USSR-LDC TRADE: AN ECONOMIC AND QUANTITATIVE ANALYSIS

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP86T00591R000100050002-7
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
C
Document Page Count: 
38
Document Creation Date: 
December 22, 2016
Document Release Date: 
January 19, 2010
Sequence Number: 
2
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
February 1, 1985
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP86T00591R000100050002-7.pdf2.14 MB
Body: 
Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Directorate of Confidential Intelligence USSR-LDC Trade: An Economic and Quantitative Analysis A Technical Intelligence Report Confidential SOV 85-10010 February 1985 Copy 4 7 4 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Directorate of Confidential Intelligence USSR-LDC Trade: An Economic and Quantitative Analysis Comments and queries are welcome and may be directed to the Chief, Soviet Economy Division, SOYA, Confidential SOV 85-10010 February 1985 25X1 25X1 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential July 1982 to October 1983. research contract with the Office of Soviet Analysis and carried out from The research contained in this report was funded under an external Confidential SOV 85-10010 February 1985 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential USSR-LDC Trade: An Economic and Quantitative Analysis Summary An analysis of Soviet trade with the LDCs since the early 1970s using a Information available new body of statistics suggests that some common perceptions of the nature as of 31 October 1983 and importance of this trade are mistaken. was used in this report. The growth in the volume of Soviet-LDC trade since 1970 has exceeded the rate of growth in Moscow's trade with developed Western economies, although the value of trade with the developed West grew at a faster rate. Hence, price trends in this trade have tended to move against the USSR: ? Real Soviet imports from LDCs increased over the period at an average annual rate of 8 percent, but the pattern of growth was erratic. Real im- ports declined in each year during 1976-79 and then climbed in 1980 and 1981 as a result of massive food imports-mainly from Argentina, Brazil, India, and Thailand. ? Real Soviet exports to LDCs grew at an average rate of 5.5 to 9.5 percent per year in 1971-8 1, primarily because of a surge in military exports. Identified (primarily civilian) exports, however, stagnated in real terms during 1971-75 and have grown by only 2.5 to 5 percent per year since then.' ? Soviet terms of trade with the developing countries have deteriorated since the early 1970s, whereas terms of trade with the industrialized West have improved. From the LDC viewpoint, the USSR has not proved to be as important a trade partner as is sometimes believed in the West. In particular, it has not provided a substantial market for LDC manufactures: ? Soviet trade with the LDCs is still highly concentrated among five to 10 trading partners. ? Real reported exports to socialist-oriented clients and oil-exporting countries grew more rapidly than exports to the LDCs as a whole in 1971-81. ? Soviet purchases from non-socialist-oriented, non-oil-exporting countries, on the other hand, accounted for most of the growth in real imports from the LDCs during this period. ? Soviet imports from the Third World have been increasingly dominated by raw materials, especially agricultural commodities. The share of manufactured products in Soviet imports has diminished since the early 1970s. ' This estimate assumes that Soviet prices for machinery and equipment and unspecified ex- ports (believed to be mostly if not entirely military-related items) grew at an average annual rate of 4.5 percent to 9 percent. 25X1 Confidential Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential The Soviets have long claimed that the USSR, and the "socialist" countries in general, represent relatively fast-growing and stable markets for the raw material exports of the developing countries. This was a common assertion in Soviet writings of the 1950s and 1960s, and it was fre- quently voiced in the United Nations Conference on Trade and Develop- ment (UNCTAD) forums in the 1970s in the context of continued debate on The New International Economic Order. Analysis of the trade of the USSR, West Germany, Japan, and the United States with the LDCs shows that: ? The Soviet Union accounted for 17 percent of combined imports by the four countries of nine important primary products in the 1960s. In terms of the market size for these products, the USSR ranked third after the United States and West Germany. ? In 1971-81 the Soviet share of the combined imports increased to 23 percent, and the USSR and the United States shared first place in terms of market size. ? Soviet real imports of primary products from the LDCs seem to have been more variable than those of the average developed West importing country in 1960-70. The USSR ranked last in terms of variability of real imports in the 1970s, but the differences were not great enough to be sta- tistically significant. ? Examination