THE GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT OF COMMUNIST CHINA 1952-60

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
C
Document Page Count: 
46
Document Creation Date: 
December 23, 2016
Document Release Date: 
July 11, 2013
Sequence Number: 
1
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
September 1, 1961
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2.pdf2.18 MB
Body: 
Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 CONFIDENTIAL 3 Economic Intelligence Report THE GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT OF COMMUNIST CHINA 1952-60 CIA/RR ER 61-41 September 1961 CENTRAL INTELLIGENCE AGENCY Office of Research and Reports CONFIDENTIAL Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 CONFIDENTIAL Economic Intelligence Report THE GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT OF COMMUNIST CHINA 1952-60 CIA/RR ER 61-41 WARNING This material contains information affecting the National Defense of the United States within the meaning of the espionage laws, Title 18, USC, Secs. '793 and 794, the trans- mission or revelation of which in any manner to an unauthorized person is prohibited by law. CENTRAL INTELLIGENCE AGENCY Office of Research and Reports CONFIDENTIAL Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C -0-N-F- I-D-E-N-T- I- A-L CONTENTS Page The Gross National Product of Communist China, 1952-60 . . Appendixes Appendix A. Statistical Tables Appendix B. Methodology for Estimating the Gross National Product of Communist China 1. Introduction 2. Basic National Accounts, 1952 and 1957-59 . 3. Gross National Product, by Sector of Origin, 1952-60 4. Special Problems Relating to the Estimates of GNP 5 17 17 18 35 39 Tables 1. Communist China: National Income and Product Account, 1952 and 1957-59 2. Communist China: Personal Income and Expenditures Ac- count, 1952 and 1957-59 7 8 3. Communist China: Government Receipts and Expenditures Ac- count, 1952 and 1957-59 9 4. Communist China: Foreign Transactions Account, 1952 and 1957-59 5. Communist China: Gross Saving and Investment Account, 1952 and 1957-59 6. Communist China: Gross National Product, by Sector of Origin, 1952-60 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 50X1 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L 7. Communist China: Per Capita Gross National Product, 1952-60 8. Communist China: Production of Major tural Commodities, 1952 and 1957-60 9. Communist China: Production of Major Commodities, 1952-60 Agricul- Industrial 10. Communist China: Calculation of Changes in In- ventories in Trade, Selected Years, 1951-59 . . Charts Figure 1. Communist China: Total and Per Capita GNP, 1952-60 Figure 2. Communist China: Indexes of Growth of GNP and of Major Economic Sectors, 1952-60 Figure 3. Communist China: Comparison of Increases in Official National Income Statistics and Estimates of GNP, 1952-59 - iv - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Page 13 14 15 33 Following Page 2 2 4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-O-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L THE GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT OF COMMUNIST CHINA* 1952-60 The Chinese Communist economy has expanded at a rapid rate since 1952, although not so rapidly as claimed in official Chinese statistics. Gross national product (GNP), valued in constant (1957) market prices, is estimated to have been 79.2 billion yuan in 1952 and 151.1 billion yuan in 1960,** an average annual increase of 8.4 percent*** for the 8 years. Per capita GNP increased at an average annual rate of 5.9 per- cent during this period.t The trend in total and per capita GNP, 1952-60, is shown in the chart, Figure 1.tt In spite of remarkable economic achievements since 1952, per capita GNP remains small, and Communist China is still far behind Japan, the USSR, and industrialized nations of the West in terms of quality and diversity of industrial production and mastery of modern technology. The economic program was seriously disrupted in 1960 by the second con- secutive year of poor harvestl.by the sudden withdrawal of Soviet tech- nicians, and by the accumulated problems in planning and organization which stemmed from the excesses of the "leap forward" policy. ttt The rapid growth of the modern sectors of the economy -- industry, construction, and transportation and communications -- and the contrast- ing slow and erratic expansion of agriculture are depicted in the chart, Figure 2.tt Industrial production expanded at an average annual rate of almost 20 percent during 1952-60, and the expansion of heavy industrial * The estimates and conclusions in this report represent the best judgment of this Office as of 1 August 1961. ** For estimates of GNP in constant (1957) market prices, see Tables 6 and 7, Appendix A, pp. 12 and 13, respectively, below. The figure for 1960 is a preliminary estimate. Based on a comparison of US and Chinese Communist prices, the preliminary estimate of GNP in 1960 is roughly equivalent to US $86 billion. (All dollar values in this report are in terms of 1960 US dollars.) xxx Measured in terms of the US price structure, the increases in GNP and industrial production achieved during 1952-60, although still im- pressive, would be significantly lower than those shown by valuation in yuan. t Per capita GNP in 1960 was roughly equivalent to 1960 US $125, based on a comparison of US and Chinese Communist prices. tt Following p. 2. ttt The term leap forward as used in this report refers to the regime's policy, instituted in 1958 and carried over into 1959 and early 1960 in milder form, of working men and machines at maximum speed with only secondary concern for the quality and balanced proportioning of output. C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L production was even faster. The industrial sector constituted almost 27 percent* of GNP (at factor cost) in 1960 compared with 12 percent in 1952. The agricultural sector accounted for 35 percent of GNP in 1960 compared with 58 percent in 1952.* Production in the agricultural sector in 1960 was only about 11 percent above the level of 1952 and, on a per capita basis, about 8 percent below the level of 1952. A principal explanation of the rapid growth of the GNP of Communist China lies in the allocation of a large and increasing share of GNP to investment. The expansion of the share of investment in GNP and the off- setting contraction of the share of consumption are shown in the following tabulation of the distribution of GNP, by end use, in 1952 and 1957-59: Percent End Use 1952 1957 1958 1959 Government purchases of goods and services 10.9 10.3 8.8 9.4 Net exports of goods and services -0.4 o.8 O. 0.5 Gross domestic investment 15.1 20.9 29.5 32.6 Personal consumption ex- penditures 74.4 68.0 61.3 57.5 Gross national product (in current domestic market prices) 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 This rapidly increasing investment has been directed mainly toward heavy industry rather than toward light industry, agriculture, housing, and consumer services. The share of GNP allocated to government uses de- clined during this period because military expenditures declined from about 6.5 percent of GNP in the Korean War year of 1952 to about 4.9 percent of GNP in 1959. Consumption and government uses, although de- clining as a proportion of GNP, have increased in absolute terms during these years. Net imports of goods and services were equivalent to 0.4 percent of GNP in 1952, representing Soviet credits used to import mili- tary and industrial goods. By 1957 the Soviet credits were virtually ex- hausted, and net exports in 1957-59 were needed to repay the Soviet debt and to finance China's foreign aid program. * Measured in terms of the US price structure, the agricultural contri- bution to GNP would be somewhat larger and the industrial contribution somewhat smaller than that shown by valuation in yuan. - 2 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 COMMUNIST CHINA: Total and Per Capita GNP, 1952-60 TOTAL GNP (Billion /957 Yuan) 79.2 _.- 86.6 89.8 _ 94.3 05.5 45.4 _ 151.1 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 (Preliminary) PER CAPITA GNP (1957 Yuan) 139 149 151 154 169? 172 201 _ 216 219 35362 8-61 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 (Preliminary) Figure 1 50X1 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 50X1 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 COMMUNIST CHINA Indexes of Growth of GNP and of Major Economic Sectors, 1952-60 1952 1953 1954 35363 8-61 1955 1956 1957 1958 50X1 Figure 2 CONSTRUCTION INDUSTRY TRANSPORTATION AND COMMUNICATIONS TRADE AND MISCELLANEOUS BUSINESS SERVICES GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT (at market prices) PERSONAL SERVICES AND HOUSING SERVICES GOVERNMENT SERVICES AGRICULTURE 1959 1960 (Preliminary) Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 50X1 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Chinese Communist success in the basic policy of restricting in- creases in consumption while rapidly expanding investment has in large part resulted from the extension and refinement of government control over manpower and materials. The rapid rise in the proportion of GNP originating in state enterprises -- from 8.3 percent in 1952 to 24.7 percent in 1959 -- reflects the primary method of extending state con- trol over the economy. Other ways in which state control has been pro- gressively extended under the Communist regime are the following: 1) the allocation of major commodities according to the state plan, 2) the rationing of grain and cotton cloth to consumers, (3) the regula- tion of prices, (4) the control over credit through the state banking system and credit cooperatives, and (5) the collectivization of agricul- ture. Economic growth in Communist China has not been as great as claimed. The chart, Figure 3,* presents a comparison of Chinese claims of increases in national income and estimates (used in this report) of increases in GNP for 1952-59. Conceptual differences between the Chinese measurement of nationAl income and the estimates of GNP in this report partially explain the differing rates of economic growth. The Chinese measurement of na- tional income, for example, excludes most if not all of the income from personal services, housing, and government services. Income originated by these services has expanded slowly since 1952 (see Figure 2**). The major factor explaining these differing rates of growth, however, is the assessment of progress of agricultural production. The Chinese have claimed that the gross value of agricultural production in 1959 was more than 80 percent higher than in 1952. The estimates of the gross value of agricultural production used in this report indicate that the increase was only about 21 percent.