organizations concerned with the allocation of housing had registered and had on their lists 13 million families and individuals waiting for better housing. Forced Savings Increase Some Soviet and Western economists believe that a substantial share of Soviet savings are "forced" in the sense that consumers save because desired goods and services are not available. They view the large stock of savings as an indication of repressed inflation. Ac- cording to one Soviet economist, the research arm of the Ministry of Trade estimates that such deferred demand amounts to 60-65 billion rubles, about one- quarter of total savings deposits. Soviet savers added record amounts to their savings deposits during 1985-87. The average addition to savings per year during 1981-84 was 11.4 billion rubles. In contrast, additions were 19, 22, and 24 billion rubles in 1985, 1986, and 1987, respectively. Through the first half of 1988, savings increased 13 billion rubles, implying an annual rate of 26 billion rubles. Some of the increased pent-up demand of Soviet consumers resulting from inflationary pres- sures probably is being absorbed through increases in forced saving. Soviet citizens also maintain a portion of their finan- cial assets in the form of cash hoards. Both Western and Soviet analysts have pointed to the phenomenon of large holdings of cash "under the mattress" as an indication of repressed inflation.' Our estimates of rapid money expansion since 1985 suggest that cash hoards probably have increased substantially over the last two years. Increased Soviet Recognition of the Problem Leadership Concern The General Secretary has severely criticized eco- nomic policy and performance under Brezhnev, re- peatedly referring to the late seventies and the early eighties as a period of stagnation, a precrisis situation, or a period of growing contradictions. In his speech to In a recent interview, economist Aganbegyan was asked whether vast amounts of money are lying unused?"260 billion rubles in the banks, plus a further 240 billion under mattresses?" He replied, "It is true, more or less." 7 the party leadership in June 1987, the General Secre- tary broadened his critique to include the state budget: Take the state budget. Everything looked favor- able on the surface. Expenditures were covered by revenues, but how was this achieved? Not through a growth in the efficiency of the nation- al economy, but by other ways which had no economic or social justification. Gorbachev particularly takes the Brezhnev regime to task for relying too heavily on generating state reve- nues through high taxes on alcoholic beverages and enterprise profits, as well as sales of oil and other fuels on the world market. Gorbachev returned to this theme in his speech to the party leadership in February 1988, suggesting that without the effect of rising world oil prices and increased alcohol sales economic growth would have been much lower (see inset). In this same speech, he concluded that "the country's economy has come up against a very serious financial problem," that is, a much larger state budget deficit. For example, he stated: As a result of reducing the sale of alcohol, in the last three years the state has suffered a revenue shortfall of more than 37 billion rubles. In addition to this, in comparison with 1985, revenue in 1987 from domestic sales of import- ed goods, the purchase of which we have been forced to limit due to a shortage of hard currency, fell by 9 billion rubles. Prime Minister Ryzhkov in his May 1988 speech to the Supreme Soviet indicated that "growing cash- backed demand of the population" remains an acute problem, adding: The disparity between the income of the work- ing people and their opportunities to use this income to buy goods is increasing. Unsatisfied demand is growing and that engenders the occurrence of inflationary processes in money circulation. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18 : CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Gorbachev 's Statement on National Income: Justifying Slow Growth in 1987 Gorbachev estimated in his February plenum speech that the average annual increment in Soviet national income would have declined in the early 1980s if the influence of higher world oil prices and accelerated domestic retail sales of alcohol were disregarded. In doing so, he ratcheted up the contrast between eco- nomic performance in the Brezhnev "stagnation" period and performance under his tenure. He is saying in effect that the Soviet economy was on the way to decline in the early 1980s but for the influence of luck (higher world oil prices) and wrong-headed policy (accelerated retail sales of alcohol). This formulation appears to be an attempt to put some of the negative consequences of Gorbachev's own policies in a better light. His antialcohol cam- paign and other policy initiatives have increased the gap between purchasing power and availability of consumer goods and services. Last year, the new quality control program and implementation of new reforms contributed to the lowest growth in Soviet national income since 1979. By telling the Party leaders at the February plenum that the average annual increment in national income would have declined in the early 1980s but for higher oil prices and greater alcohol sales, we believe Gorbachev was attempting "to level the playing field." He alleged that one must compare the results of his policies with Brezhnev's economic performance only after netting out the impact of increased alcohol sales and wind- fall profits from oil exports. As Gorbachev states at the end of this part of his speech, "This is the real picture, comrades. Only now is the economy begin- ning to grow on a healthy basis." In an offhanded way, he tied the purchasing power growth problem to budget stresses, remarking that a "neglected financial