EAST EUROPEAN COUNTERTRADE: THE TREND TOWARD BILATERALISM IN TRADE WITH THE WEST

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
S
Document Page Count: 
25
Document Creation Date: 
December 22, 2016
Document Release Date: 
February 17, 2011
Sequence Number: 
5
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
April 1, 1985
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0.pdf1.6 MB
Body: 
Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Iq Next 1 Page(s) In Document Denied Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Directorate of Seer-et Intelligence in Trade With the West Ar East European Countertrade: The Trend Toward Bilateralism An Intelligence Assessment EUR 85-10065 April 1985 Copy 3 9 7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Directorate of Sew Intelligence East European Countertrade: The Trend Toward Bilateralism in Trade With the West An Intelligence Assessment This paper was prepared by Office of European Analysis. Comments and queries are welcome and may be directed to the Chief, East/West Regional Economics Branch, EURA,F- Secret EUR 85-10065 April 1985 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Secret Summary Information available as oft February 1985 was used in this report. in Trade With the West East European Countertrade: The Trend Toward Bilateralism impact of financial problems and soft export markets. Eastern Europe's' trade with the West 2 has been marked in the 1980s by an increase in countertrade-transactions in which the exporter accepts goods or services from the importer as payment. The USSR and Eastern Europe have long used countertrade to increase import capacity by circumventing the problems of poor export competitiveness and lack of hard currency and to facilitate planning by reducing uncertainty in trading relations with the West. In the early 1980s, the East Europeans stepped up their demands for countertrade in an effort to limit the countertrade now accounts for about 30 percent of trade with the West for the financially strapped East European countries (Poland, Romania, and Yugoslavia) and for 10 to 20 percent of trade for the other countries. the shares could run as high as 40 to 50 percent for the most active countertrading countries, but we believe these estimates are somewhat inflated. Nonetheless, countertrade is comparatively more important in Eastern Europe's trade with the West than it is in total world trade. Countertrade proved a useful expedient during the region's 1981-83 financial crisis. It was one of several options available to the East Europeans to deal with their financial problems and was attractive because it resulted in less economic burden than administrative controls on imports and domestic austerity measures. The hard currency outlays saved by countertrade transactions may have equaled as much as a third of the region's debt service costs and helped moderate reductions in Western imports. Countertrade also helped limit the decline in East European exports caused by soft markets in Western Europe. While helpful in a period of financial stress, we believe countertrade will do more harm than good to Eastern Europe's trade performance in the long run. Using Western suppliers as an outlet for otherwise unsaleable goods weakens incentives to some East European trade officials contend that long-term reliance on countertrade tends to perpetuate uncompetitive production, shelters Eastern enterprises from valuable marketing experience, and damages the image of Eastern goods. In our view, linking exports to the willingness of Western partners to accept countertrade is a less promising basis for achieving strong export gains than working to meet market upgrade the quality and efficiency of production. requirements for price and quality. Yugoslavia. iii Secret EUR 85-10065 April 1985 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 While many East European officials recognize that countertrade is a poor solution to the region's export problems, in our judgment, the East Europeans will continue to rely heavily on countertrade to sell to the West: ? Chronic problems with hard currency exports will probably worsen as a result of the growing technological edge the West has over Eastern Europe, stiffer com- petition from the more industrialized LDCs, and tougher Soviet demands for better quality goods from Eastern Europe. ? Planning and foreign trade bureaucracies in Eastern Europe still favor counter- trade because of its compatibility with intra-Bloc trading mechanisms. Only Hungary seems committed to fundamental reforms that may weaken the institu- tional bias for countertrade. ? Businessmen anxious for sales seem ready to accept countertrade as one of the costs of competing in Eastern Europe. Many Western banks and firms have a vested interest in promoting countertrade because of investments made in trading companies that specialize in countertrade with both LDCs and the Soviet Bloc. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Secret Contents Development of East-West Countertrade 1 Responding to Financial Crisis Impact on Trade With the West 7 Implications for Eastern Europe 10 Countertrade Policies of the East European Countries 15 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 25X1 The term "countertrade " refers to any transaction in which the exporter commits himself to take products from the importer or importer's country in full or partial payment for his deliveries. This can happen in a variety of ways, but the terminology used to describe the various forms of countertrade is incon- sistent and often confused. In general, four main types of countertrade occur in East-West commerce: barter, counterpurchase, buy-backs, and offsets. F_ Barter In straightforward barter, goods are exchanged di- rectly between the Eastern and Western partners without exchange of cash, pricing of goods, or financ- ing. Barters are difficult to conclude because of problems in finding a party that will receive one type of goods and simultaneously deliver another and in determining their relative value. In some cases, the contract may limit the Western partner's purchase commitment to only a portion of his sale with the balance paid in cash. It is generally difficult, howev- er, for the East Europeans to obtain financing for the cash payment because Western banks and credit insurers oppose making the repayment of credit con- tingent upon the Western supplier's purchase of East- ern goods. Because of a variety of complications, barter has become much less common in East-West trade than it was in the immediate postwar period. F Counterpurchase Counterpurchase has become the predominant coun- tertrade variant in East European trade with the West because it circumvents some of the limitations of barter. Counterpurchase involves two separate but linked contracts, each involving cash payment for goods. One contract involves the sale of goods to the Eastern side; the other involves the Western expor- ter's commitment to buy (or have a third party buy) products from the importer up to and even exceeding the amount of the original sale within a stipulated period (usually one to three years). A major advan- tage to the Western seller is that he is paid at once in convertible currency and lenders are more willing to provide credit because payment of the export contract is not contingent upon counterdeliveries. Buy-Back In buy-back deals-sometimes referred to as com- pensation-the Western firm supplies technology, equipment, and even entire plants in return for goods produced using the plant or equipment (resultant products). In contrast to counterpurchase, which in- volves repayment in nonresultant products, buy-back deals generally involve very large sales, extend over a long period of time, and require substantial bridge financing to cover the time lag between delivery of equipment and resultant production. Buy-back is less common than counterpurchase because Western firms generally are looking for raw materials, which are in short supply in Eastern Europe. Offset Offset is a system by which the Western exporter incorporates goods from the Eastern partner in the product he sells. Like buy-back, offset transactions are more long term and are more closely linked to industrial cooperation than to the commercial prac- tices of counterpurchase and barter. 