of more than 20 years of Soviet imports of raw materials suggests some slight relative improvement in the stability of the prices the USSR pays for LDC exports, although Soviet performance in this respect must be considered as essentially no different from that of Western market economies. In sum, few LDCs outside the Soviet orbit depend heavily on the Soviet Union as a trade partner. Soviet shares of total trade have declined for some of the USSR's more important LDC trade partners but have increased for a number of other LDCs. Instances in which the Soviet share has fallen were twice as frequent as instances in which the share increased. This trend, in conjunction with the concentration of Soviet import growth in the raw materials group, suggests that the economic interdependence between the USSR and the LDCs probably has increased more slowly over the past 10 years than is often perceived in the West and claimed by the Soviets. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential A statistical analysis of the determinants of Soviet-LDC trade suggests that political factors have been significant to some degree. The level of Soviet exports to an individual LDC was found to be related to whether it had a "socialist orientation" and to whether it had a soft currency clearing agreement with the USSR. Soviet imports, however, seem to be unrelated to the socialist orientation of the exporting countries. The issue of how much market power the Soviet state trading monopoly can exert on prices cannot be settled with the available evidence. The trade data, however, point to relative price discrimination in favor of the USSR's trading partners in the Council of Mutual Economic Assistance (CEMA). Moreover, this discrimination appears to have increased over time. While this trend probably results mainly from a combination of political factors, it also reflects an inertia built into the intra-CEMA foreign trade system. The Soviets also appear to discriminate against socialist-oriented and soft currency countries, possibly because the USSR may have relatively more bargaining power with these countries than with other non-Communist LDCs. Finally, because the USSR continues to conduct its trade relations with several of its important trading partners through bilateral clearing ac- counts rather than in hard currency, the role these arrangements play in Soviet-LDC trade was investigated. Since the early 1970s, a number of soft currency agreements have been terminated, and trade has flourished most with those countries with which settlements are made in hard currency. Nevertheless, imports from Moscow's soft currency trade partners seem to be more diverse and stable than imports from hard currency partners. This trade also seems to include a higher proportion of manufactured commod- ities. Thus, it appears that Moscow's soft currency partners still benefit by maintaining their clearing account arrangements with the USSR. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential Trends in Aggregate Real Trade and Terms of Trade 1 Disaggregated Trends and Determinants of Soviet-LDC Trade 4 Composition of Trade 5 Trade by Country Group 6 Trade and the Payments Mechanism 7 Price Discrimination in Soviet Trade With the Developing Countries 8 Growth and Stability of Soviet Imports of Primary Products 13 Previous Investigations 13 The Role of Bilateral Clearing Agreements 15 Sample 15 Hypotheses Tested 15 Summary 17 A. Methodology for Calculating Price and Quantity Indexes 19 C. USSR: Soft and Hard Currency LDC Trading Partners 23 D. Statistical Notes on Calculating the Determinants of Soviet Trade With the LDCs 25 E. Methodology for Calculating Price Discrimination Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential USSR-LDC Trade: An Economic and Quantitative Analysis The goal of the contract research described in this technical intelligence report was to increase under- standing of Soviet trade with the Third World. A great deal of time was first spent in compiling statis- tics-that is, data on the dimensions of Soviet-LDC trade by country and commodity. That such an effort played an important role in the research will come as no surprise to students of the USSR's foreign trade, especially in view of the relative paucity and the recent deterioration in Soviet statistics. With the help of these statistics on the value and volume of LDC trade with the Soviet Union, the contractor proceeded to investigate a number of questions that before now have been looked at only in passing or not at all because of the lack of adequate data. His findings are This report first sets out the aggregate trends in the volume of Soviet-LDC trade in 1971-81 and estimates the changes in the terms of this trade over the period. In the next section, a disaggregated view of the trade is presented. Topics covered include the commodity composition of the trade, the distribution of trade by country group, the payment mechanisms, and the degree of concentration in this trade. The results of an econometric analysis of the determinants of the size and direction of Soviet-LDC