situation" existed at the start of the 12th Five-Year Plan period (1986-90) and that "It is not in a favorable state even now." Specifically, he blamed state subsidies to loss-making enterprises and the decline in world oil prices for the current financial situation. Economists' Statements The leadership's willingness to address the state bud- get issue is paralleled by increased openness on the part of Soviet economists. For example, in an article published last September, Oleg Bogomolov (head of the Institute of the Economics of the World Socialist System) hinted at the existence of a budget deficit when he blamed "the deficit in the state bank cash balance" as a major cause of inflation. Nikolay Shmelev, perhaps the most provocative Sovi- et economist, provides the most graphic discussion so far of the budget deficit and its causes and effects in the April 1988 issue of Novyy mir. He writes: Having handed over income from alcohol to the home distiller, the state has in the last two years seen a drastic exacerbation of the imbal- ance in the budget, in which the deficit is today covered by that supremely dangerous, un- healthy means?the mint. Shmelev returns to the problem of the budget deficit a number of times in this important article: ? Perestroyka requires increased government spend- ing but traditional state revenues are not even sufficient to cover "today's gap in the budget." ? The financial system is "fundamentally based on largely inflationary methods of finance." ? State borrowing is being extended in an "unhealthy, covert way." ? Nontraditional means of raising state revenues should be considered such as bond sales and foreign borrowing. ? State expenditures on investment should be reduced with enterprises investing more from their own incomes. Subsidies of loss-making enterprises should be stopped. But the option of reducing defense spending "is a separate question." Beyond suggesting that the budget deficit has grown subtantially, Shmelev does not provide numerical estimates of its current size or increases over time. 8 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Official Acknowledgement In late May, Pravda published the proposals to be considered at the June party conference. Included in the proposals was the following sentence: The commodity-money imbalance and state budget deficit are having an adverse effect on current production and the course of the reform itself This is one of the few times in the post-war period that Moscow has officially acknowledged the exis- tence of a budget deficit and indicates the seriousness of the problem. In early June, the Soviet press reported a roundtable discussion on the proposals that noted the past practice of masking the actual budget position: Our readers have learned a very important thing from the theses for the first time: our state budget has a deficit. However, each year the Supreme Soviet approves a report on budget implementation in which income exceeds expen- diture. This recurs every year. Of course, spe- cialists know that the real situation is different. But who is fooling whom? Then, in late June, General Secretary Gorbachev reported at the party conference that the state budget has been in deficit for many years. Now that the deficit has been acknowledged official- ly, in effect calling into question official budget statistics, we may see some substantial revisions in such data in the near future. Limited Policy Measures So Far Moscow has taken a number of steps over the last couple of years to soak up excess purchasing power or to otherwise manage the resulting shortages of goods and services. These policies, however, do not address the budget deficit itself, and thus ignore the source of the purchasing power problem. 9 Rationing In a rather quiet manner, Moscow has granted repub- lic governments greater authority to implement ra- tioning. As reported by a Latvian radio program in July 1987, the USSR Council of Ministers granted the 15 republics in early 1987 the right to indepen- dently fix norms for rationed goods. There were numerous reports of rationing on a variety of foods in 1987. Early in September 1988, Pravda noted that rationing has been introduced in eight republics. In the RSFSR, for example, rationing is being used in 26 oblasts, krays, and autonomous republics for the sale of meat, in 32 for the sale of butter, and in 53 for the sale of sugar. Savings Bonds As of 1 March 1988, Soviet citizens can purchase a new series of savings bonds redeemable after 10 years, paying an interest rate of 4 percent. However, the Soviet press indicates that the public has shown little interest in purchasing them to date and few have been sold. Insurance As of 1 January 1988, Soviet citizens may purchase a new form of insurance to supplement state old-age pensions. This appears to be another measure meant to absorb extra rubles in the hands of the populace. The State Insurance Agency (Gosstrakh) has also been pushing overall insurance sales (life, accident, property). According to the latest official data, the population's payments of premiums grew by over 7 percent in 1986. Charity Funds Since 1986, Soviet citizens have increasingly been pressured to contribute to newly formed "socialist" charity funds?for development of culture, for the victims of Chernobyl', for the care of orphans, and for improving health care. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Increased Role for Collective Farm Markets A March 1986 decree on management of the agro- industrial sector allows farms to sell up to 30 percent of their fruits and vegetables to collective farm markets and the Tsentrosoyuz?the predominantly rural retail trade network, where prices are higher than in state stores. By selling less in state stores and more through the other channels where prices are higher, the government would raise the average price of food and thereby absorb excess purchasing power. This measure has had little success so far, however: farms continue to market only a minor share of their produce through the CFMs or the rural retail trade network. Cooperative Housing Moscow is hoping that increased construction of cooperative housing will absorb some of the excess rubles in the hands of the populace. An April 1988 decree calls for formation of more housing coopera- tives: associations composed of Soviet citizens who pool their money for the construction and mainte- nance of apartment buildings. An increased role for cooperative housing construction will require the backing of state housing construction organizations, which previously have given little priority to coopera- tives. Encouraging Private Business The Gorbachev regime has launched a program en- couraging the development of legal private businesses operated by individuals and small groups in an effort to satisfy consumer demand without large invest- ments. New legislation has affirmed the legality of individual labor activity and fostered the establish- ment of member-run cooperatives. While the develop- ment of legal private business is proceeding more slowly than the leadership had hoped, Gorbachev continues to emphasize this program. Costs of Continued Inaction Moscow probably cannot stay the present course. Continued large deficits financed through monetary expansion will lead to an expansion of the second economy, a substantial redistribution of income from state workers to second-economy participants, greater resource diversions, and in general a growing loss of state control of the economy. Moreover, rising prices in the second economy coupled with more empty shelves in state stores will cut into the living standards of citizens on fixed incomes, including pensioners, bureaucrats, and many state workers. Worker incen- tives will weaken further and efforts to increase support for perestroyka could be thwarted. Resource Diversions From the State Sector Increased purchasing power of Soviet consumers does not affect production activity in the state sector of the economy, at least directly. In the state sector, enter- prises producing consumer goods and services take their marching orders from ministries and other ad- ministrative authorities?not consumers. Prices are administered from the center and largely fulfill an accounting function rather than serve as a guide to production. The Soviet "second economy," however, is based on private initiative responding to market demand.' In- creases in consumer purchasing power will result in some combination of higher prices and greater supply of goods and services in this sector, often at a cost to the state of rising theft and corruption. Labor. Higher prices translate into higher incomes of second-economy participants, which in turn will draw in more participants. For example, pensioners, work- ing mothers, and students?some of whom might be employed in the state sector?will have greater incen- tive to take up work in the second economy. More full-time state workers also could be increasingly tempted to work in the second economy, even if just As defined here the Soviet "second economy" includes the whole of the private economy (legal and illegal) as well as illegal state activities (theft, cheating of state store customers, resale of state goods at black-market prices). Estimates of the size of the second economy vary, but there is little doubt that it is substantial. Soviet economists V. Rutgayzer and V. Kostakov of the Gosplan Econom- ics Research Institute recently estimated that by the mid-1980s, 17-18 million people participated each year in the underground service sector at least part-time, providing some 5-6 billion rubles of everyday services?from car repairs to tailoring?annually. This amounts to almost a third of all such purchases by Soviet consumers. 10 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 on a part-time basis. For example, the potential to earn large incomes producing and selling moonshine has clearly drawn in much more labor into this activity. One measure of this shift is the number of arrests for moonshining. Interior Minister Vlasov announced in November 1987 that there had been 390,000 arrests so far that year, as compared with less than 70,000 in 1985. This suggests a roughly fourfold increase in labor supply, although some of the in- crease in arrests may reflect tighter enforcement. Consumer Goods. Higher prices in the second econo- my will tend to result in a greater supply of goods and services as producers respond to greater profit poten- tial. Some of the supply increase will come exclusively through increased application of labor. Some of it, however, will come through increased diversions from the state sector. Theft of consumer goods at the factory and throughout distribution channels, whether for own consumption or resale in the second economy, is a frequent occurrence. Recently the Ukrainian procurator's office reported that over 54,000 workers were caught pilfering in the meat, dairy, and food industries of that republic in 1987. In light industry, where the differential between state and second- economy prices is much lower, 6,000 workers were caught pilfering. Producer Goods. Higher second-economy prices will also draw in more raw materials and other producer goods from the state sector, primarily through theft. Diversions of such goods as gasoline, textiles, tools, and other products will increase as profit opportuni- ties expand in the second economy. For example, a recent Soviet radio report said that 242,000 kilograms (242 metric tons) of sugar was stolen in 1987 partly as a result of the spread of "home distilling." A recent Soviet article on the second economy observed that the main advantage of a "private operator" is usually his access to