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 OUVIrrt East European Countertrade: The Trend Toward Bilateralism in Trade With the West Countertrade has been a fixture of East European trade with the West since World War II. Over this period it has evolved from simple barter to complicat- ed deals involving several parties. East-West counter- trade began to attract attention during the 1970s when East European countries tried to stem rising hard currency trade deficits by pressing Western suppliers to take Eastern goods in return. Severe financial problems in the early 1980s caused most East European regimes to increase demands on West- ern suppliers to accept countertrade. These arrange- ments provided some shortrun gains during a period of financial stress, but over the longer term we believe that reliance on countertrade will hinder improvement in the region's export competitiveness. This paper will contrast the shortrun gains with the longer term problems associated with increased bilat- eralism in trade with the West. It will review briefly the evolution of countertrade prior to the region's financial crisis in the 1980s and will examine in more detail its role in helping Eastern Europe adjust to reductions in Western credit. This paper will consider the outlook for East-West countertrade, for alterna- tives to such trading arrangements, and for the impli- cations of these trade policies for Eastern Europe. Countertrade, primarily barter arrangements, played an important role in European trade in the immediate postwar years when the rebuilding economies of East- ern and Western Europe lacked the convertible cur- rency needed to conduct normal commerce. The use of countertrade diminished within Western Europe as the region's economies strengthened, particularly af- ter 1958 when West European currencies became fully convertible. The USSR and Eastern Europe, however, continued to rely on simple forms of counter- trade in dealing with the West because they lacked hard currency and trade credits and because counter- trade was compatible with intra-Bloc trading mecha- A surge in East-West trade in the 1970s increased the complexity of countertrade, especially through the conclusion of long-term buy-back deals. As the Soviet Bloc became more dependent on Western imports, the regimes used countertrade as a way to adjust their foreign trade planning to uncertain Western markets. By establishing specific Western purchase commit- ments extending over a long period of time, central planners aimed to moderate fluctuations in exports, facilitate the formulation of long-range trade plans, ensure adequate earnings to repay Western credits, and provide for increased import capacity. the USSR (see figure 2). Most of the large buy-back deals concluded in the 1970s involved Soviet purchases of Western machin- ery and equipment on credit for the development of the USSR's energy and raw material sectors (see figure 1). Western suppliers found such arrangements attractive because they promised large machinery sales at a time of soft markets in the West and repayment through long-term deliveries of energy and raw materials at favorable prices that the firms could use in production or readily sell. Eastern Europe concluded fewer long-term deals because-except for Poland-the region could not offer significant amounts of energy or raw materials for countertrade. East European buy-back deals generally involved deliveries of chemicals and machinery (see table 1), but these arrangements covered a smaller amount of the region's capital goods imports than in the case of only about 10 percent of Eastern Europe's trade with the West was conducted through bilateral channels in the early 1970s. Easy access to Western financing limited the need to match imports with offsetting exports, but it also laid the basis for growing financial problems, which eventual- ly led to an upswing in East European demands for countertrade. The East Europeans anticipated that imported Western technology would generate the additional exports needed for debt repayment. Sys- temic inefficiencies, poor marketing skills, quality nisms. 25X1 25X1 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Secret Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 control problems, and, in the West, recession and protectionism curtailed strong gains in sales. As hard currency trade deficits and debt mounted by the mid- 1970s, most regimes intensified demands on Western suppliers to take goods, especially machinery and consumer goods, as payment. While attracted to deals offering energy and raw materials at discount prices, Western firms generally had limited interest in countertrade involving East European manufactured goods. These products often were low in quality or difficult to sell in the West because of import restrictions; otherwise, the East Europeans probably would have marketed them under more conventional arrangements. Western firms- willing to accept countertrade as the price of making a sale-faced the problem of disposing of Eastern counterdeliveries. West German, French, Austrian, and Italian companies were the most willing to negoti- ate countertrade deals with Eastern Europe. A sizable subindustry of firms developed-notably in Austria- to act as middlemen in buying and selling counter- trade goods. Although facilitating deals, these so- called switch traders made countertrade more costly and complex than conventional trade. These difficul- ties posed major obstacles to small firms; consequent- ly, large multinational corporations that could more easily absorb or dispose of Eastern goods through their extensive supply networks and diverse operations became the dominant participants in countertrade with Eastern Europe. Even with renewed East European interest in counter- trade, these trading arrangements apparently still accounted for a comparatively small share of East- West trade by the late 1970s. Although East Europe- an buyers often demanded that counterpurchases cover as much as 50 percent of an import contract, the OECD concluded that countertrade in the late 1970s accounted for no more than 15 to 20 percent of total hard currency trade in countries where it was most widely practiced (Romania, Poland, and Bulgaria) and for less than 10 percent in other countries. The collapse of Eastern Europe's creditworthiness in the early 1980s resulted in a sharp cutback in credit to the region. With the exception of Czechoslovakia and Bulgaria, the regimes all but exhausted hard currency Figure 1 Eastern Europe-USSR: Buy-Back Deals With the West, 1969-80 Billion US $ Bulgaria Czecho- East Hungary Poland Romania USSR slovakia Germany reserves in trying to meet debt service payments that could no longer be financed through more borrowings. Lack of cash and credits left the East Europeans with little choice but to reverse the decadelong trend of large hard currency trade deficits through cuts in imports and concerted efforts to boost exports. East European economic managers, in our view, had four options to improve their balance of trade: ? Administrative controls on imports. ? Adjustment policies to reduce domestic demand for imports and to free up more production for exports. ? Systemic reforms to provide incentives for exports and to improve the efficiency and quality of production. ? Commercial policies to boost exports through ag- gressive price cutting, countertrade, and industrial cooperation. 