*** Numerical estimates of the GNP of Communist China and of the compo- nents of GNP are presented in Tables 1 through 7, Appendix A.t The method used to estimate the GNP is summarized in Appendix B. Following p. 4. ** Following p. 2, above. *** It should be noted that value added in agriculture has increased only about 16 percent between 1952 and 1959 compared with the 21-percent increase in the gross value of agricultural production. t Pp. 7 through 13, below. - 3 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 250 200 150 100 COMMUNIST CHINA Comparison of Increases in Official National Income Statistics and Estimates of GNP, 1952-59 Figure 3 50X1 Chinese Claims of Increase in National Income Estimate of Increases in Gross National Product 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 PERCENTAGE INCREASES OVER THE PRECEDING YEAR 35364 8-61 4.0 9.3 ED Chinese Claims E3 Estimates 5.7 1953 1954 1955 14.0 1956 4.6. 4.3 Fri 1957 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 34.0 21.6 19.8 10.3 1958 1959 50X1 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L APPENDIX A STATISTICAL TABLES Tables 1 through 5 in this appendix* are modeled after the so-called "five-account system" of the US Department of Commerce.** The various segments of economic activity in Communist China are aggregated to give the following accounts: (1) gross national product (GNP), (2) personal income and expenditures, (3) government receipts and expenditures, (4) foreign transactions, and (5) saving and investment. Each segment of economic activity appears in two places, the system operating accord- ing to the fundamental principle of double-entry bookkeeping. Table 6*** gives GNP by sector of origin, in constant 1957 prices. Table 7t combines these estimates of GNP with estimates of population to give estimates of GNP per capita. Tables 8 and 9tt present estimates of production of major agricultural and industrial commodities, respectively. * Pp. 7 through 11, below. 50X1 *** P. 12, below. t P. 13, below. tt pp. 14 and 15, respectively, below. - 5 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Table 1 Communist China: National Income and Product Account 1952 and 1957-59 Billion Current Yuan Item Number 1952 1957 1958 1959 1 Compensation of employees (see Table 2, item 10) '9.3 18.8 21.2 25.4 2 Agricultural income 39.1 47.5 52.9 51.5 3 Agricultural taxes (see Table 3, item 9) 2.9 3.4 3.7 3.7 4 Agricultural income (after taxes) (see Table 2, item 16) 36.2 44.1 49.2 47.8 5 Income of nonstate nonagricultural enterprises 7.6 10.4 11.0 9.3 6 Income taxes (see Table 3, item 11) o.8 1.8 1.4 7 Income (after taxes) (see Table 2, item 17) 6.8 8.6 9.6 9.3 8 Income of state enterprises 6.1 15.4 24.9 37.2 9 Dividends to former owners of private enterprises (see Table 2, item 15) 0 0.1 0.1 0.1 10 Undistributed (to persons) income (see Table 5, item 7) 6.1 15.3 24.8 37.1 11 Rental income and personal service income (see Table 2, item 18) 5.0 7.1 7.6 8.3 12 Indirect taxes (see Table 3, item 12) 6.3 10.7 14.1 17.2 13 Statistical discrepancy (see Table 5, item 14) 0.6 1.3 1.6 1.5 Gross national product 74.0 111.2 133.3 150.4 14 Personal consumption expenditures (see Table 2, item 1) 55.0 75.7 81.8 86.6 15 Gross domestic investment (see Table 5, item 1) 11.2 23.2 39.3 49.o 16 Net exports of goods and services -0.3 0.9 0.5 0.7 17 Exports (see Table 4, item 1) 3.2 5.8 6.8 7.9 18 Imports (see Table 4, item 2) 3.5 4.9 6.3 7.2 19 Government purchases of goods and services (see Table 3, item 1) 8.1 11.4 11.7 i4.1 Gross national product 74.0 111.2 133.3 150.4 - 7 - c -0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Table 2 Communist China: Personal Income and Expenditures Account 1952 and 1957-59 Billion Current Yuan Item Number 1952 1957 1958 1959 1 Personal consumption expenditures (see Table 1, item 14) 55.0 75.7 81.8 86.6 2 Farm home consumption-in-kind 23.9 26.8 29.1 26.2 3 Retail sales to consumers 24.6 40.6 43.8 50.7 4 Wages-in-kind of government employees 0.7 0 0 0 5 Agricultural consumer services and house rent 2.4 2.8 3.0 3.1 6 Nonagricultural consumer services 1.9 3.6 3.9 4.5 7 Nonagricultural house rent 1.5 1.9 2.0 2.1 8 Personal tax and nontax payments (see Table 3, item 10) 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.4 9 Personal saving (see Table 5, item 13) 2.5 3.7 6.2 6.1 Personal expenditures and saving 57.9 79.8 88.3 93.1 10 Compensation of employees (see Table 1, item 1) 9.3 18.8 21.2 25.4 11 Workers and salaried employees 12 Wages and salaries 7.4 15.3 17.6 21.5 13 Supplements 0.5 1.6 1.6 1.8 14 Military, including supporting, personnel 1.4 1.9 2.0 2.1 15 Dividends to former owners of private enterprises (see Table 1, item 9) 0 0.1 0.1 0.1 16 Agricultural income (after taxes) (see Table 1, item 4) 36.2 44.1 49.2 47.8 17 Income (after taxes) from nonstate nonagricultural enterprises (see Table 1, item 7) 6.8 8.6 9.6 9.3 18 Rental income and personal service income (see Table 1, item 11) 5.0 7.1 7.6 8.3 19 Agricultural consumer services and house rent 2.4 2.8 3.0 3.1 20 Nonagricultural personal services 1.4 2.7 2.9 3.4 21 Nonagricultural house rent 1.2 1.6 1.7 1.8 22 Government transfer payments (see Table 3, item 5) 0.6 1.0 0.5 2.1 23 Personal interest income (see Table 3, item 6) 2/ 0.1 0.1 0.1 Personal income 57.9 79.8 88.3 93.1 a. Less than 50 million yuan. - 8 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Table 3 Communist China: Government Receipts and Expenditures Account 1952 and 1957-59 Billion Current Yuan Item Number Purchases of goods and services (see Table 1, item 19) 1952 1957 1958 1959 1 8.1 11.4 11.7 14.1 2 Military 4.8 6.3 6.0 7.3 3 Health and education 1.3 2.8 3.2 3.8 4 Administration 2.0 2.3 2.5 3.0 5 Transfer payments (see Table 2, item 22) 0.6 1.0 0.5 2.1 6 Interest paid to persons (see Table 2, item 23) 2,/, 0.1 0.1 0.1 7 Interest paid to foreign governments (see Table 4, item 3), 21 0.1 0.1 2/ 8 Surplus on income and product account (see Table 5, item 12) 1.7 3.7 7.1 5.0 Government expenditures and surplus 10.4 16.3 19.5 21.3 9 Agricultural taxes (see Table 1, item 3) 2.9 3.4 3.7 3.7 10 Personal tax and nontax receipts (see Table 2, item 8) 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.4 11 Income taxes from nonstate nonagricultural enterprises (see Table 1, item 6) 0.8 1.8 1.4 o 12 Indirect taxes (see Table 1, item 12) 6.3 10.7 14.1 17.2 Government receipts 10.4 16.3 19.5 21.3 a. Less than 50 million yuan. - 9 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Table Ii- Communist China: Foreign Transactions Account 1952 and 1957-59 Billion Current Yuan Item Number 1952 19>7 1958 1959 1 Exports of goods and services (see Table 1, item 17) 3.2 5.8 6.8 7.9 Receipts from abroad 3.2 5.8 6.8 IL2 2 Imports of goods and services (see Table 1, item 18) 3.5 4.9 6.3 7.2 3 Interest paid to foreign governments (see Table 31 item 7) 2/ 0.1 0.1 2/ 14 Net foreign investment (see Table 51 item 6) -0.3 0.8 0.4 0.7 Payments abroad 3.2 5.8 6.8 LU a. Less than 50 million yuan. - 10- Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/97/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Table 5 Communist China: Gross Saving and Investment Account 1952 and 1957-59 Billion Current Yuan Item Number 1952 1957 1958 1959 1 Gross domestic investment (see Table 1, item 15) 11.2 23.2 39.3 49.0 2 "Peasant" investment 1.3 2.1 5.6 6.3 3 Budgeted investment 5.0 13.8 24.0 29.3 4 Extrabudgetary investment 1.0 2.0 5.3 5.0 5 Changes in inventories 3.9 5.3 4.4 8.4 6 Net foreign investment (see Table 4, item 4) -0.3 0.8 o.4 0.7 Gross investment 10.9 24.0 1 49.7 7 Undistributed (to persons) income of state enterprises (see Table 1, item 10) 6.1 15.3 24.8 37.1 8 9 Remitted to the state treasury Retained by central government ministries, local governments, and enterprises 10 Major repair funds 11 Other funds 12 Government surplus on income and product account (see Table 3, item 8) 1.7 13 Personal saving (see Table 2, item 9) 2.5 14 Statistical discrepancy (see Table 1, item 13) 0.6 Gross saving and statistical discrepancy 5.6 14.0 21.9 0.5 1.3 2.9 0.4 1.0 1.3 0.1 0.3 1.6 3.7 3.7 1.3 7.1 6.2 1.6 5.0 6.1 1.5 10.9 24.0 39.7 49.7 -11- Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 33.3 3.8 1.6 2.2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Table 6 Communist China: Gross National Product, by Sector of Origin 1952-60 Billion 1957 Yuan Economic Sector 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 2/ Agriculture 42.1 42.6 41.2 44.2 46.3 47.5 51.7 48.7 46.7 Industry 8.6 10.7 12.5 12.6 15.6 17.6 25.6 32.6 36.5 Construction 1.7 2.8 3.1 3.4 4.6 4.2 6.3 7.5 7.5 Transportation and communications 3.7 4.5 5.3 5.6 6.6 7.3 9.3 12.4 l4.4 Trade and miscellaneous business services 6.3 7.2 7.9 8.3 9.7 9.9 11.6 13.3 13.6 Personal services and housing services 5.6 6.1 6.3 6.4 6.9 7.1 7.5 8.0 8.2 Government services 5.0 5.3 5.2 5.4 5.8 5.7 5.8 6.0 6.2 Gross national product (at factor cost) 73.0 79.2 81.5 85.9 95.5 99.3 117.8 128.5 133.1 Indirect taxes 6.2 7.4 8.3 8.4 10.0 10.7 14.0 16.9 18.0 Gross national product (at market prices) 79.2 86.6 89.8 94.3 105.5 110.0 y 131.8 145.4 151.1 Index of gross national product Previous year = 100 109 104 105 112 104 120 110 104 1952 = 100 100 109 113 119 