trade also are described. In the following three sections, the report summarizes the contractor's research on three questions that have been discussed extensively over the years: ? Does the USSR offer more favorable prices in buying from and selling to LDCs who are political allies, strategically important, or participants in bilateral clearing arrangements with the USSR? ' This paper uses the Soviet definition of less developed countries, which encompasses: (1) all countries in Africa except the Republic of South Africa; (2) all countries in East Asia except Hong Kong, Japan, Laos, and Vietnam; (3) all countries in Latin America except Cuba; and (4) all countries in the Middle East except Israel. The terms less developed countries (LDCs), the Third World, and ? Does the Soviet Union represent a more stable and faster-growing market for LDC primary products than developed Western economies? ? How influential are bilateral clearing agreements in explaining Soviet trade with developing countries? Finally, a series of appendixes (a) explain the proce- dures followed in delivery price and quantity indexes for Soviet-LDC trade, (b) set out the definitions of socialist-oriented LDCs and soft and hard currency trading partners employed in the research, (c) provide the statistical basis for the findings regarding deter- minants of Soviet-LDC trade, and (d) reviews the methodology used to investigate price discrimination in this trade. Trends in Aggregate Real Trade and Terms of Trade The initial report focuses on the volume and terms of trade in Soviet commerce with the Third World during 1971-81. The developing countries studied were all those not classified as "socialist" LDCs in Soviet foreign trade statistics. The study included 73 developing countries for which Soviet trade statistics were available. The three developing country mem- bers of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (CEMA) (Cuba, Mongolia, and Vietnam) and socialist LDCs (Laos, North Korea, and China) were excluded. Basis for the Estimates Because of the dramatic deterioration in the coverage of Soviet foreign trade statistics since 1975-76, analy- sis of prices, quantities, and terms of trade has become very difficult. Soviet foreign trade with the developing countries is no exception. In particular, the reduced amount of data on quantities traded (that is, trade volume) and the Soviet tendency to report trade values at a higher level of aggregation for many products have made it impossible to calculate mean- ingful unit values from Soviet statistics. 25X1 25X1 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential A rather eclectic approach had to be followed in estimating price and quantity trends in recent Soviet trade with the developing countries. For machinery and equipment and "residual" exports-largely arms deliveries unidentified by country and/or commod- ity-indexes of world market prices and evidence of overall movements in Soviet export prices were used to derive two "synthetic" price indexes. Specifically, it was assumed that the average annual increase in ruble export prices for these two commodity groups fell within a range of 4.5 to 9 percent during 1971-81. Unit values for trade in fuels, metals, and minerals, and a few other primary or intermediate products were calculated from official Soviet foreign trade statistics for 1971-76, and synthetic price indexes were created on the basis of movements in world market price for these products after 1976. For all remaining products-including chemicals, building materials, other nonfood raw materials, foodstuffs, and industrial consumer goods-price indexes were developed from unit value calculations at the individ- ual country-product level. These price indexes were constructed for Soviet trade with each LDC and were aggregated to obtain overall price indexes for aggregate exports and imports, respectively. Quantity indexes were then derived for exports and imports using available data on trade values and the constructed aggregate price indexes. (See appendix A for a more complete description of the calculation of the price and quantity indexes presented in the report.) Results The calculations reflected several developments in aggregate Soviet trade with the developing countries over the past decade. From 1971 to 1981, the prices of Soviet exports to LDCs of identified trade (presumed to be civilian commodities) tended to rise more rapidly than prices for Soviet residual trade (pre- sumed to be military exports). This trend probably reflects the important role that exports of crude oil and oil products continue to play in Soviet trade with these countries. In 1981, for example, petroleum exports accounted for 38 percent of total identified Soviet exports to the LDCs. Over the entire decade, the reported calculations indicate that Soviet export prices to the developing countries increased at an average annual rate of 6.9 percent to 10.7 percent. Figure 1 USSR-LDC Trade: Trends in Soviet Export and Import Prices a, 1975-81 a Some 73 developing countries for which Soviet trade statistics are available