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588ROO0100130005-0 Table I Large East European Buy-Back Deals With the West in the 1970s W estern Country F Western Supplier East European Country rance W Technip Bulgaria est Germany J Friedrich Uhde East Germany apan F Toyo Engineering, Mitsui East Germany rance U i Citroen East Germany n ted States F Steiger Hungary rance Citroen Romania United Kingdom Petrocarbon Development Ltd. Poland Belgium Unknown Poland Year East European Imports Signed 1975 Ethylene plant 1976 Import Value East European Exports Planned East European Outcome and Comments (millio US $ n ) Export Value (million US $) 50 Machinery and engi- NA neering goods, petro- chemicals Polyvinyl chloride complex 451 Polyvinyl chloride and NA and related equipment soda lye 1977 Two petrochemical plants 450 Petrochemicals NA 1978 Turnkey plant 1976 1977 330 Transaxle units and NA parts (300,000 per year) Technology and parts for 80 Tractor axles 20 tractor manufacturing Design, engineering, and 170 "Olcit" cars parts for automobiles Exports to equal 30 percent of output over eight to 10 years; project apparently working as planned. Most of the chemicals Japan received probably were sold to third countries via trading houses. In 1982 France imported $12 million worth of parts, in- creased to $20 million in 1983. Has worked out well. Steiger has purchased more axles than called for in the agreement. Half of annual The French have not accepted production any of the cars because of fail- 1975 Polyvinyl chloride 400 Polyvinyl chloride NA and chlorite plants 1975 Coal-mining equipment 335 1.5 million tons of coal 335 per year for 10 to 15 years Austria Voest Alpine Poland 1975 Steel products West Germany West German Poland Consortium Equipment for expanding Poland's copper industry 125 40,000 tons of copper 800 to 1,000 over The Poles used most of the credits for these projects to cover financial obligations. Poland, nonetheless, has export- ed coal, copper, and chemicals to the Western firms despite strike disruptions in 1980 and 1981. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588ROO0100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Figure 2 Planned East European and Soviet Exports to the West Under the Buy-Back Arrangements Signed, 1969-80 Note scale changes Other M Consumer goods Chemicals From the perspective of planning and foreign trade bureaucracies, adoption of more aggressive commer- cial policies seemed an attractive strategy to counter the swift contraction of trade credits because they promised the quickest payoff with the least cost. Import cuts and restraints on demand-primarily on investment-were unavoidable, but the regimes want- ed to minimize such measures out of political concern over the popular reaction to austerity. The payoff from systemic reform would have been too slow and uncertain to be much help in a period of financial crisis. Moreover, vested interests in party, govern- ment, and enterprise management probably would have watered down reform programs. Of the various commercial policies considered, countertrade was more promising than price cutting or industrial cooperation. The scope for aggressive price cutting was limited by the threat of antidumping actions by Western countries. Western firms general- ly have not been enthusiastic about entering into industrial cooperation arrangements with Eastern Eu- rope, and the returns take several years to be realized. Faced with an immediate financial crunch, the East Europeans had little choice but to press suppliers even harder to accept payment in goods. Western firms looking to sell to Eastern Europe recognized that they had to meet these conditions given the region's severe financial problems. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Secret Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 At the onset of the East European financial crisis, only Romania mandated the use of countertrade for hard currency imports. Most of the other countries increased reliance on countertrade without making it an explicit requirement. Although the regimes varied considerabl in the t e of arrangements they pre- ferred, 7 reported several trends: ? Most countries increased the share of their import costs that they tried to cover through counter- deliveries (see table 2). ? The lack of hard currency compelled many regimes to demand countertrade for priority imports that they had previously purchased for cash. In late 1984, a Polish firm had a tentative agreement with a US company to purchase $6 million worth of badly needed X-ray equipment and film. In return, the US firm agreed to purchase $10 million worth of coal and chemicals. ? The goods offered as counterdeliveries became even less attractive. There was a movement away from agricultural commodities, energy, and semifinished goods-which are somewhat easier for Western firms to resell or to use in their own production- toward machinery, which entails problems in quali- ty, service, and spare parts (see figure 3). Because of the pressing need for cash, foreign trade organiza- tions tried to sell more marketable goods for hard currency while attempting to offer less desirable goods in countertrade deals. The countries that suffered the most severe financial problems gave the most attention to countertrade: ? In 1980, Romania's President Ceausescu an- nounced that all foreign trade organizations must link planned imports of machinery and equipment and all nonplanned imports to counterpurchases of Romanian machinery and equipment. Bucharest subsequently pressed holders of overdue supplier credits to accept goods in lieu of cash. ? Although Poland demanded relatively small countertrade ratios for imports going to key export sectors, in most other sectors the ratios rose to between 60 and 90 percent, Polish enterprises, however, often failed to enforce their demands because shortages of goods limited barter with Western companies. Table 2 Countertrade Ratios Demanded by East European Buyers, a 1976, 1980, and 1983 Romania 30 to 40 50 to 70 60 to 80 Poland 25 to 30 20 to 50 60 to 90 Yugoslavia 30 40 to 60 60 to 80 East Germany 20 to 40 20 to 50 50 to 75 0 15 to 50 30 to 50 Bulgaria 40 to 50 40 to 60 40 to 60 Czechoslovakia 30 to 40 15 to 50 35 to 50 a The ratios in this table reflect typical maximum countertrade demands made by East European buyers. Western suppliers can usually lower these requirements in contract negotiations, particu- larly for higher priority imports. Source: Surveys of