133 139 166 184 191 a. Preliminary estimates -- no general economic report covering 1960 has been issued by the Chinese Communist government. b. This gross national product total for 1957 is 1.2 billion yuan lower than the gross national product total in Table 1 (p. 7, above) because the statistical discrepancy has not been included. The estimates for the years other than 1957 are derived from the figures for 1957 and are in 1957 prices; consequently, there is no problem of a statistical discrepancy for these years. - 12 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Table 7 Communist China: Per Capita Gross National Product 1952-60 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 2/ Gross national product (billion 1957 yuan) 79.2 86.6 89.8 94.3 105.5 110.0 131.8 145.4 151.1 Population (million persons at midyear) 570 583 596 611 626 641 657 674 689 Per capita gross national product (1957 yuan) 139 149 151 154 169 172 201 216 219 Index of per capita gross national product (1952 = 100) 100 107 109 111 122 124 145 155 158 a. Preliminary estimates -- no general economic report covering 1960 has been issued by the Chinese Communist government. - 13 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Table 8 Communist China: Production of Major Agricultural Commodities 1952 and 1957-60 Million Metric Tons Commodity 1952 1957 1958 1959 1960 2/ Rice 75 87 99 90 90 Wheat 22 24 29 28 20 Other grains 53 53 51 46 45 Tubers (grain equivalent) 18 22 33 26 30 Total grains 168 18512/ 212 190 180 to 190 Soybeans 9.5 10.0 9.8 9.5 9.0 to 9.5 Peanuts 2.3 2.6 2.8 2.3 2.1 Rapeseed 0.93 0.89 1.10 0.95 1.03 Sesame seed 0.52 0.31 0.37 0.38 0.35 Cotton (ginned) 1.3 1.6 2.1 1.8 1.8 Tobacco (flue-cured) 0.22 0.26 0.38 0.42 0.43 Vegetables 45 62 56 70 65 Meat sj 5.1 5.6 5.8 5.6 5.2 a. Preliminary estimates -- no general economic report covering 1960 has been issued by the Chinese Communist government. b. Because of rounding, components do not add to the total shown. c. Pork, beef (including buffalo), mutton and goat, and poultry. - 14 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Table 9 Communist China: Production of Major Industrial Commodities 1952-60 Commodity Crude steel Coal Crude oil Electric power Machine tools 2/ Trucks Tractors Cement Timber Paper (machine-made) Chemical fertilizer / Sulfuric acid Cotton cloth 2/ Cigarettes Salt Unit 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 Million metric tons 1.35 1.77 2.22 2.85 4.46 5.35 8.0 Million metric tons of standard fuel equiva- lents -12/ 61.7 64.7 77.7 91.3 102.5 121.4 213.3 Million metric tons 0.44 0.62 0.79 0.97 1.16 1.46 2.26 Billion kilowatt-hours 7.26 9.2 11.0 12.3 16.6 19.3 27.5 Thousand 13.7 20.5 15.9 13.7 25.9 28.3 30 Thousand 0 0 0 0 1.6 7.5 15.5 Thousand 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 Million metric tons 2.86 3.88 4.60 4.56 6.39 6.86 9.30 Million cubic meters 11.2 17.5 22.2 20.9 20.8 27.9 35.0 Million metric tons 0.37 0.43 0.55 0.59 0.74 0.91 1.22 Thousand metric tons 39 53 71 85 132 159 266 Thousand metric tons 190 260 344 375 517 632 740 Billion linear meters 3.83 4.69 5.23 4.36 5.77 5.05 5.7 Million cases f/ 2.6 3.6 3.7 3.6 3.9 4.5 4.8 Million metric tons 4.9 3.6 4.9 7.5 4.9 8.3 10.4 1959 1960 2/ 13.4 18.4 274.5 296.0 3.7 4.6 41.5 57 33 38 19.4 16.9 5 lo 12.27 14 41.2 43 1.70 1.8 408 500 1,050 1,360 7.5 6.5 5.5 5.5 11.0 14.0 a. b. C. d. e. f. Preliminary estimates -- no general economic report covering 1960 has been issued by the Chinese Communist government. Standard fuel has a calorific value of 7,000 kilocalories per kilogram. Machine tools that approximate internationally accepted classifications for metalcutting machine tools. Chemical nutrient equivalents based on amounts of nitrogen, phosphoric anhydride, and potassium oxide. Including machine-made and handicraft production. One case contains 50,000 cigarettes. - 15 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L APPENDIX B METHODOLOGY FOR: ESTIMATING ifit GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT OF COMMUNIST CHINA 1. Introduction No single measure is adequate to assess the economic capability of a country: the choice of a measure depends on the purpose for which it is needed -- for example, whether for an assessment of military strength, consumer welfare, or economic growth. The closest approach to a general measure of the over-all economic strength of a country is an estimate of the value of all the final (as opposed to intermediate) goods and services produced during a specified period, usually 1 year. This measure of total output is called gross national product (GNP). GNP is estimated through the construction of national accounts for the economy, in which each segment of economic activity -- such as agri- cultural production -- is defined, measured, and aggregated. The system of nationnl accounts used in this report, as noted pre- viously, is modeled after the five-account system of the US Department of Commerce. Every major transaction appears twice -- compensation of employees, for example, appears in the National Income and Product Ac- count and in the Personal Income and Expenditures Account. The method- ology used to estimate a given transaction, however, is discussed only once -- the method used to estimate compensation of employees, for ex- ample, is discussed under the Personal Income and Expenditures Account whereas under the National Income and Product Account reference is made to the discussion under the Personal Account. The double-entry feature provides a check on the accuracy of indi- vidual estimates and on the consistency of the relationships among the five accounts. Wherever possible, the entries were estimated independ- ently. Where limitations of the data did not permit independent estima- tion of the entries -- for example, in the case of personal saving, government surplus on income and product account, and net foreign in- vestment -- it was necesa'ary to derive the total expenditures of an account from its total income. In these instances the dependence of one side of the account on the other explains the absence of a statis- tical discrepancy. The precision implied by the set of accounts fails to disclose the ranges of uncertainty that surround particular estimates within the ac- counts. The conceptual frame of reference used differs from that em- ployed by the State Statistical Bureau of Communist China in preparing - 17 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L official Chinese data. For this reason, it has been necessary in many instances to adjust the available official data to fit the system of na- tional accounts used in this report. Furthermore, on occasion it has been necessary to derive particular estimates as residuals from larger. reported totals. Both of these operations have been hampered by the lack of detailed data and of full knowledge of that is included in the reported totals. In addition, because official data exaggerated claims for in- creases in production of grain in 1952-54 and production of grain and other agricultural products in 1958-59, estimates by Western analysts were employed in these instances. In the earlier period the exaggeration may have resulted from an inadequate system of statistical collection and re- porting, which resulted in an understatement of production in the base year. The gross overstatement of actual agricultural production in 1958-59, however, was clearly the result of the political influences of the "leap forward." As a result, although the detailed data presented in the accounts are believed to adequately reflect relative orders of magnitude, the individual entries should be viewed as having varying de- grees of uncertainty attached to them. Lack of data prevented the estimation of the distribution of GNP, in current prices, by sector of origin for the years after 1957. Data also are insufficient to provide adequate price deflators for the major end- use estimates in current prices. For the purpose of indicating trends in GNP in constant prices, GNP in 1957 prices (see Table 6*) has been calculated on the basis of an estimate of GNP, by sector of origin, in 1957 and of indexes of production in each of the economic sectors for the years 1952-60. 2. Basic National Accounts, 1952 and 1957-59 a. National Income and Product Account (Table 1**) (1) Compensation of Employees (See b, (10), p. 26, below.) (2) Agricultural Income Agricultural income as treated in this report includes the value added*** by agriculture, forestry, animal husbandry, agricultural side-occupations, fishery (exclusive of fishing by mechanical means), * Appendix A, p. 12, above. ** Appendix Al p. 7, above. *** The value added in any economic sector is the value of production in that sector minus the value of raw materials and intermediate products bought from other sectors. - 18 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L handicrafts in production of goods that were produced and consumed on the farm, and preliminary processing of agricultural products. This entry was calculated by subtracting the value of seed and feed grains, chemical fertilizer, and other products used up in production from the gross value of agricultural production. The Chinese Communists have reported the gross value of agri- cultural production in 1957 to be 64.87 billion yuan in 1957 prices. 