are examined in the report. b Variant A: Machinery and equipment export prices and residual export prices are assumed to increase at 9 percent per annum. c Variant B: Machinery and equipment export prices and residual export prices are assumed to increase at 4.5 percent per annum. Second, prices for Soviet imports from LDCs have risen over the past decade at an average annual rate of about 11 percent. The rate of price increase slowed during 1976-78 but picked up again in 1979 as prices for oil, natural gas, and some foodstuffs increased rapidly on world markets (see figure 1). Third, Soviet net barter terms of trade with the developing countries have deteriorated since the early 1970s.3 How sharply they have declined depends a ' Net barter terms of trade reflect how well Soviet export prices have done vis-a-vis import prices. Declining terms of trade indicate that increases in Soviet export prices have not been sufficient to keep up with increases in import prices, thus the USSR must pay more in real exports to pay for the same quantity of goods imported in the base year. Improvement in the USSR's terms of trade would 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Figure 2 . USSR: Net Barter Terms of Trade With the LDCs, 1975-81- 975-81 a Figure 3 Figure USSR: Trends in Exports to the LDCs, 1975-81 **\, L - ~ - - aNet barter terms of trade reflect how well Soviet export prices have done vis-a-vis import prices. Declining terms of trade indicate that increases in Soviet export prices have not been sufficient to keep up with increases in import prices. Thus the USSR must pay more in real exports to buy the same quantity of goods imported in the base year. Improvement in the USSR's terms of trade would be the opposite situation. b Variant A: Machinery and equipment export prices and residual export prices are assumed to increase at 9 percent per annum. c Variant B: Machinery and equipment export prices and residual export prices are assumed to increase at 4.5 percent per annum. great deal, however, on which export price variant is presumed to have prevailed. Under variant A, where machinery and equipment and "residual" (or military) export prices are assumed to have grown at 9 percent per annum, there is a slight terms-of-trade improve- ment since 1975 and only a 2.5-percent cumulative deterioration since 1971. Variant B, on the other hand, assumes a 4.5-percent average annual rate of growth of prices for the same commodity groups and appears to be more consistent with aggregate Soviet export price trends for these products as reflected in official Soviet statistics. This variant yields a 15- percent cumulative terms-of-trade decline against the LDCs since 1975 and a more than 30-percent decline since 1971 (see figure 2). Regardless of price variant, the real growth of residu- al exports to LDCs by the USSR surpasses the real 100 1975 76 77 78 79 80 81 a Variant A: Machinery and equipment export prices and residual export prices are assumed to increase at 4.5 percent per annum. b Variant B: Machinery and equipment export prices and residual export prices are assumed to increase at 9 percent per annum. growth of identified exports during 1971-81. Residual exports, which are probably arms deliveries, have increased in real terms at an average annual rate of 10 to 15 percent over the past decade. Identified exports, however, essentially stagnated in real terms from 1971 to 1975 and since 1975 have grown by only 2.5 to 5 percent a year. Overall real exports grew at an annual average rate of 5.6 to 9.4 percent (see figure 3). The much faster growth of residual exports has caused that group to play an important role in overall Soviet exports despite the slower rate of increase in their prices. The proportion of residual exports in total Soviet exports to LDCs climbed from 47 percent in 1971 to 51 percent in 1975, and exceeded 60 percent in 1977-79. Because variant B suggests such a high (15 percent) rate of growth in the volume of Soviet residual exports, it is likely that Soviet prices of these exports have been growing at a faster rate than assumed under that variant-that is, greater than 4.5 percent per annum. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential Figure 4 USSR: Trends in Imports From the LDCs, 1975-81 1 1 50 1975 76 77 78 79 80 81 Constant 1975 prices Over the past decade, real Soviet imports from the LDCs increased at about an 8 -percent average annual rate, although the growth pattern was erratic within this period. Real imports grew at an average rate of 9.2 percent per annum during 1971-75, declined each year from 1976 to 1979, and then surged again as massive Soviet grain purchases were redirected to developing countries, particularly Argentina, in 1980 and 1981 (see figure 4). The growth in real imports over the past decade matched the growth in real exports by averaging the growth rates under variants A and B. Finally, the calculations for Soviet trade with the LDCs were used in conjunction with official Soviet statistics on trade with all "nonsocialist" countries to derive rough measures of trends in prices, trade