Western businessmen reported by Business Eastern Europe. ? In 1982, Yugoslavia adopted legislation requiring $103 worth of counterpurchases for every $100 worth of imports of raw materials, semifinished goods, and consumer goods in short supply. Yugo- slav firms were allowed to offer higher quality goods to meet these needs while less desirable goods were to be used in countertrade to purchase capital equipment. In this way, the authorities promoted imports of goods needed for production and con- sumption at the expense of investment goods. The sudden unavailability of credits and weak West- ern markets in the early 1980s led both East Germany and Hungary to begin insisting on counterpurchase deals. Prior to the credit crisis, Hungary generally opposed the use of countertrade while East Germany focused mainly on long-term buy-back deals linked to the construction of complete plants. In addition to counterpurchase deals, the East Germans have earned substantial hard currency in recent years by acting, in effect, as middlemen in multiparty barter-switch deals. Items the East Germans have resold for cash include oil, metals, and raw materials obtained through barter with developing countries, as well as goods obtained on clearing account from West Ger- many. 25X1 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Secret Figure 3 USSR-Eastern Europe: Change in Catagories of Goods Offered in Countertrade, 1976 and 1982 Percent Fuel Engineered and capital Chemical Food trade with the West since the late 1970s, but reliable data on its magnitude are impossible to find. Pub- lished statistics do not distinguish countertrade from conventional trade. ome recent estimates asserted that 40 to 50 percent-an possibly even more-of East European imports from nonsocialist countries are tied to countertrade. this may be reasonably accurate for trade in captial goods (particularly for countries facing the most severe hard currency shortages), but it probably is too high for total trade. probably accounts for 20 to 30 percent of the region's trade with nonsocialist countries, that is, $15-20 billion annually of which $10-15 billion is with the developed West. There are, however, important dif- ferences among countries: 25X1 25X1 25X1 25X1 25X1 ? Romanian officials have stated in the press that countertrade accounts for 30 percent of the country's $5 billion in trade with the West, well 25X1 short of Bucharest's goal. ? According to embassy reporting, Polish trade offi- cials recently told Western executives that counter- trade accounts for 8 to 10 percent of Poland's total trade, equivalent to about 25 to 30 percent of its $6.4 billion trade with the West. Because of their reasonably strong financial positions, neither Czechoslovakia nor Bulgaria had to adopt substantially tougher policies on countertrade in re- sponse to the credit crisis. The Bulgarians have long sought buy-back and offset deals to modernize their industry and expand hard currency export capacity but with meager results. Bulgaria has had more success in negotiating arrangements in which it pro- vides construction and engineering services in return for Western machinery and equipment used in joint ventures in developing countries. Czechoslovak buyers often raise the possibility of countertrade in negotia- tions with Western firms, but generally do not insist on such arrangements except in the case of large purchases and low priority imports. ? Yugoslavia announced in the press that the counter- trade variant established by 1982 legislation ac- counted for about 15 percent of its $14.3 billion hard currency trade in 1983; we estimate conven- tional countertrade probably accounted for an addi- tional 5 to 10 percent. ? The other East European countries have not report- ed comparable statistics, but, Measuring the impact of tougher East European demands for countertrade is difficult.F_ counter- trade has increased its share of Eastern Europe's we estimate that the countertrade shares for East Germany and Bulgaria are on the order of 15 to 20 percent and no more than 10 percent for Hungary and Czechoslovakia. 25X1 25X1 25X1 25X1 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 Based on OECD and GATT studies, we estimate countertrade accounted for nearly 6 percent of inter- national trade in 1983.' Even for LDCs, where coun- tertrade has attracted much attention in the past few years, only about 10 percent of total imports-and 4 percent of imports from industrial countries-were linked to countertrade deals. Total world countertrade deals are estimated by the OECD to have totaled approximately $95 billion in 1983. An important measure of countertrade's importance to Eastern Europe is the extent to which it helped ease financial constraints during the 1981-83 credit crunch. If we assume that 20 percent of imports were paid for by countertrade arrangements, this would have saved on hard currency outlays that could be used instead to cover almost 30 percent of the region's debt service during this period. The absence of coun- tertrade would have resulted in an average annual reduction in imports of 18 percent instead of the 11- percent average annual cut actually made over the three years. These measures overstate countertrade's significance because some counterexports presumably could have been sold without linkage to imports. Nonetheless, countertrade played a useful role in helping these countries deal with their external finan- cial crisis. Countertrade probably also helped limit the decline in East European hard currency exports in 1981-83 caused by soft markets in Western Europe. Perhaps paradoxically, depressed conditions in the West may have strengthened the hand of the East Europeans because Western firms anxious for sales were more amenable to countertrade requirements. According to Western business press many firms took countertrade goods they might have reject- ed under more normal circumstances, including items that could only be sold for scrap. While Western suppliers would try to negotiate the most favorable prices possible for their deliveries and counterpur- chases, many firms were prepared to accept some reduction in normal earnings to enter or maintain their position in East European markets. Western chemical firms were accepting a growing volume of Romanian chemicals as payment on over- due supplier loans and to preserve established com- mercial ties. This may explain the growth in Roma- nia's chemical sales to the OECD in recent years when many of its other exports have declined. Countertrade may have contributed to the surprising- ly strong growth in East Germany's exports. 