2/ Official data on the gross value in 1957 of production of grain, indus- trial crops, vegetables and other crops, and livestock and livestock products have been found to be reasonably consistent with estimates of the gross value of these commodity groups derived by aggregating the production figures for rice, wheat, hogs, and other agricultural prod- ucts on the basis of sample farm sale prices in 1957 for these products. The gross value of agricultural production in 1952 and 1958-59, in 1957 prices, was calculated by summing the gross value of production of grain, industrial crops, livestock and livestock products, and the other commodity groups within agriculture. The gross value of production of grain in 1952 and 1958-59 -- 39 percent of the gross value of agricultural production in 1957 -- was calculated by multiplying the gross value of production of grain in 1957 by an index of production of rice, wheat, other food grains, and soybeans in 1952 and 1958-59 (1957 production equaling 100). This index of production of grain was com- puted by taking quantity relatives* and weighting by the farm sale price of each product in 1957. The gross value of production of the other com- modity groups within agriculture was calculated by the same method used for grain. The value of products used up in production was calculated on the basis of (a) data on retail sales of production materials to agri- culture, 00 estimates of seed and feed grain, and (c) Chinese Communist claims of gross value and net value of agricultural production in 1955 and 1956. Agricultural income in 1952 and 1958-59, in 1957 prices, was converted to current prices on the basis of an index of farm sale prices. ..31 (3) Agricultural Taxes This item covers agricultural taxes, which are included in the state budget, and local surtaxes and levies for village administra- tion, which are not included in the state budget. Agricultural taxes included in the state budget in 1952 and 1957-59 and local surtaxes and levies for village administration in 1957-59 have been reported by the Chinese Communists. Estimates of local surtaxes and levies for village * For estimates of production of major agricultural products in 1952 and 1957-60, see Table 8, Appendix A, p. 14, above. - 19 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L administration in 1952 and 1959 can be derived from other official data.11/ (4) Agricultural Income (After Taxes) This entry is the residual after agricultural taxes are subtracted from agricultural income. (5) Income of Nonstate Nonagricultural Enterprises This item includes income originated by (a) state-private, cooperative, and private industrial and commercial enterprises; 00 native transportation and handling services; (c) peddlers; and (d) construction activities of farmers. Rough estimates of income originated by these enterprises are as follows: Billion Current Yuan 1952 1957 1958 1959 State-private, cooperative (except handicraft coopera- tives), and private enterprises 3.27 2.80 2.15 Nonstate handicrafts (handicraft cooperatives and independent handicraftsmen) 1.70 2.87 3.02 Native transportation and hand- ling services 1.73 3.21 3.71 Peddlers 0.39 0.43 0.43 Construction activities by farmers 0.46 1.04 1.72 Total 1,22 10.35 11.03 0.10 2.46 4.32 0.43 1.97 9.28 Income originated by state-private, cooperative (except handi- craft cooperatives), and private enterprises was estimated as follows: (a) for 1952, on the basis of an estimate of income taxes paid by these enterprises and a Chinese Communist statement of the ratio of income taxes to income of these enterprises; 00 for 1957, on the assumption that the ratio of profits and depreciation reserves to the gross value of produc- tion of these enterprises was the same as the same ratio for state indus- trial and commercial enterprises; and (c) for 1958, on the assumption that income originated in 1958 had the same relationship to income originated in 1957 as the income taxes paid by these enterprises in 1958 had to simi- lar income taxes in 1957. By September 1958 the state-private and coopera- tive enterprises in this group were turning over their income to the state -20- C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L treasury in the form of profits remittances. Income originated by private industrial and commercial enterprises in 1959 was very small and is roughly estimated to be 100 million yuan. Income originated by nonstate handicrafts in 1952 and 1957 was calculated on the assumption that the value added by handicraft pro- duction in these years was the same proportion of the gross value of handicraft production as it was in 1956. The Chinese Communist figure for net value of handicraft production in 1956 was adjusted (a) to in- clude depreciation and (b) to exclude indirect taxes. Because of the industrial reorganization and the formation of communes in 1958, organi- zational control of handicraft activity changed considerably in 1958 and 1959. Of the units engaged in nonstate handicraft production in 1957, some units came under full state control in 1958, some units came under commune control, and some units remained as handicraft cooperatives and independent handicraftsmen. The estimates for 1958 and 1959 of income originated by handicraft activity represent rough estimates of the in- come originated by units that did not come under state control and there- fore did not remit profits to the state treasury. Budget data provide figures for taxes on rural industry and commerce for 1957-59, and it was assumed that income originated in handicraft-type production increased at roughly the same rate as these taxes. The Chinese Communists have re- ported that 37 percent of the handicraft cooperatives (according to mem- bership) had been transformed into state-owned factories by the end of 1958 2/ and that 37.8 percent had been so converted by May 1959. g The handicraft cooperatives that became state-owned factories probably were transferred to state ownership in the latter half of 1958. It was as- sumed, therefore, that only one-third of income originated in 1958 by these units went to the state. On the basis of the above information, it was estimated that 88 percent of the income originated by handicraft- type production in 1958 and that 63 percent in 1959 came from nonstate handicraft units. Income originated by native transportation and handling serv- ices has been estimated to be 1,730 million yuan in 1952 and 2,600 mil- lion yuan in 1955. 1/ Income originated by native transportation and handling services was assumed to have increased at the same rate as total retail sales of commercial enterprises in 1957 above 1955 and at the same rate as total retail sales in 1958 and in 1959. Income originated by peddlers has been estimated to be 390 million yuan in 1952 and 400 million yuan in 1955. .?./ The 1957 estimate was derived from the 1955 estimate on the basis of the increase in total retail sales by commercial enterprises. Income originated by peddlers was assumed to have remained in 1958 and 1959 at roughly the level of 1957. -21- Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Income originated by farmers in construction activities was estimated to be one-half of total budget expenditures on agricultural construction including water conservation projects. (6) Income Taxes of Nonstate Nonagricultural Enterprises In 1952, income taxes of private enterprises were stated to be about 700 million yuan. Income taxes of state-private and cooperative enterprises were small in magnitude and were roughly estimated to be 100 million yuan. Income taxes were reported to be 1,391 million yuan in January-August 1958, 16.0 percent of total industrial-commercial taxes, and 1,186 million yuan in January-August 1957, 16.1 percent of total industrial-commercial taxes. 2/ Total industrial-commercial taxes were 11.30 billion yuan in 1957, and income taxes for 1957 were estimated to have been 16 percent of total industrial-commercial taxes. Because of the adoption of the new consolidated industrial-commercial tax, income taxes were not collected after about 1 September 1958. After about 1 September 1958, income of state-private enterprises was turned over to the state treasury in the form of profits remittances. (7) Income (After Taxes) of Nonstate Nonagricultural Enterprises This entry is the difference between the income of nonstate nonagricultural enterprises and the income taxes paid by these enter- prises. (8) Income of State Enterprises This item is the sum of dividends paid to former owners of private enterprises and of undistributed income of state enterprises. Income of state enterprises includes income of state-owned enterprises for all years, profits of state-private enterprises remitted to the state treasury in the period 1 January 1957 to 1 September 1958, all income of state-private enterprises after 1 September 1958, and all in- come of supply and marketing cooperatives in 1958-59. (9) Dividends to Former Owners of Private Enterprises A recent Chinese Communist publication 12/ states that pay- ments are made from the state treasury in the amount of 120 million yuan annmally to the former owners of private business and industrial enter- prises. The first of these annual payments was made in 1956, and the last payment will be made in 1962. (10) Undistributed (to Persons) Income of State Enterprises (See el (7), p. 34, below.) - 22 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L (11) Rental Income and Personal Service Income (See b, (18), p. 28, below.) (12) Indirect Taxes Indirect taxes were calculated by subtracting agricultural taxes included in the state budget and income taxes of nonstate nonagri- cultural enterprises from total taxes. (13) Statistical Discrepancy This item represents the excess of the estimate of GNP in terms of final product flows over the estimate of GNP in terms of the income generated in its production. The statistical discrepancy arises because of inaccuracies in the estimates of components. (14) Personal Consumption Expenditures (See b, (1), below.) (15) Gross Domestic Investment (See e, (1), p. 31, below.) (16) Net Exports of Goods and Services This item is the difference between exports of goods and services and imports of goods and services. (17) Exports of Goods and Services (See d, p. 30, below.) (18) Imports of Goods and Services (See d, (2), p. 31, below.) (19) Government Purchases of Goods and Services (See c, (1), p. 28, below.) b. Personal Income and Expenditures Account (Table 2*) (1) Personal Consumption Expenditures This item is the sum of farm home consumption-in-kind; retail sales to consumers, wages-in-kind of government employees, agricultural * Appendix A, p. 8, above. - 23 