shortage goods?"spare parts for cars, components for household equipment, Finnish wallpa- per and toilet bowls, construction materials, and so forth." Weakened Workers' Incentives State workers' incentives and productivity are likely to suffer when purchasing power is rising but supplies of goods and services are not. At state stores, longer queues and greater shortages will result in more absenteeism from work, as working wives and mothers 11 especially struggle to ensure that food is on the table. Recently the official Literaturnaya gazeta reported that 65 billion hours are spent each year in shop- ping?about 32 million man-years representing 25 percent of total annual employment.? Moreover, while rubles can always be spent in the second economy on food, services, and handicraft items, longer waiting lists for such big-ticket items as cars, appliances, housing, and furniture could result in a greater sense of futility. This will be especially true if such goods come to be recognized as being rationed through nonmoney means such as political connections. Excess purchasing power will also undermine Gorba- chev's wage reform, which is predicated on Soviet workers' wanting to earn more rubles. Under this reform, workers' wages and salaries are to increase about 30 percent, but at the same time pay is to correspond much more closely to productivity. But if desired goods are not readily available, rubles are worth less and the incentive effects of the wage reform will be blunted. Price Reform Constrained Most Western analysts and many Soviet economists agree that reform of the price-setting mechanism is essential for the success of Gorbachev's effort to revitalize the economy. The decree on the price reform published in July 1987 makes clear that one of its major objectives is to reduce the role of state authorities in establishing prices and give greater freedom to enterprises to set prices through negotia- tions. Given strong inflationary pressures, however, any relaxation of state controls will lead to large price increases across the board. Reform advocates, aware that price reform rather than excess money creation would be blamed for this inflation, have called for resolving the financial problem before relaxing state controls on prices. Gorbachev said in his party confer- ence speech that resolving the deficit was a precondi- tion for price reform. 1? Much of this time does not represent absenteeism because it includes shopping by retirees and housewives, as well as shopping after work hours. Nonetheless, since most state stores are not open in the evenings or on weekends, a large proportion of these hours must involve absences from work. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Price reform in China has run into just such difficul- ties. On several occasions, price controls have been relaxed only to be tightened again when rapid price increases occurred, even though rapid money supply growth was a key factor behind the increases. Gorbachev's Options Gorbachev indicated in his February 1988 speech that "extraordinary efforts"?"radical" reform and great- ly increased production of consumer goods and ser- vices?were needed to bring the "financial problem" under control. In his July speech at the Central Committee plenum, the General Secretary was much more explicit, stating that the 1989 budget and economic plan should incorporate measures, possibly even a reduction in investment, to reduce the deficit. Removal of Subsidies Under the forthcoming price reform announced last year, retail prices are to be revised although major changes are to be preceded by a public debate. Removal of subsidies on food products could result in large savings of government expenditures. Food prod- ucts alone cost the government 60 billion rubles? roughly the size of the current deficit. Moreover, the effective price increases would devalue much of the accumulated purchasing power in savings accounts and cash hoards. Although the administrative price revision as a whole is supposed to be completed before the beginning of the next five-year plan in 1991, the pricing decree does not set a specific target date for the politically sensitive task of revising retail prices (reducing subsi- dies), as it does for wholesale and procurement prices. Even the reformers have become more aware, howev- er, of the political costs of increasing food prices. The timing of the introduction of higher food prices is an especially difficult problem. Removing the subsi- dies gradually seems to make the most political sense. But from an economic perspective, this would greatly dilute the effectiveness of the policy. Not only would deficit reduction take longer, but also announcement of a policy of gradual reductions in subsidies would set in motion a number of responses by the populace. Hoarding would increase. Savers would start drawing out their deposits to turn them into material goods. Owners of cash hoards would do the same. The result would be rampant price increases in the second economy, including collective farm markets, and mostly empty shelves in state stores. On the other hand, an overnight removal of subsidies maximizes its economic benefits (since consumers and savers have no chance to adjust) but carries higher political risks. As reform economist Nikolay Shmelev recently wrote: "We must not forget the lamentable experience of Poland, where, in 1976, they tried to change prices overnight, and were then forced to retreat." The recent unrest in Poland tied to a 45- percent increase in prices since the first of the year is a pointed reminder, if one was needed. Lower subsidies of industrial goods also would reduce government spending. According to the price reform decree, subsidies for industrial output sold to the agricultural sector are to be eliminated. For example, agricultural enterprises are to pay