0 the general- ly better quality of East German manufactured and consumer goods has made counterpurchase deals more feasible than with other East European coun- tries. Resales of oil and other commodities obtained through barter deals, however, have probably played a more important role in boosting East German exports to the West. Although countertrade apparently has contributed to export growth for Yugoslavia, we believe it has worked against Belgrade's efforts to restore financial health because Yugoslav enterprises have used coun- tertrade to circumvent regulations designed to build up the country's foreign exchange reserves. In conven- tional trade, a Yugoslav firm had to surrender 60 percent of the proceeds from hard currency exports to the Yugoslav National Bank, compared with only 20 to 40 percent in countertrade. Because of this incen- tive, Yugoslav firms often exported goods in counter- trade deals that otherwise could have been sold directly for cash. This evasion of foreign exchange regulations contributed to Belgrade's failure to re- build its depleted hard currency reserves in 1983 and complicated negotiations on Yugoslavia's 1984 refi- nancing agreement with Western banks. Most East European countries claim that they do not want to increase their use of countertrade, saw would prefer not to barter exports for imports. The Poles claimed that continuing shortages of ex- portable goods limit their ability to use countertrade. Instead the Poles want to obtain imports on credit and 25X1 25X1 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 Countertrade Deals: The Good, The Bad, and The Romanians Negotiating a countertrade deal with an East Euro- pean buyer is filled with pitfalls for a Western firm. Western businessmen are at a disadvantage because they cannot be sure of the quantity, price, and quality of goods they must purchase. The East European side knows the exact goods it wants to purchase, the price, and the countertrade ratio it will require. Eastern negotiators will often wait until just before signing contracts to bring up countertrade demands in order to prevent the Western partner from raising his price to cover the cost of disposing of countertrade goods. The East European side will generally try to impose tight restraints on the list of goods available for counterpurchase, the time limit for Western pur- chase, and potential resale markets. The East Euro- pean objective is to require the purchase of less marketable goods with little delay and to prevent the Western firm from reselling in established markets. The Eastern side will generally try to guarantee Western counterpurchases by demanding a sizable penalty clause covering nonfulfillment of contract. F_ Faced with these difficulties, many companies try to negotiate price discounts and other concessions in lieu of countertrade obligations. Nonetheless, some companies, particularly chemical firms and commod- ity traders, are able to profit from both the import and export contracts of countertrade transactions because they can more readily use or resell basic products from Eastern Europe. West European com- panies generally are in a better position to accept countertrade than US firms because some electrical components, clothing, textiles, shoes, and household items offered by the East Europeans meet West European standards. In addition, West European firms can more readily accept chemicals, steel, and cement, which have comparatively high transporta- tion costs, because of the shorter distances involved. Japanese trading companies also are better able to negotiate successful countertrade deals than US firms. The Japanese can rely on extensive marketing networks in East Asia to dispose of East European goods, often by bartering the East European products for goods from third countries. Even when a firm carefully negotiates a deal, it can still end up losing money. Many Western suppliers have been ready to make counterpurchases in good faith only to find that the East European side cannot or will not supply goods originally listed as available for counterexport. This leaves the Western firm with the choice of either taking worthless goods in pay- ment or paying a penalty-which can run up to 100 percent of the contract-for nonfulfillment of contract. Western businessmen have the most trouble negotiating satisfactory coun- tertrade terms with the Romanians. Romanian for- 25X1 eign trade organizations are notorious for reneging on the promised quality of counterexports. According to press reports, Japanese firms trapped into purchasing Romanian goods have found one solution to the cost of countertrade with Bucharest. They simply request delivery of the heaviest Romanian machinery avail- able so that they can sell it immediately as scrap. export for cash to generate the funds needed to meet debt service requirements. Belgrade is discouraging the use of countertrade by reducing the amount of hard curren- cy export earnings from conventional trade that a Yugoslav firm must surrender to the National Bank. some easing in demands for countertrade from East German, Czechoslovak, and Hungarian buyers as their ability to borrow from Western banks has improved. Only Romania seems committed to pressing for more countertrade. In his recent speech to the Romanian party congress, President Ceausescu endorsed coun- tertrade as a means to expand economic relations with the West. But even Romanian foreign trade officials have acknowledged that the push for more counter- trade would be balanced by an effort to receive Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 Secret Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 payment in cash for Romanian exports. Deputy For- eign Trade Minister Stanciu told the Western press that, while Bucharest wants to increase countertrade deals, most exports will not be tied to imports because the Romanians also want to pay back their hard currency debt in the next few years. Despite apparent reluctance to increase countertrade, we believe that it will continue to play an important role because Eastern Europe is likely to face increas- ing difficulties in exporting to the West. Reductions in investment and imports of Western capital goods in recent years have widened the technological gap between Eastern Europe and the West. The East Europeans also are facing stiffer competition from the more industrialized LDCs in Western markets. Grow- ing Soviet demands for better quality East European goods in return for deliveries of energy and raw materials may reduce the amount of East European goods available for sale in the West. We expect that the combination of these factors will compel the East Europeans to continue pressing Western suppliers to take less attractive goods as payment. The East Europeans are unlikely to give up counter- trade because it is a long-established way of doing business. With the possible exception of Hungary, East European foreign trade organizations continue to favor countertrade because they perceive that it promises stability and facilitates planning. Moreover, West European businessmen, in particular, seem to accept countertrade as a necessary evil. Since West- ern firms expect that the East Europeans will remain strapped for cash, we believe businessmen anxious for sales will accept countertrade as one of the costs of competing in Eastern Europe and will even initiate countertrade offers in the hope of clinching deals. Many Western banks and companies also have a vested interest in promoting countertrade because they have made significant investments in divisions or companies that specialize in countertrade with both LDCs and the Soviet Bloc. Even though Western governments generally disapprove of state-mandated countertrade because it reduces the efficiency of world trade, governments are reluctant to interfere with the activities of domestic exporters. Countertrade with developing countries, particularly switch trading involving Western firms, LDCs, and Communist countries, seems likely to grow. Switch Western Governments: Searching for a Consensus on Countertrade Caught between theoretical objections and the reality of business, OECD governments have struggled for nearly a decade to establish a position on East-West