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 consumer services and house rent, nonagricultural consumer services, and nonagricultural house rent. (2) Farm Home Consumption-in-Kind The estimate of farm home consumption-in-kind consists of the imputed value* of farm products that are produced and consumed on the farm. The estimates for 1952 and 1957 were derived by subtracting from the gross value of agricultural production (a) seed, feed grains, and other intermediate products produced by the agricultural sector and used up in production; (b) sales -- including tax payments in kind -- of grain, hogs, and other farm products to the nonagricultural sector of the econ- omy; and (c) intrasector investment. Because of the lack of adequate data on the sale of farm prod- ucts to the nonagricultural sector, the value of farm home consumption- in-kind in 1958-59 was computed by multiplying the value of farm home consumption-in-kind in 1957 by an index of farm home consumption-in-kind of major farm products in 1957-59. The index of farm home consumption- in-kind of major farm products was computed by taking estimates of the physical quantities of grain, cotton, vegetables, meat, and other farm products consumed on the farm in 1957-59 and weighting by the estimated farm sale price for each product. In 1957 the value of farm home consumption-in-kind of these major farm products accounted for almost three-fourths of total farm home consumption-in-kind. (3) Retail Sales to Consumers Retail sales of consumer goods to consumers were estimated by subtracting from total retail sales (a) sales of office supplies and other consumer goods to government and business; (b) sales of tools, chemical fertilizers, and other production materials to rural areas; and (c) sales of house repair materials. Total retail sales and sales of rural production materials have been reported by the Chinese Com- munists. 11/ Sales of consumer goods to government and business have been estimated from Chinese statements on retail sales to "social organs." 12/ Sales of house repair materials were estimated to be roughly 15 percent of nonagricultural house rent in each year. (4) Wages-in-Kind of Government Employees In August 1955 the State Council issued an order on the change- over from the supply system, under which government employees received part of their compensation in grain, cotton cloth, and other consumer goods and * The imputed value of a product is the value that it would have if it were placed on the market. C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L part in money, to a complete money wage system. Under this order those government employees who had been receiving part of their wages-in-kind would receive only money wages, beginning in July 1955. It was also mentioned that in 1955 about one-third of the government employees were still under the supply system. 1.V For the purposes of this estimate, it was assumed that all government employees were under the supply sys- tem in 1952 and that wages-in-kind in 1952 were roughly equivalent to one-half of total money wages. Total money wages of government em- ployees have been estimated to be 1,340 million yuan in 1952. 114/ (5) Agricultural Consumer Services and House Rent This entry consists of the imputed value of on-farm con- sumer services and housing services. Agricultural consumer services and house rent in 1952 have been estimated to be equivalent to 1.4 per- cent and 5.3 percent, respectively, of agricultural income, not includ- ing "peasant" investment and the imputed value of preliminary processing of farm products. 12/ The value of house rent in 1953-59, in 1952 prices, was assumed to have increased at the same rate as total farm housing. lg The value of consumer services was assumed to have increased about 1.5 percent per year in 1953-57 and in 1959, roughly the same rate as the in- crease in the farm population, and to have increased roughly 10 percent in 1958. The value of house rent and consumer services in 1952 prices was converted into current prices on the basis of the index of farm sale prices. (6) Nonagricultural Consumer Services This item includes sales of consumer services by the nonagri- cultural sector of the economy to the agricultural and the nonagricul- tural population. Sales of consumer services to the agricultural popu- lation have been estimated to be equivalent to roughly one-half of the value of on-farm consumer services. 12/ Sales of consumer services to the nonagricultural population have been estimated on the basis of sev- eral reports of household budget studies, which indicate the proportion of total expenditures for commodities and for rent, utilities, and other noncommodity items. lg From the information in these studies, it was estimated that sales of consumer services to the nonagricultural popula- tion were roughly equivalent to 14 percent of total retail sales of con- sumer goods to the nonagricultural population. Educational and medical feea paid to the government were deducted from the total in order to obtain the estimated value of sales of consumer services by such nonagri- cultural activities as utilities, barbering, bathhouses, theaters, pedi- cabs, and funerals. -25- C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L (7) Nonagricultural House Rent Total rent was calculated on the basis of rough estimates of the total housing available (in square meters) 1 and an estimate of the average rent per square meter of private housing. Treated in this manner, total rent includes money rent, imputed rent for self-owned housing, and rental subsidies of all kinds. The information on rents of private housing is extremely limited, but two Chinese Communist reports suggest that average monthly rent per square meter for private housing was about 0.30 yuan in 1957. 2.0./ This average rental probably is related to wage earner housing in urban centers, but it is assumed in this report to represent the average monthly rent per square meter for nonagricultural private housing. Total rent, in 1957 prices, was converted into current prices on the basis of the cost-of-living index for workers and salaried employees for 1952-57 and of estimated increases in retail prices for 1958-59. (8) Personal Tax and Nontax Payments This item consists of miscellaneous fees received by the government from households for educational, health, and cultural serv- ices. Personal taxes and nontax payments are believed to be entered in the state budget account Other Revenue. (9) Personal Saving This item was calculated by subtracting from personal income (a) personal consumption expenditures and (b) personal tax and nontax payments. These estimates appear to be reasonable when checked against estimates of increases in personal savings deposits, purchases of do- mestic bonds, agricultural business savings, and business savings of nonstate nonagricultural enterprises. (10) Compensation of Employees This entry includes only the compensation of workers and salaried employees and of military (including supporting) personnel. Compensation of employees in nonstate handicrafts and native transporta- tion and handling services is included under income from nonstate non- agricultural enterprises. Compensation of employees in personal serv- ices is included under personal service income. (11) Compensation of Workers and Salaried Employees This item includes money wages and salaries, wages and sala- ries paid in kind, and other labor income received by workers and salaried employees of government organs and of state, state-private, cooperative, and private enterprises. - 26 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 (12) Wages and Salaries Total money wages and salaries have been reported by the Chinese Communists for 1952-57 22/ and were claimed to have increased 2.38 billion yuan in 1958. 22/ Total money wages and salaries in 1959 were estimated on the basis of fragmentary data (a) on increases in average money wages and salaries and the number of workers and salaried employees in 1959 and (b) on the planned increase in total and average money wages and salaries and in the number of workers and salaried em- ployees in 1960. (13) Supplements This item consists of wages-in-kind of government employees in 1952 and of nonwage and salary expenditures of enterprises and govern- ment organs for labor insurance, free medical care, subsidies for medical services, canteens and other welfare services, and other fringe benefits in 1952 and 1957-59. This entry does not include budget expenditures for subsidies to students and for relief; which were treated in this report as government transfer payments. The entries for 1952 and 1957 were esti- mated from several Chinese Communist reports on wage supplementary expend- itures. 22/ Estimates for 1958-59 have been derived from the 1957 esti- mate on the basis of claimed increases in these expenditures. 