the same rates as industry for electricity, heat, and natural gas. Price increases, however, would help the budget only if they do not result in compensating expenditures. For example, some Soviet economists have argued that consumers will need to be compensated for the expected retail price increases through such measures as reducing income taxes or providing supplements to wages and pensions. The relief to the budget from reduced subsidies would be diluted by any increases in expenditures for pensions or reductions in tax collections. Gorbachev's reforms also intend to reduce the bud- get's role in financing investment by increasing the role of enterprises. Spending on investment represents about a third of the budget. But it is not clear that this measure will reduce the budget deficit, since the share of state deductions from enterprise profits is to fall also so that firms are able to invest more. 12 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18 : CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Increased Sales of Consumer Goods Increased sales of certain consumer goods could raise substantial tax revenues." Such manufactured con- sumer goods as appliances, automobiles, clothing, and shoes carry high tax rates, and thus increased produc- tion and sales of them would contribute to increased budget receipts. Gorbachev's push for the expansion of cooperatives that produce consumer goods and services could also contribute to state revenues to the extent they earn high incomes and meet their tax obligations. The quickest step Moscow could take to raise reve- nues through increased consumer goods production would be to back off the antialcohol campaign and permit legal sales of alcoholic beverages to increase. A 6 May Izvestiya article called for a reassessment of the antialcohol campaign, stating that the grumbling it caused was more dangerous than drunkenness. Moscow could use its high credit rating in the West to finance consumer good imports. Because of the large price markups on domestic sales of imported goods, such a policy could earn the state large revenues? amounts equal to 3 to 4 times the values of the loans used to finance the imports. Economist Shmelev estimated in his April 1988 Novyy mir article that the import of consumer goods valued at $1.5-2 billion would cover the loss in state revenues from the reduction in vodka sales. Spending Cuts on Defense and Investment Since the June 1987 plenum, several high-ranking political and military spokesmen have stated publicly that the Soviet Union plans to reduce spending on defense. For example, in an August 1987 interview with a Spanish reporter, Gen. Yuriy Lebedev said that, although the Soviets must be careful not to ignore the armed forces' needs, "nevertheless, our plans include a reduction of military spending in order " A number of Soviet officials and economists have proposed increased production of consumer goods and services also as the solution to the purchasing power overhang. Given the low state prices of many consumer goods and services, the supply increases needed to equate supply and demand would be extraordinary and essentially impractical. This proposal illustrates the Soviet predilic- tion to focus on the supply side of market imbalances rather than demand and the role of prices. 13 to allocate the money to other areas." While this statement and similar ones could reflect a propaganda motive, they might also reflect the budget situation. Reduced outlays on investment would also trim the budget deficit, but it is not clear which areas could afford to be cut back: ? Growth of energy production requires continued large investments. ? As a key element of the modernization program, the machine-building industry is scheduled to receive large amounts of investment through the rest of the five-year plan period (1986-90). ? The rest of heavy industry and transportation all are in need of large investments for modernization, new projects, and upkeep of existing plant and equipment. ? Gorbachev's new emphasis on the consumer implies large investment flows to both housing and indus- tries producing consumer goods and services. The most likely short-term target for reductions would be nonpriority sectors in industry and possibly agriculture. A January 1988 Kommunist article hints strongly that Moscow is considering substantial cut- backs of investment in agricultural machinery and land reclamation. Neglect of industrial sectors for more than a couple of years might produce bottle- necks. Moreover, the economy is structured to pro- duce large amounts of investment goods. Any sub- stantial reduction in investment spending would imply shutting down some of heavy industry. Currency Reform Gorbachev may need to undertake a currency reform to take care of the problem of excess purchasing power, although by itself such a reform would not help the deficit. As in the case of removing consumer subsidies, a currency reform would have to be imple- mented overnight so that consumers and savers could not take evasive actions that would result in large increases in demand for goods. Currency reform is not unprecedented in the Soviet Union. The inflation in World War II greatly in- creased collective farm market prices, resulting in Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18 : CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 large cash accumulations by peasants. Concern about the resulting pent-up demand caused Moscow to decree a currency reform on 14 December 1947 (with no advance notice). The reform consisted of the following elements: ? New currency was issued at a rate of one new ruble to 10 old ones which had the effect of devaluing cash holdings by a factor of 10 (or to one-tenth their previous value). ? State bonds were converted at an exchange rate of 1-to-3 and thus lost two-thirds of their