countertrade. Since 1977 the OECD and the EC have debated the issue and ordered studies, but progress toward a Western consensus has been extremely slow. Most governments want to establish ground rules with the Soviet Bloc that would make it easier for Western firms to deal with Eastern demands. Some governments, however, are concerned that a code of conduct would imply official endorsement of state- mandated countertrade as a normal practice. The USSR and Eastern Europe have persistently pressed for such official endorsement but have balked at Western efforts to discuss the commercial problems posed by their practices in CSCE sessions and the United Nation's Economic Commission for Europe. The Soviet Bloc has argued that some countertrade deals-notably buy-back arrangements-contribute to the growth of East-West trade while counterpur- chase and barter deals are a response to "discrimina- tory" Western restrictions on their exports. transactions were fairly common in the 1950s, but declined in number and importance as LDCs and CEMA countries began conducting more of their trade in hard currencies. This practice, however, is enjoying a revival as a result of the financial problems encountered by both developing countries and Eastern Europe. According to press a growing number of multinational firms and Western banks trying to make new sales or collect on old debts are proposing various types of switch trade arrange- ments to the East Europeans and LDCs. Countertrade has been a useful expedient during a period of financial problems and soft export markets in the West, but we believe it may do more harm than good to Eastern Europe's trade performance in the 25X1 25X1, Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Secret long run. In our view, this is particularly true of counterpurchase and barter deals. Longer term rela- tionships with Western firms through buy-back and offset deals and other forms of industrial cooperation offer better prospects for obtaining modern technol- ogy and marketing skills needed to be competitive in the West. Western businessmen and even some East European economic officials argue that reliance on countertrade tends to perpetuate uncompetitive production, shelters Eastern enterprises from valuable marketing experi- ence, and damages the image of East European goods. When Western firms looking for sales accept goods that the East Europeans may not be able to export otherwise, the East Europeans have little incentive for innovation or improvement in the quality of their production and marketing. In our view, linking ex- ports to the willingness of Western partners to accept countertrade is a less promising basis for achieving strong gains in sales than working to meet market requirements for price and quality. When the East Europeans sell marketable goods through countertrade, they may often receive less for their exports than they would in normal trade. Since Western businessmen find countertrade transactions more costly and complex to arrange than conventional deals, they often raise the price of their goods or demand discounts on the price of East European counterdeliveries. Western firms may often agree to coun- tertrade because they can make a profit on disposing of the counterdeliveries-a gain the East Europeans could capture with better knowledge of the market. A Western firm, for example, recently bartered agro- chemicals with a Czechoslovak foreign trade organi- zation because it could sell them to a French company for a higher price than the Czechoslovaks demanded. the most beneficial direction of development for coun- tertrade would be an increase in industrial coopera- tion. Longer term arrangements that go beyond a one- time sale or purchase of goods offer better possibilities for improving East European export performance because sustained contact with Western firms can provide a continuing flow of technology, technical and marketing skills, incentives to maintain quality stan- dards, and stable markets. Cheap Eastern labor and improved access to CEMA markets are the principal attractions to the Western partner. Industrial cooper- ation arrangements can include buy-back and offset deals, subcontracting where the Eastern partner is a regular supplier of components, joint research and development, coproduction where each partner makes some components that contribute to the other's final product, and joint marketing in either partner's mar- ket or in a third country. Certain East European countries are even interested in establishing joint ventures with equity of both partners either in Eastern Europe or in the West. Over the past few years, the East Europeans have taken steps to make cooperation and joint ventures more attractive to Western businesses: ? Hungary, whose 1972 legislation authorizing for- eign equity participation in joint ventures had at- tracted disappointingly few takers, in 1982 autho- 25X1 rized the creation of duty-free zones. Mixed companies in duty-free zones would be exempt from import duties and certain wage and benefit regula- tions if they export the end product. ? Bulgaria introduced a joint venture law in 1980 and has been pursuing cooperative relationships in elec- tronics and the automotive sector with Western (particularly Japanese) firms. ? Yugoslavia has been revising its joint venture legis- lation in a bid to attract more foreign capital without increasing its debt and to obtain the help of Western firms in developing stronger export indus- tries and promoting import substitution. ? Although long reluctant to enter into industrial cooperation arrangements with Western firms, the East Germans agreed in 1984 to supply diesel engines to Volkswagen beginning in 1988 in return for a production line, truck chassis, and trucks. 25X1 25X1 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 The OECD estimates that countertrade accounts for as much as 30 percent of trade between the Soviet Bloc and the LDCs. The OECD apparently includes in its estimate goods exchanged through bilateral clearing accounts in addition to transactions involv- ing linked export and import contracts-the typical countertrade deal with firms from developed coun- tries. Bilateral clearing trade probably accounts for most East European-LDC countertrade; nonetheless, barter transactions and switch deals involving several countries and firms are common between the regions and have grown in importance as a result of the financial problems faced by both Eastern Europe and the Third World. Romania is the most aggressive East European coun- try in trying to arrange countertrade deals with LDCs. Most of these efforts are directed at bartering oilfield equipment, machinery, and chemicals for petroleum from oil producing countries. The other East European countries also seek out opportunities to swap finished goods for oil, food products, and raw materials from developing countries. While the East Europeans generally will use the LDC imports as industrial inputs or additions to consumer supplies, in recent years several countries-notably East Ger- many-have resold bartered LDC goods for hard currency to help ease liquidity problems. Many pro- posed deals are never completed, however, because the LDC cannot identify any East European items that it wishes to import, or the East European partner fails to deliver acceptable goods on time. F_ An important aspect of East European-LDC counter- trade is the use