212/ (14) Compensation of Military, Including Supporting, Personnel This item consists of the pay and allowances of military personnel and of supporting civilian personnel. primarily coolie labor. For 1958-59 it 50X1 was assumed that the number of personnel remained constant and that average pay and allowances increased at the same rate as the average money wage of workers and salaried employees (not including those newly employed in 1958-59). aY (15) Dividends to Former Owners of Private Enterprises (See a, (9), p. 22, above.) (16) Agricultural Income (After Taxes) (See a (4), p. 20, above.) (17) Income (After Taxes) from Nonstate Nonagricultural Enterprises (See a, (7), p. 22, above.) -27- C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L (18) Rental Income and Personal Service Income This entry includes income from (a) agricultural consumer services and house rent, (b) nonagricultural personal services, and (c) nonagricultural house rent. (19) Income from Agricultural Consumer Services and House Rent This item was assumed to be the same as expenditures for agricultural consumer services and house rent (see b, (5), p. 25, above). (20) Income from Nonagricultural Personal Services Personal service income of the nonagricultural population was assumed to be roughly three-fourths of the value of nonagricultural consumer services (see b, (6), p. 25, above). The remaining income from nonagricultural consumer services was paid to the state for urban trans- portation, electricity, water, and other utilities. (21) Income from Nonagricultural House Rent Rental income of the nonagricultural population was calculated by subtracting from total rent (see b, (7), p. 26, above) the cost of house repair materials. (22) Government Transfer Payments (See cl (5), p. 29, below.) (23) Personal Interest Income (See c, (6), p. 30, below.) c. Government Receipts and Expenditures Account (Table 3*) The entries in the Government Account were derived largely from information contained in the annual state budget of Communist China and from other Chinese reports on budget revenue and expenditures. (1) Purchases of Goods and Services This item is the gum of budget expenditures for (a) defense; (b) administration; (c) social, cultural, educational, and health ex- penses; (d) other expenses included in the state budget; and (e) other purchases for defense programs included under the state budget account Expenditures on Economic Construction minus budget expenditures for * Appendix Al p. 9, above. - 28 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L student subsidies, relief, and investment in administrative, cultural, educational, and. health facilities plus expenses of village administra- tion not included in the state budget. (2) Military This entry consists of explicit budget expenditures for de- fense and rough estimates of other budget expenditures, military in nature, that are believed to be included under other accounts in the state budget. For example, it is believed that (a) other purchases for defense programs are included under the state budget account Expenditures on Economic Construction; (b) scientific research leading to new weapons is included under the state budget account Social, Cultural, Educational, and Health Expenditures; and (c) wages and subsistence of public security troops and construction of border and coastal defenses are included under the state budget account Expenditures on Administration. (3) Health and Education This item was calculated by subtracting from the reported budget figures for social, cultural, educational, and health expenditures (a) investment expenditures in this category, (b) estimates of government expenditures for relief and student subsidies, and (c) estimates of scien- tific research leading to new weapons. : (4) Administration This item is the residual derived by subtracting from total government purchases of goods and services (a) military purchases and (b) health and education purchases. (5) Government Transfer Payments Government transfer payments consist of budget expenditures (a) for subsidies to students; (b) for social relief and special bene- fits; and (c) in 1959, for government grants of aid to communes and pro- duction brigades. Total social relief and special benefits have been given in the budget data for 1952-57. 22/ Social relief and special benefits were assumed to have been roughly two-thirds of the 1957 level in 1958 and to have roughly doubled in 1959 compared with the level of 1958. Subsidies to students in 1952 and 1957 have been estimated on the basis of budget expenditures for culture, education, and health and of the Chinese Communist statement that subsidies to students were 9.3 per- cent of the total expenditures for culture, education, and health during the period of the First Five Year Plan (1953-57). 2.?i Subsidies to students in 1958 were calculated by subtracting total subsidies to stu- dents for 1952-58 from total subsidies to students for 1952-57. E.22/ Sub- sidies to students in 1959 were assumed to have been roughly three-fourths - 29 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L of the level of 1957. Subsidies to students are believed to have been lower in 1958-59 than in 1957 because students were participating in the "leap forward" production drives. Government aid to communes and production brigades was claimed to have totaled 1 billion yuan in 1959. (6) Interest Paid to Persons This entry represents government payments for interest on domestic bonds and has been calculated on the basis (a) of scheduled payments of interest and bond redemptions, calculated from the Chinese Communist regulations for these bonds, and (b) of the actual payments from the state budget for domestic debt service -- interest and bond redemptions. Ei (7) Interest Paid to Foreign Governments This item covers interest paid by the Chinese Communist Government to the USSR on credits received from the USSR during 1950-57. 32/ (8) Surplus on Income and Product Account This entry was calculated by subtracting from government receipts (a) government purchases of goods and services, (b) government transfer payments, (c) government interest paid to persons, and (d) govern- ment interest paid to foreign governments. (9) Agricultural Taxes (See a, (3), p. 19, above.) (10) Personal Tax and Nontax Receipts (See b, (8), p. 26, above.) (11) Income Taxes from Nonstate Nonagricultural Enterprises (See a, (6), p. 22, above.) (12) Indirect Taxes (See a, (12), p. 23, above.) d. Foreign Transactions Account (Table 4*) (1) Exports of Goods and Services This entry consists of (a) exports, which were calculated on the basis of trade data reported by communist China, the USSR, other * Appendix A, p. 10, above. -30- C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Soviet Bloc countries, and non-Bloc countries; (b) remittances from Overseas Chinese, which were calculated on the basis of reports from Hong Kong and other countries of South and Southeast Asia; and (c) pro- duction of gold, which, on the basis of prewar figures for production of gold in China, was estimated to be roughly 25 million yuan per year. (2) Imports of Goods and Services This entry is the sum of (a) imports, which were calculated from trade data reported by Communist China, the USSR, other Soviet Bloc countries, and non-Bloc countries on an f.o.b. basis, and (b) a rough estimate of the insurance and freight charges associated with these im- ports, which was calculated as a percentage of the value of imports -- the percentage used depending on the distance of the countries from China, the type of transportation used, and the type of commodities involved. (3) Interest Paid to Foreign Governments (See cl (7), p. 30, above.) (4) Net Foreign Investment This item was derived by subtracting from total receipts from abroad (a) Imports of goods and services and 00 interest paid to foreign governments. e. Gross Saving and Investment Account (Table 5*) (1) Gross Domestic Investment Gross domestic investment is the sum of (a) "peasant" in- vestment, (b) budgeted investment, (c) extrabudgetary investment, and (d) changes in inventories. (2) "Peasant" Investment This entry represents total purchases of investment goods by the agricultural sector of the economy. The total of such purchases is composed of (a) purchases of investment goods by the agricultural sector from the nonagricultural sector, through retail trade channels, and 00 purchases of investment goods produced in the countryside by the agricultural sector itself. (3) Budgeted Investment Budgeted investment consists of expenditures from the state budget for (a) investment in capital construction (not including expendi- tures for construction of barracks, military airfields, and similar * Appendix Al p. 11, above. -31- C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 50X1 50X1 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 military projects, which were included under government purchases of goods and services); (b) stockpiling of construction materials; (c) state material reserves; and (d) agricultural operating expenses. This entry was calculated from data contained in the annual state budgets and in several articles in Chinese Communist periodicals. la/ (4) Extrabudgetary Investment This item consists of investment expenditures by central government ministries, local (provincial and county) governments, and enterprises from funds other than state budget investment funds. These extrabudgetary funds include (a) major repair funds, (b) enterprise bonus funds, (c) the share of above-plan profits not remitted to the state treasury, and (d) funds raised by private and state-private enterprises from their own operations. Expenditures for major repairs in 1952 and 1957 have been estimated It is believed that Chinese Com- 50X1 munist claims for extrabudgetary investment in 1958-59 include expendi- tures on major repairs. The estimates of extrabudgetary investment for 1952 and 1957-58 were derived by subtracting the official claims for in- vestment "under the plan" -- that is, investment through the state budget carried out through the annual national capital construction plan -- from the official claims for "total investment," both of which are given in the regime's statistical compendium, Ten Great Years. 5../ The figure for 1959 also is the official Chinese estimate. .1.Y (5) Changes in Inventories This item consists of changes in inventories in trade and industry and changes in government stocks of tax collections-in-kind. Changes in inventories of construction materials held by construction enterprises are included in budgeted investment. Changes in inventories of transportation enterprises and of the agricultural sector are believed to be small and in this report were assumed to be zero. Changes in in- ventories in trade were calculated as in Table 10.