value. ? Savings accounts less than 3,000 rubles were con- verted at an exchange rate of one-to-one. Thus savings of urban workers, who were much more likely to use banks than peasants, were treated favorably. ? Wages and prices were not changed. Thus the primary effect of the currency reform was a sub- stantial confiscation of the wealth of peasants. According to Shmelev, currency reform is a "hot topic of discussion" among Soviet economists today. In his most recent Novyy rnir article, moreover, he points out that "Strong rumors are circulating about a possible monetary reform and the consequent confis- cation of a proportion of investments in savings banks." To avoid a bank run and other adverse reactions, the authorities will probably be quick to deny these rumors. Outlook: Perestroyka Threatened General Secretary Gorbachev, other Soviet leaders, Soviet economists, and others have in the last several years frequently pointed out the serious nature of Soviet economic and financial problems, even at times suggesting that a crisis situation existed. Politically this probably is a useful tactic for justifying the many policy shifts, reforms, and other changes Gorbachev has initiated. However, there is also a tone of real concern in many of the comments, which is reflected in the hurried and heedless nature of many of Gorba- chev's initiatives. However, the rush to put new policies in place has if anything exacerbated the economy's problems. Such key initiatives as sharply increased investment and the antialcohol campaign not only have failed to accom- plish key objectives, but also have contributed to the drastic increases in the state budget deficit and money creation. The cost of living is higher, shortages have intensified, modernization is proceeding at a snail's pace, and the economy's fastest growing industry is moonshining. The General Secretary needs to come to grips with the budget deficit. Most of the options open to him, however, impinge on the welfare of the population or key interest groups, such as the military, just at a time when he needs as much political support as he can garner. Indeed, the leadership apparently has made a decision to do more for the consumer quickly as a means of obtaining the population's backing for peres- troyka. This decision in turn probably means that consumer subsidies will not be reduced soon, despite the large potential this offers for reducing the deficit, nor?for the same reason?are taxes likely to be raised. Large-scale imports of consumer goods and relaxing the antialcohol campaign offer Moscow opportunities to address the budget deficit without gouging an important interest group. Both steps are under discus- sion in Moscow. The leadership may follow through by allowing increased alcohol sales. Increased imports of consumer goods could be easily financed through foreign borrowing, but Moscow so far prefers to reserve foreign loans for investment uses that expand domestic production capacity rather than for current consumption. While in general this restriction makes sense, imports of investment goods do not help resolve the immediate problem of the budget deficit and Soviet conservatism on borrowing for current con- sumption may eventually be relaxed. Gorbachev must act quickly. Because the inflationary impact of the budget deficit exacerbates current consumer problems, the leadership is fighting an uphill battle in trying to improve the quality of life for average citizens and gain support for perestroyka. If the budget deficit is not brought down, it could lead to inflation much worse than the Soviets have experi- enced in the postwar era. 14 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Appendix A Key Tables Our information comes from published and unpub- lished data from the Center for International Re- search (formerly the Foreign Demographic Analysis Division) of the United States Department of Com- merce, various issues of the annual Soviet economic and foreign trade handbooks (Narodnoye kho- zyaystvo SSSR and Vneshnyaya torgovlya), the Sovi- et five-year statistical budget handbooks, the laws on the state budget, and the annual budget speeches of the Soviet Minister of Finance to the Supreme Soviet. The analytical framework behind the tables follows the methodology developed by Mark Harrison in his article, "The USSR State Budget under Late Stalin- ism (1945-55): Capital Formation, Government Bor- rowing and Monetary Growth" in Economics of Planning, Vol. 20, No. 3 (1986). 15 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18 : CIA-RDP91S00056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Table A-1 USSR: Estimated State Revenues From Foreign Trade Billion current rubles 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 Foreign trade prices 1. Exports 2. Imports 3. Net exports Conversion ratios 11.5 12.4 10.6 11.2 12.7 15.8 20.7 24.0 28.0 33.3 35.7 42.4 49.6 57.1 13.3 15.5 18.8 26.7 28.7 30.1 34.6 37.9 44.5 52.6 1.0 1.2 -0.6 0.3 1.9 -2.6 -0.7 3.2 1.1 4.5 5.2 4.5 63.2 67.9 74.4 72.7 68.3 68.1 68.0 56.4 59.6 65.4 69.4 62.6 60.7 61.0 6.8 8.3 9.0 3.2 5.7 7.4 7.0 4. Exports 5. Imports Domestic prices 1.59 1.50 1.40 1.28 1.12 1.04 1.00 0.98 0.96 0.83 0.74 0.66 0.77 0.74 0.70 0.69 0.69 0.69 0.69 2.36 2.36 2.36 2.44 2.21 2.04 2.08 2.06 2.06 1.97 1.86 1.74 1.90 1.95 1.90 1.93 1.93 1.93 1.93 6. Exports 7. Imports 8. Net imports 18.3 24.9 6.6 9. Net exports in foreign trade prices 1.5 converted to domestic prices 18.6 26.5 7.9 1.8 17.8 20.2 31.4 37.9 13.6 17.7 -0.8 0.3 23.2 25.0 28.0 32.6 34.2 35.2 36.7 37.7 48.6 50.2 52.1 50.1 47.1 47.0 46.9 41.6 54.4 59.8 62.0 71.2 74.6 82.7 91.6 107.2 116.2 124.2 134.0 120.8 117.2 117.7 18.4 29.4 31.7 29.4 36.9 39.4 46.0 53.9 58.5 66.0 72.1 83.9 73.7 70.2 70.8 2.1 -2.7 -0.7 3.1 1.1 3.8 3.8 3.0 5.2 6.1 6.3 2.2 3.9 5.1 4.8 10. Estimated foreign trade revenues 8.1 9.7 12.8 18.0 20.5 26.7 31.0 32.5 38.0 43.2 49.8 56.8 63.7 72.1 78.4 86.1 77.6 75.3 75.6 Notes: 1. Lines 1 and 2, 1970-86: Soviet foreign trade handbooks, Vneshnyaya Torgovlya, various years; 1987: Soviet foreign trade journal, Vneshnyaya Torgovlya, No. 3 (March 1988); 1988: estimated. 