of switch trades to acquire Western goods or repay hard currency debts with bilateral clearing account balances. Clearing account balances between Eastern Europe and the LDCs are not directly convertible into cash but represent purchasing power for goods mant4fac- tured in the countries subscribing to the clearing agreement. The agreement may provide that the country with a surplus in bilateral trade can turn over its balance to a third party. The third party, in turn, can use the surplus to acquire goods from the deficit country and-through a series of transac- tions-convert these goods into hard currency. A West German firm, for example, delivers $470,000 worth of machinery to Romania (see figure 4). Roma- nia, which has a bilateral clearing surplus with Morocco, pays the West German firm in Moroccan clearing dollars. The Romanians discount the clear- ing currency by 6 percent, giving the West Germans a 500,000 clearing-dollar credit. The West German firm, unable to use the clearing currency, contacts a switch trader who in turn locates a Dutch firm interested in buying from Morocco. The switch trader purchases the clearing dollars from the West German firm for $470,000 and sells the balance to the Dutch firm for $475,000. The Dutch firm uses the clearing balance to import from Morocco. As a result of this transaction, the Romanians obtain Western goods without using hard currency while eliminating a clearing account surplus with Morocco. Because of problems in collecting on credits from both LDCs and East European countries, Western companies and even some banks have been trying to use switch trades to liquidate their claims. A firm holding a claim on an East European country, for example, will try to arrange a purchase from an LDC that has a clearing deficit with the same East Euro- pean country. The firm will then either use or resell the LDC import and liquidate its claim on the East European country, while the LDC's clearing deficit is reduced. Arranging such deals obviously is compli- cated, and the rate of success appears low relative to the effort invested. 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 .~ccicL Figure 4 Flow of Good and Money in an LDC-East European Switch Deal $470,000 MA CHINER Y WEST GERMAN FIRM $500,000 CLEARING CURRENCY srs00 '0019 $500,000 CLEARING CURR,"Cy DUTCH FIRM Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Although the East Europeans extol the virtues of industrial cooperation, achievements to date have been limited. concluded that less than 10 percent of East-West trade has resulted from such agreements. Even Hungary, which together with Poland has been in the forefront of cooperation deals, has estimated that these arrangements account for only 6 to 7 percent of its exports to the West. The new East European initiatives are unlikely to change the attitude of Western businesses significant- ly and permit the development of useful alternatives to current countertrade practices. Western firms con- tinue to regard investment in East European joint ventures as risky. Despite its newly liberalized joint venture regulations and generally good reputation with Western business, Hungary so far has attracted only one duty-free-zone joint venture. While Western businessmen are somewhat more interested in cooper- ative arrangements, they still view Eastern proposals with caution, according to press articles. Western companies are skeptical that they can rely on Eastern partners to meet contract deadlines and quality stan- dards. East European regimes can easily impose administrative measures that can add costs and un- dermine a Western firm's rights in a cooperation agreement. Moreover, in many cases, the partners' interests eventually clash, particularly when the East Europeans want to push exports to hard currency markets while the Western side wants to use a cooperative deal to enter the CEMA market. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Appendix Countertrade Policies of the East European Countries The countries that suffered the most severe financial problems and consequent decline in hard currency trade-Romania, Poland, and Yugoslavia-have giv- en the most emphasis to countertrade. East Germany and Hungary, which rarely demanded counterpur- chases during the 1970s, became more aggressive in dealing with Western suppliers when their financial positions weakened in 1981-82. Although Bulgaria has not encountered severe financial problems over the past three years, Sofia regularly exerts pressure on Western suppliers to accept countertrade. Czechoslo- vakia did not alter its commercial policies significant- ly, reflecting its good financial health and relatively low priority on hard currency imports. Romania has tried to enforce the toughest counter- trade demands. In December 1980 the government issued a decree requiring all foreign trade organiza- tions to link planned imports of machinery and equip- ment and all nonplanned imports to counterpurchases of Romanian machinery and equipment or, in excep- tional cases, to purchases from other sectors. When Romania went into arrears on its foreign debt, Bucha- rest told holders of overdue supplier credits that they had to accept goods in lieu of cash if they wanted repayment in the near future. The Romanian Government claims that countertrade is a response to import restrictions imposed by West- ern countries on Romanian products. Bucharest has offered to exempt from countertrade requirements any country that liberalizes restrictions on Romanian exports. In 1982 Romania made a deal with the European Community (EC) to relax its demands. The EC liberalized some import restrictions on Romanian goods, but EC members are still encountering high countertrade demands from Romanian buyers. Despite the severity of Poland's financial crisis, the trend toward countertrade seems less pronounced than in Romania. Western suppliers of goods such as electronic components and agricultural chemicals used in export industries face small countertrade ratios. In most other sectors, however, the ratios have increased to between 60 and 90 percent. Because of their cash shortage, the Poles have joined the Roma- nians in trying to arrange straight barters or barter- like deals that require minimal cash payments. Such transactions are particularly awkward for Western firms, but the Poles-unlike the Romanians-occa- sionally will offer marketable items such as coal and raw materials for barter. Polish enterprises often are unable to enforce their demands because shortages of goods restrict what can be traded with Western companies. Some Western suppliers have made the best of a difficult situation by reversing the countertrade process through advance purchases. The Western partner buys Polish goods on the strength of the Polish firm's commitment to buy something from the Western importer within a stipu- lated period. The Western company has greater con- trol over the quality of the goods received, and the proceeds from the sale of the Polish products are kept in the West to ensure that hard currency is available the new rules complicated foreign trade management, leading to complaints from industries requiring Western ma- chinery and other imported inputs. In a speech to economic managers in 1981, President Ceausescu defended the policy as part of his plan to eliminate Romania's foreign debt. "Without the principle of compensation, nothing can be imported. We have taken the decision to allow no further increase in our foreign debt and to reduce it from this year onward. We shall import no more unless we have the where- withal to pay and unless the compensation we require is forthcoming from the firms concerned." to cover later sales to the Polish firm. 