* Total inventories and changes in inventories in industry in 1952-57 have been estimated . The increase in inventories 50X1 in industry in 1957 is the official Chinese Communist claim. Since 1957 the Chinese have mentioned only that in 1959 "the stocks of materials and equipment of the industrial departments ... registered a fair in- crease." Additions Additions to bank credit funds and to working capital from the state budget in 1958 and 1959 were larger than in 1957, and industrial enterprises have been largely dependent on budget allocations and bank credits for increases in their working capital. It was assumed, there- fore, that increases in inventories in industry were less than the in- crease in 1957, or roughly 1 billion yuan each year in 1958-59. * Table 10 follows on p. 33. - 32 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Table 10 Communist China: Calculation of Changes in Inventories in Trade Selected Years, 1951-59 Billion Current Yuan Type of Enterprise 1951 1952 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 State, state-private, and cooperative 5.33 8.82 23.54 2/ 20.84 2/ 24.67 2/ 28.37 .../ 35.75 2/ State 4.78 2/ 7.15 2/ 15.24 2/ 12.79 2/ State-private and cooperative 0.55 _d/ 1.67 6.53 2/ 8.05 2/ Private 4.77 2/ 4.38 2/ 0.43 e 0.29 y 0 jj 0 1/ Total inventories 10.10 13.20 23.97 21.27 24.96 28.37 35.75 Changes in inventories 3.10 3.69 3.41 7.38 a. Calculated on the basis of official claims of absolute and percentage increases in inventories of state, state-private, and cooperative enterprises. J.12/ b. Calculated on the basis of official claims of annual percentage increases in inventories of state trading enterprises, 1950-56. 31/ c. Inventories of state, state-private and cooperative, and private enterprises in 1955 were assumed to have been in the same proportion to total inventories as trade turnover of these enterprises was to total trade turnover. d. Assumed to have been in the same proportion to inventories of state enterprises as trade turnover of state-private and cooperative enter- prises was to trade turnover of state enterprises. e. Calculated by multiplying the value of inventories held by private enterprises in 1955 -- 2.20 billion yuan -- by the index of the value of inventories in private trade 50X1 f. The figure of 23.54 billion yuan in inventories of state, state-private, and cooperative enterprises in 1955 is believed to include inven- tories of nearly all commercial enterprises, including larger private commercial enterprises but excluding the small quantity of inventories held by small private commercial units that were socialized in 1956. The small private commercial units handled 1.8 percent of total trade turnover in 1956 and were assumed to have held 1.8 percent of total commercial inventories in 1955. g. Assumed to have been the same as in 1955. h. Assumed to have declined at the same rate as retail sales by private trading enterprises. L41/ i. Assumed to have been zero. - 33 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11: CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Changes in government stocks of tax collections-in-kind occur because the state budget is calculated on a calendar year basis and col- lections of agricultural taxes are made on a fiscal year basis (1 April to 31 March). These changes are relatively small; official data on tax collections-in-kind and budget revenue from agricultural taxes indicate that increases in government stocks of tax collections-in-kind were about 100 million yuan in 1957. In the absence of similar information in 1952 and 1958-59, it was assumed that government stocks of tax collections-in- kind in those years did not change. '(6) Net Foreign Investment \ \N d, (4), p. 31, above.) (7) Undistributed (to Persons) Income of State Enterprises This item is the sum of (a) income remitted to the state treasury and (b) major repair funds and other funds retained by central government ministries, local governments, and enterprises. (8) Remitted to the State Treasury This item is the official budget figure for profits and de- preciation reserves of state enterprises less budget expenditures for dividenda to former owners of private enterprises in 1957-59 and for the "four expenses" in 1952 and 1957.* (9) Retained by Central Government Ministries, Local Governments, and Enterprises This entry is the sum of major repair funds and other funds. (10) Major Repair Funds Major repair funds have been estimated to be equivalent to 3 percent of the total value of industrial fixed assets during 1952-57. L42/ Major repair funds in 1958-59 were assumed to be equivalent to 3 percent of the average annual value of industrial fixed assets of state, state- private, and cooperative enterprises in those years. * The "four expenses," as they are called by the Chinese Communists, in- clude expenditures for (1) "organization of technical works," (2) trial manufacture of new products, (3) labor protection, and (4) purchase of miscellaneous assets. It is believed that these expenditures should be treated as expenditures on intermediate products. The income remitted to the treasury was therefore reduced by the amount of these expenditures in 1952 and 1957. In 1958-59 the "four expenses" were covered by retained profits. - 34 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L (11) Other Rinds This entry consists of (a) enterprise bonus fundsl, net of expenditures for employee welfare, (b) the share of above-plan profits not remitted to the state treasury, and (c) the funds for the "four expenses," net of expenditures for the "four expenses." In 1952 and 1957 the figure for other funds was essentially the share of above- plan profits; the enterprise bonus funds were largely expended for employee welfare, and the "four expenses" were covered by state budget expenditures. The estimates for 1952 and 1957 were made on the basis of the planned share of above-plan profits for 1958, La/ and the estimates for 1958-59 were calculated by subtracting from reported total retained profits1111/ the following: (a) rough estimates of expenditures from the enterprise bonus funds for employee welfare in 1958-59; (b) the reported expenditures on the "four expenses" In_1958212; and (c) a rough estimate of expenditures on the "four expenses" iii-1959, which was based on the planned figure for 1959 )2g and the actual increase in total retained profits in 1959. (12) Government Surplus on Income and Product Account (See c, (8), p. 30, above.) (13) Personal Saving (See b, (9), p. 26, above.) (14) Statistical Discrepancy (See a, (13), p. 23, above.) 3. Gross National Product, by Sector of Origin, 1952-60 (Table 6*) GNP for each year was calculated by summing (a) value added in the various sectors of the economy and (b) indirect taxes. The value added by each sector and the indirect taxes were all expressed in 1957 internal Chinese Communist prices. The estimates of value added by the various sectors of the economy in the years 1952-56 and 1958-60** have been cal- culated, for the most part, on the basis of indexes of production in each sector, 1952-60, and the value added by the sector in 1957. Estimates of value added by agriculture, industry, and other sectors of the economy in 1957 were derived from the detailed estimates that underlie the figures * Appendix A, p. 12, above. ** The estimates for 1960, which are preliminary in nature, have followed this same general methodology but were based on the limited amount of in- formation available on actual production in 1960. -35- C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L for compensation of employees, agricultural income, income of state and nonstate enterprises, rental income, and personal service income presented in Tables 1 through 5.* The methods used to estimate the value added in the several sectors of the economy in 1952-56 and 1958-60 are discussed below, using the esti- mate of GNP for 1959 as an example. The contributions of the sectors of the economy to GNP as calculated for 1959 are as follows: Economic Sector Billion 1957 Yuan Percentage Distribution Agriculture Industry Construction Transportation and communications Trade and miscellaneous business services 48.7 32.6 7.5 12.4 13.3 37.9 25.4 5.8 9.6 10.4 Personal services and housing services 8.0 6.2 Government services 6.0 4.7 Gross national product (at factor cost) 128.5 100.0 Indirect taxes 16.9 Gross national product (at market prices) 145.4 a. Agriculture In agriculture, value added for 1959 was calculated by subtract- ing the value of chemical fertilizer, seed and feed grain, and other products used up in production from the gross value of agricultural pro- duction, in 1957 prices. (The method used to calculate value added by agriculture is summarized in 2, a, (2), p. 18, above.) b. Industry In industry, value added for 1959 was calculated by summing the value added by iron and steel, coal, machine building,, food processing, textiles, and other components of industry.