2. Line 3 = line 1 - line 2. 3. Conversion ratios, 1970-85: Center for International Research, US Department of Commerce printout; 1986-88: same values as 1985 assumed. 4. Line 6 = line 1 X line 4. 5. Line 7 = line 2 X line 5. 6. Line 8 = line 7 - line 6. 7. Line 9 = line 3 X line 4. 8. Line 10 = line 8 + line 9. See Foreign Economic Report, No. 20, Domestic Value of Soviet Foreign Trade: Exports and Imports in the 1972 Input-Output Table, (US Department of Commerce, October 1982), for discussion of methodology used to estimate special earnings from foreign trade. 9. Components may not add to totals shown because of rounding. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Table A-2 USSR: Miscellaneous State Budget Revenues Billion current rubles 1. Local taxes and collections 2. Forest income 3. Rent income 4. Other incomes 5. Total miscellaneous revenues 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 0.8 0.9 0.9 0.9 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.1 1.1 1.1 1.2 1.2 1.3 1.3 1.2 1.2 1.2 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 3.0 2.8 2.4 4.8 5.9 6.0 6.6 5.7 5.1 5.6 6.3 4.8 6.2 7.8 5.5 6.1 6.1 6.1 6.1 4.4 4.2 3.9 6.3 7.5 7.6 8.2 7.3 6.7 7.2 7.9 6.5 8.2 9.8 7.6 8.3 8.1 8.1 8.1 Notes: 2. Line 5 = sum of lines 1 through 4. 1. Lines 1 through 4, 1970-85: the five-year statistical handbooks 3. Components may not add to totals shown because of rounding. on the USSR state budget published by the Ministry of Finance: Gosudarstvennyy Byudzhet SSSR: various years; 1986-88: estimat- ed as annual average of 1981-85. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Table A-3 USSR: Ordinary State Budget Revenues Billion current rubles 1. Turnover tax 2. Payments from profits 3. Taxes on individuals 4. Social insurance taxes 5. Income taxes paid by cooperatives and public enterprises 6. Miscellaneous revenues 7. Total revenues from domestic sources 8. Estimated foreign trade revenues 9. Total 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 49.4 54.5 55.6 59.1 63.5 66.6 70.7 74.6 84.1 88.3 94.1 100.4 100.6 102.9 102.7 97.7 91.5 90.0 89.0 54.2 55.6 60.0 60.0 64.4 69.7 70.6 78.4 78.6 84.2 89.8 92.4 102.4 106.6 115.6 119.5 129.8 135.0 137.5 12.7 13.7 14.8 15.8 17.1 18.4 19.6 20.8 22.1 23.2 24.5 25.5 26.6 27.6 28.8 30.0 31.2 32.4 33.6 8.3 8.8 9.3 9.9 10.6 11.3 12.2 12.4 13.1 13.9 14.2 15.0 22.3 23.1 24.5 25.4 26.5 27.5 28.5 1.2 1.4 1.3 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.6 1.6 1.6 1.7 1.9 1.9 2.2 2.6 2.5 2.6 2.8 2.9 4.4 4.2 3.9 6.3 7.5 7.6 8.2 7.3 6.7 7.2 7.9 6.5 8.2 9.8 7.6 8.3 8.1 8.1 8.1 130.2 138.2 144.9 152.6 164.6 175.1 182.8 195.1 206.2 218.4 232.2 241.7 262.0 272.2 281.8 283.4 289.7 295.8 299.6 8.1 9.7 12.8 18.0 20.5 26.7 31.0 32.5 38.0 43.2 49.8 56.8 63.7 72.1 78.4 86.1 77.6 75.3 75.6 138.3 147.9 157.7 170.6 185.1 201.8 213.8 227.6 244.2 261.6 282.0 298.6 325.8 344.3 360.2 369.5 367.3 371.1 375.2 Notes: 1. Ordinary domestic revenues, also called current revenues, are mainly forms of taxation. They accrue to the government without creating corresponding liabilities that require servicing or redeem- ing in the future. 2. Lines 1 through 5, 1970-86: Narkhoz, various years. 3. Line 1, 1987 and 1988: estimated. Revenues from turnover taxes began to fall sharply in 1985 as a result of the launching of Gorbachev's antialcohol campaign. Further revenue losses due to the antidrinking campaign occurred in 1986 when tax revenues were more than 10 billion rubles below plan. The 1987 plan called for 96.4 billion rubles, but Finance Minister Gostev said in October 1987, "The turnover tax will produce less than planned" in 1987. Gostev also said the plan figure for 1988 was 89 billion rubles, with planned revenues from the sale of alcoholic beverages reduced by 11.5 billion rubles, indicating a possibly more realistic assessment of the effect of the antialcohol campaign on tax revenues. 4. Line 2, 1987 and 1988: estimated as 31 percent of total planned revenues (435.7 and 443.6 billion rubles, respectively, during 1987 and 1988), the average share during 1984-86. 5. Line 3, 1987 and 1988: estimated by increasing previous year's value by 1.2 billion rubles, the average annual increment during 1985-86. 6. Line 4, 1987 and 1988: estimated by increasing previous year's value by 1 billion rubles, the average annual increment during 1985-86. 7. Line 5, 1987 and 1988:- estimated as 0.65 percent of total planned revenues, the average share during 1984-86. 8. Line 6 = table A-2, line 5. 9. Line 7 = sum of lines 1 through 6. 10. Line 8 = table A-1, line 10. 11. Line 9 = line 7 + line 8. 12. Components may not add to totals shown because of rounding. Declassified in Part-Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Table A-4 USSR: Estimated State Budget Deficit Billion current rubles (except where noted) 1. Revenues from domestic sources 2. Estimated foreign trade revenues 3. Sum of ordinary revenues 4. Expenditures 5. Budget deficit 6. Budget deficit (as a percent of expenditures) 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 130.2 138.2 144.9 152.6 164.6 175.1 182.8 195.1 206.2 218.4 232.2 241.7 262.0 272.2 281.8 283.4 289.7 295.8 299.6 8.1 9.7 12.8 18.0 20.5 26.7 31.0 32.5 38.0 43.2 49.8 56.8 63.7 72.1 78.4 86.1 77.6 75.3 75.6 138.3 147.9 157.7 170.6 185.1 201.8 213.8 227.6 244.2 261.6 282.0 298.6 325.8 344.3 360.2 369.5 367.3 371.1 375.2 154.6 164.2 173.2 184.0 197.4 214.5 226.7 242.8 260.2 276.4 294.6 309.8 343.1 354.3 371.2 386.5 417.1 435.5 443.6 16.3 16.3 15.5 13.4 12.3 12.7 12.9 15.2 16.0 14.8 12.6 11.2 17.3 10.0 11.0 17.0 49.8 64.4 68.4 10.5 9.9 8.9 7.3 6.2 5.9 5.7 6.3 6.1 5.3 4.3 3.6 5.1 2.8 3.0 4.4 11.9 14.8 15.4 Notes: 1. Line 1 = table A-3, line 7. 