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Secret Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 Because of Yugoslavia's decentralized system of eco- nomic management, legislation on countertrade re- quirements adopted by federal authorities often has had little impact on foreign trade practices. At least through 1982, the republics held most of the authority for conducting foreign trade. Enterprises in republics that were net hard currency earners and whose banks had good access to Western credit markets paid much less heed to official guidelines on countertrade than enterprises from poorer regions. Even with this diversity, Yugoslav demands grew more stringent as the country's financial position deteriorated. Between 1978 and 1982, businessmen reported that counterpurchase requirements-usually on imports over authorized quotas-rose from 30 percent for all goods to 60 percent for machinery and spare parts, 80 percent for raw material and semifin- ished goods, and 100 percent for all other goods. In an effort to balance trade bilaterally, Belgrade required after 1980 that counterexports must be sold to the country supplying the initial imports. In 1982 Belgrade adopted new legislation on the use of countertrade for importing raw materials, semifin- ished goods, and consumer goods in short supply: ? Yugoslav firms purchasing such items had to re- quire $103 of counterpurchases for every $100 worth of imports. ? The Western supplier had to purchase the Yugoslav goods in advance of his own delivery. ? Only newly developed Yugoslav goods or those subject to Western import restrictions could be offered as counterdeliveries. Yugoslav authorities reasoned that this policy would generate an excess of exports over imports, would reduce the need for trade credit as a result of advance purchases, and would open up new markets for Yugo- slav goods. By reserving more desirable goods for countertrade arrangements, the authorities hoped to promote imports of goods needed for current produc- tion and consumption at the expense of imports of machinery and equipment. This was consistent with Belgrade's overall plan to reduce investment. By having access to better quality exportables, Yugoslav enterprises presumably would be more aggressive and successful in linking imports to exports. Before the credit squeeze of the 1980s, East Germany did not often demand counterpurchases for imports of consumer goods, semifinished products, or machinery. East Berlin's use of countertrade centered mainly on buy-back deals for the construction of complete plants, particularly in the chemical industry. The sudden unavailability of Western credits in 1982 and weak Western markets escalated East German de- mands for counterpurchases to pay for semifinished products and consumer goods. More important than counterpurchases, however, was East Germany's role as a middleman in multiparty countertrade deals. East Germany's Intrac trading organization, which specializes in the international trade of oil and nonfer- rous metals, helped East Berlin weather the financial squeeze by functioning as a barter-switch trader. Intrac generated substantial hard currency earnings by reselling for cash the oil, metals, and raw materials obtained in barter deals with developing countries as well as goods obtained on clearing account from West Germany. Hungary has made the least use of countertrade among the East European countries and has even criticized certain types of countertrade. In 1977, the Ministry of Foreign Trade expressed opposition to demands for counterpurchases in cases where the Hungarian enterprise would try to press on Western partners poor quality goods that it could not sell or for which it has no marketing organization. Countertrade was permissible only in cases where the Western firm would be the end user or where it had an established marketing organization. The Hungarians wanted long-term commercially based arrangements rather than one-time sales that could undermine the reputa- tion of Hungarian goods. Before 1983 Hungarian foreign trade enterprises did not require counterpurchases for planned imports for which hard currency had been allocated. (Unplanned imports required 100 percent countertrade.) Accord- ing to the business press, in early 1983, because of 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86S00588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Secret Hungary's severe hard currency problems, foreign trade enterprises began pressing for more counter- trade arrangements with Western suppliers. Western businessmen reported that Hungarian buyers began demanding counterpurchases covering 30 to 50 per- cent of imports. Until financial problems escalated countertrade de- mands from Romania, Poland, and Yugoslavia, Bul- garia generally sought the highest level of counter- trade among the East European countries. The poor quality of Bulgarian manufactured goods and Sofia's decision in the late 1970s to reduce its hard currency debt compelled foreign trade enterprises to demand 40 percent to 60 percent counterpurchase ratios from Western firms, even for priority imports. The Bulgari- ans tried to stress long-term cooperation through buy- back agreements rather than one-time counterpur- chase deals. But lack of Western interest in Bulgarian goods-except for some food products and petrochem- icals-limited the number of major countertrade agreements with Western firms. Sofia had some success in penetrating Third World markets through joint ventures with Western firms in which the Bul- garians provided construction and engineering ser- vices in return for Western machinery and equipment Czechoslovakia lagged behind most of the other East European countries in using countertrade during the 1970s because it believed its goods were competitive on Western markets. Because of Prague's reasonably strong hard currency position, the regional debt crisis did not result in much change in Czechoslovakia's commercial practices. Western businessmen have re- ported some Czechoslovak demand for counterpur- chases, but on the whole Prague has preferred to impose sharp cutbacks in imports and to press suppli- ers for financing to offset the decline in bank credits. used in the projects. Thanks to its relatively strong financial position and low level of dependence on hard currency trade, Bulgaria did not have to toughen its countertrade policies during the East European credit crunch. The Bulgarians, however, have continued to seek buy-back and offset deals in order to modernize their industry and expand their hard currency export capacity. Sofia has been particularly active in trying to develop cooperative deals with Western firms that would establish a manufacturing base for finished goods or components in the electronics and automobile indus- tries. The Bulgarians have also continued to pursue arrangements in which they can provide services in return for Western participation in joint ventures in developing countries. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0 Secret Secret Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/02/17: CIA-RDP86SO0588R000100130005-0