** * Pp. 7 through 11. above. -36- Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 50X1 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 ( C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Within industry, the value added by production of iron and steel in 1959 was calculated by multiplying value added by production of iron and steel in 1957 by the index of production, 1959 over 1957. This index of production was computed by taking quantity relatives* and weighting by the value added contributed by each product in 1957. The value added by the other components of industry was calculated by the same method used for iron and steel. c. Construction In construction, value added for 1959 was calculated by summing (1) compensation of employees, which was estimated on the basis of frag- mentary information on the increase in number of construction workers, 1959 over 1957; (2) profits, Which were estimated to be equal in amount to the same percentage of state capital investment as in 1957; and (3) the imputed value of construction activities of farmers which was estimated to be roughly equivalent to one-half of total budget expendi- tures on agricultural construction, including water conservation proj- ects. d. Transportation and Communications In modern transportation and communications, value added for 1959 was calculated by multiplying value added by this component in 1957 by the index of ton-kilometers hauled by modern transportation in 1959 (1957 equaling 100). Native trnnsportation and handling services are closely related to domestic trade, and the value added by these services was assumed to have increased at the same rate as sales in domestic trade (deflated for increases in prices). e. Trade and Miscellaneous Business Services Value added for 1959 was calculated by gumming (a) value added by foreign trade and (b) value added by domestic trade and miscellaneous business services. Value added by foreign trade for 1959 Was calculated by multiplying value added by foreign trade in 1957 by the index of total foreign trade in 1959 (total foreign trade in 1957 equaling 100). Value added by domestic trade and miscellaneous business services was calcu- lated by multiplying value added by this component in 1957 by the index of deflated retail sales in 1959 (retail sales in 1957 equaling 100). * For estimates of production of major industrial products during 1952-60, see Appendix Al Table 9, p. 15, above. -37- C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Miscellaneous business services such as insurance and rental of ware- houses are closely related to domestic trade, and the value added by these services was assumed to have increased at the same rate as de- flated retail sales. f. Personal Services and Housing Services Income from personal services and housing services represents (1) money income from rented housing; (2) an imputation of the income from owner-occupied houses; (3) an imputation for rental subsidies; and (4) an estimate of the wages and other income (mot paid by the state) received for labor in such activities as barbering, bathhouses, theaters, pedicabs, and funerals. (The method used to estimate income of the agri- cultural population from personal services and rent, in current prices, has been discussed in 2, b, (19), p. 281 above.) The estimate for 1959 in current prices was converted into 1957 prices on the basis of the index of farm sale prices. Rental income of the nonagricultural population in 1959 was calculated by subtracting from total rent, in 1957 prices (see 2, b, (7), p. 261 above), the cost of house repair materials. (The method used to estimate personal service income of the nonagricultural population in 1959, in current prices, has been discussed in 2, b, (20)1 p. 28, above.) The estimate for 1959 in current prices was converted into 1957 prices on the basis of the estimated increase in retail prices. g. Government Services In government services, value added for 1959 was calculated by multiplying the value added in 1957 -- compensation of employees in the military establishment, in administration, in health and education, and in public organizations (political parties and labor unions) -- by the index of the number of employees in each of these components in 1959 (the number of these employees in 1957 equaling 100). The number of government employees in 1959 was roughly estimated on the basis of frag- mentary information. h. Indirect Taxes' The estimates of indirect taxes for 1952-60, in 1957 prices, were calculated by summing estimates of indirect taxes on trade, heavy indus- try, and light industry. (The method used to estimate total indirect taxes in 1957 has been discussed in 2, al (12)1 p. 23, above.) Indirect taxes on trade in 1957 were calculated by summing retail trade taxes, customs taxes, and miscellaneous taxes. Indirect taxes on industry were derived by subtracting indirect taxes on trade from total indirect taxes. Indirect taxes on industry in 1957 were allocated between taxes on heavy industry and taxes on light industry on the basis of several Chinese Com- munist reports on profits and taxes collected from heavy and light indus- try.21.g/ The estimates of indirect taxes on trade, heavy industry, and - 38 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L light industry in 1952-56 and 1958-60 were calculated by multiplying in- direct taxes on each of these sectors in 1957 by the index of value added by each of these sectors during 1952-60. 4. Special Problems Relating to the Estimates of GNP a. Prices The estimates of GNP presented in this report have been compiled in terms of Chinese Communist internal prices, and the output as measured reflects the impact of Chinese price policies and other economic policies. The most important of these policies in terms of the estimates of GNP are as follows: (1) the hiel valuation of producer goods and the low valua- tion of consumer goods* compared with the US, (2) the relatively low state purchase prices of agricultural products and the relatively high profits accruing to the state from the resale of these agricultural prod- ucts, and (3) the heavy commodity taxes placed on industrial goods. Be- cause the Chinese economy is geared to increasing production of producer goods faster than production of consumer goods and services, valuation of Chinese GNP in US prices would show a rate of growth significantly lower than valuation in Chinese prices. In addition, valuation of Chinese GNP in US prices would yield different sector weights from valuation in Chinese prices. Agricultural income would be a higher proportion, and income originated by industry and trade a lower proportion, of GNP at factor cost. The effect on sector weights of the heavy commodity taxes placed on industrial goods has been isolated by inclusion of these taxes in the estimates of indirect taxes. Like the sector weights, the end- use shares of GNP would be different if Chinese GNP were valued in US prices. The share of investment would be lower, and that of consumption and government purchases higher, than the proportions of GNP indicated by valuation in Chinese prices. b. Handicraft and Household Activity It is quite likely that the existence of a large and declining element of handicraft and household activity in the Chinese Communist economy has led to some overstatement of the rate of growth of GNP, but it is believed that the overstatement is so small as not to bring into question the main themes of the analysis. The difficulties that arise are not unique to China. They include the problem of identifying and properly treating (1) economic activity that has been transferred from the household to the market place, and (2) petty, hitherto unrecorded * High internal prices of producer goods relative to prices of consumer goods are in part a reflection of the relative scarcities that existed within China at the time of the establishment of the Communist regime. Since 1952, prices of producer goods have declined relative to prices of consumer goods. - 39 - C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L handicraft activity that has been swept together into cooperative group- ings under state control and is now more thoroughly recorded in the state figures. Under WI if a woman who has been washing clothes in the house- hold now washes the village's clothes in a public laundry the GNP figure would rise, but so would the GNP figures of almost any country that is industrializing; the peculiar difficulty in the case of Communist China is that the industrialization, and consequently the distortion, is squeezed together into a few short years. Under (2), estimates of commodity pro- duction used in the calculation of value added by industry took into ac- count, to the extent permitted by the information available, the division between handicraft and modern and between state and cooperative production; most of the important increases in industrial production in Communist China have been in areas where the handicraft element was either small or nonexistent -- for instance, in steel,* electric power, petroleum, electrical equipment, machine tools,** and transportation equipment.*** In the case of agricultural production, the estimates for specific crops were based on sown acreage, weather, and level of technology and there- fore largely bypass the problem of handicraft activity; where the size of crops -- for instance, vegetables -- depends on the regime's attitude toward private plots, the estimating was more difficult, but all in all the danger of substantial overstatement appears small. c. Data In addition to the problems noted above, the estimates of value added by the several sectors of the economy, of the basic income com- ponents of GNP, and of the end-use components of GNP suffer in varying degrees from lack of data. Data problems (primarily in relation to agri- culture and industry) have been discussed in several studies.)12/ The estimates for the other sectors of the economy could be improved consid- erably with more information on the labor force in these sectors. During the period of the First Five Year Plan (1953-57), labor force data for the state-operated components of the economy were reasonably good, but there was very little information on the number and compensation of per- sons employed in handicrafts, private trade, native transportation, and personal services. Since 1957, data on the size, distribution, and com- pensation of the labor force, even in the state-operated components of the economy, have been fragmentary. * Production of the much-publicized native furnaces in 1958 is specifi- cally excluded from national statistics on production of crude steel. ** Estimates of production used for the index of value added by indus- try are based on international classification standards. *** Coal is an exception to this statement, but it is believed that the "native" element is fairly well identified and, in the calculation of the industrial index, adjustment was made for the decline in the quality of coal during 1958-60. -40- C-0-N-F-I-D-E-N-T-I-A-L Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 R Next 3 Page(s) In Document Denied Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 50X1 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2 CONFIDENTIAL CONFIDENTIAL Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/07/11 : CIA-RDP79R01141A002100130001-2