2. Line 2 = table A-3, line 8. 3. Line 3 = table A-3, line 9. 4. Line 4, 1970-86: Narkhoz, various years; 1987 and 1988: USSR state budget laws for 1987 and 1988, respectively. Almost always, actual expenditures turn out to be somewhat greater than expendi- tures given in the budget plan. Only twice in the past 20 years have actual expenditures been lower than the plan. The expenditure figures shown here for 1987 and 1988, therefore, are likely to represent conservative estimates of expenditures for those years. To the extent that expenditures are understated, given the estimate of current revenues, the estimate of the budget deficit will also be understated. 5. Line 5 = line 4 - line 3. 6. Line 6 = line 5/line 4 X 100. 7. Components may not add to totals shown because of rounding. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Table A-5 USSR: Sources of Finance of the State Budget Deficit Billion current rubles 1970 I. Budget deficit 16.3 Known sources of finance 2. Long-term borrowing (bond sales) 0.5 3. Short-term borrowing from the 8.2 State Bank (savings receipts) Residual 4. Implied other short-term borrowing 7.6 from the State Bank 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 16.3 15.5 13.4 12.3 12.7 12.9 15.2 16.0 14.8 12.6 11.2 17.3 10.0 11.0 17.0 49.8 64.4 68.4 0.3 0.3 0.4 0.4 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.7 0.6 0.4 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.4 1.9 2.2 2.5 6.6 7.5 7.9 10.3 12.1 12.0 13.7 14.5 15.1 10.3 9.2 8.6 12.6 15.2 18.7 22.0 24.0 26.0 9.4 7.7 5.0 1.6 0.1 0.2 1.0 0.9 -1.0 1.7 1.6 7.7 -3.7 -5.2 -3.1 25.9 38.2 39.9 Notes: crease in savings deposits reported for first half of 1988. I. Line 1 = table A-4, line 5. 4. Line 4: calculated as the difference between the budget deficit 2. Line 2, 1970-86: Narkhoz, various years; 1987-88: estimated. and long-term and short-term borrowing. 3. Line 3, 1970-86: Narkhoz, various years; 1987: 1987 plan 5. Components may not add to totals shown because of rounding. fulfillment report; 1988: estimated, based on 13-billion-ruble in- Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Appendix B State Revenue From Foreign Trade State revenue from foreign trade is not completely understood by Western analysts.' Simplifying great- ly, the mechanism seems to work in the following way: ? Soviet trade authorities try to keep exports and imports roughly in balance in terms of foreign currencies (or, what amounts to the same thing, in terms of "foreign trade" rubles). ? Moscow prices imports much higher domestically on average than what it pays for them in foreign markets. Accordingly, the value of imports in do- mestic rubles is now about twice what it is in foreign trade rubles. ? On the other hand, domestic prices for exports on average are set lower than foreign trade prices. Exports in foreign trade rubles are now about 40 to 50 percent higher than in domestic rubles. '2 For more details, see V. Treml and B. Kostinsky, Domestic Value of Soviet Foreign Trade (US Department of Commerce, October 1982), FER 20. Reverse Blank 21 The surplus obtained by selling imports to Soviet consumers and enterprises at high domestic prices, and selling exports at high world prices, constitutes the revenue from foreign trade. The Center for International Research (CIR), US Bureau of the Census, estimates that total revenue from foreign trade was 63.7 billion rubles in 1982, or 20 percent of estimated current budget revenues for that year. Consumer goods imports stand out as a source of this surplus because their domestic prices are espe- cially higher than foreign trade prices. For example, according to CIR estimates, textile and apparel imports were priced at 4.3 times their foreign trade prices in 1982. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6 Appendix C The Official Balance as an Indicator of the Estimated Deficit Soviet official budget data almost invariably report a small budget surplus every year. While this surplus clearly is misleading concerning the true relationship between current government revenues and expendi- tures, at the same tithe it does vary somewhat from year to year. Harrison, in his study of trends in the state budget during 1945-55, carried out a statistical analysis that showed that his estimates of the budget deficit were strongly related to the official surplus.? In particular, he found that increases in the official surplus were strongly indicative of reductions in the actual deficit. We carried out a similar analysis for the period 1970- 86 using our estimates of the budget deficit and Soviet data on the official budget surplus. The regression results (table C-1) and the scatter diagram (figure 4) are consistent with Harrison's finding of a significant statistical relationship between the deficit and the official surplus. ' Mark Harrison, "The USSR State Budget under Late Stalinism (1945-1955): Capital Formation, Government Borrowing and Mon- etary Growth," Economics of Planning, Vol. 20, No. 3 (1986), p. 204. Table C-1 Regression Results Key to Symbols Y = estimated budget deficit as percent of state expenditures (from table A-4) X = Soviet official budget surplus as percent of state expendi- tures (derived from data in the Narkhoz, various years) Estimated Equation Y = 9.42? 1.68X 122 = 0.24 (0.77) Sample years: 1970 - 86 Number of observations = 17 Reverse Blank 23 Figure 4 USSR: Estimated Deficit Versus Official Surplus (Percent of state expenditures) Estimated budget deficit 14 A 1986 1970 12 1971 A 10 A A 1972 '973A 1977 8 Regression line 1978 1974 AA 1976 6 A1982 1985 1979A \ A 1983 ? 1975 A ? 1980 1981 4 1984 2 0 0 1 2 3 4 Official budget surplus 317637 6-88 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/01/18: CIA-RDP91500056R000400110002-6