volume, and terms of trade in Soviet economic rela- tions with the industrialized West. The calculations suggest that prices of Soviet exports to the industrial- ized West rose in 1976-81 at an average annual rate of 14 to 16 percent, while prices of Soviet imports from this region grew at an average rate of about 4 Figure 5 USSR: Implied Terms of Trade With Industrially Developed Countries, 1975-81 Export prices: Variant A a Export prices: Variant B b 100 1975 76 77 78 79 80 81 a Variant A: Machinery and equipment export prices and residual export prices are assumed to increase at 4.5 percent per annum. b Variant B: Machinery and equipment export prices and residual export prices are assumed to increase at 9 percent per annum. percent.' In contrast to the stagnation or possible cumulative deterioration of Soviet terms of trade with the LDCs of up to 15 percent in this period, Soviet terms of trade with the industrial West improved at an average annual rate of 10 to 12 percent. Since the mid-1970s, the volume of Soviet exports to the LDCs, particularly arms exports, has apparently grown at a much faster rate than have Soviet exports to the West. Only because of the recent surge in Soviet imports of foodstuffs from LDCs has the volume of Soviet imports from the LDCs matched the growth of real imports from the West since the mid-1970s (see figure 5) Disaggregated Trends and Determinants of Soviet-LDC Trade The statistical base also permits an analysis of recent patterns and trends in Soviet foreign trade with the ' It is unlikely that prices of Soviet imports from the developed West really grew at such a slow rate during 1976-81, especially Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential Table 1 USSR: Commodity Composition of Exports to the Developing Countries, 1970, 1975, and 1980 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 Machinery and equipment 32.9 24.3 20.3 Fuels 3.5 10.2 16.8 Ores, concentrates, and.metals 5.8 3.3 1.2 Chemicals and products 1.0 3.0 1.9 Building materials 0.6 1.0 0.6 Timber, pulp, and paper 3.0 3.5 2.3 Textile 0.6 0.4 Other materials of animal, vegetable origin 0.1 0.1 .0.1 Food and foodstuffs 4.7 2.7 1.2 Industrial consumer goods 1.5 1.1 0.5 Residual 46.9 50.2 54.7 Source: Calculated in current prices from Vneshniaia torgovlia SSSR, various issues. Table 2 USSR: Commodity Composition of Imports From the Developing Countries, 1970, 1975, and 1980 Machinery and equipment 0.2 0.6 0.8 Fuels 3.7 19.3 13.9 Ores, concentrates, and metals 4.3 3.5 3.0 Chemicals and products 11.4 3.7 5.0 Building materials 0.1 Timber, pulp, and paper 0.5 0.7 0.5 Textile raw materials 25.7 11.5 5.0 Other materials of animal, vegetable origin 8.5 5.0 6.7 Food and foodstuffs 33.2 44.3 48.4 Industrial consumer goods 12.5 8.8 7.1 Residual 2.6 9.4 Source: Calculated in current prices from Vneshniaia torgovlia SSSR, various issues. developing countries at a more disaggregated level, largely by using the unit values implied by value and quantity data and other information to calculate changes in the volume of trade and in export and import prices. Composition of Trade Over the past decade the trade residual (Soviet arms sales) was the most dynamic source of real growth in Soviet exports to the LDCs. Real exports of petroleum and petroleum products also accelerated until 1979. After stagnating during 1971-75, real exports of machinery and equipment also grew at a respectable rate after the mid-1970s. Real exports of the other major commodity groups, however, either stagnated or actually declined in the latter half of the 1970s. In nominal or current prices the share of exports ac- counted for by petroleum exports and arms sales increased over the past decade, largely at the expense of machinery and equipment shares and exports of ores and metals (primarily iron and steel products) (see table 1). From 1970 to 1975, Soviet real imports of petroleum and ores, metals, and concentrates from the develop- ing countries climbed swiftly. From 1978 to 1981, however, the volume of petroleum imports-apparent- ly intended for reexport-has declined, as have identi- fied imports of ores and metals. This estimated down- turn in real imports of ores and metals may be exaggerated, however, and could be completely mis- leading (see table 2). The rapidly expanding Soviet import residual probably contains at least some ores and metals trade that were in the past included in identified trade. From 1975 to 1979, aggregate real imports from the developing countries apparently declined. The dra- matic growth in imports after 1979, however, resulted almost exclusively from large purchases of foodstuffs from such countries as India, Thailand, Argentina, and Brazil. Contrary to Soviet public statements, imports to the USSR from the Third World appear to Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential Table 3 USSR: Trends in Terms of Trade With Various LDC Groups, 1975-81 Trade with developing countries 100 88 to 90 with a "Socialist Orientation" a Trade with developing "Client 100 97 to 99 Countries" b Trade with developing oil-exporting 100 101 to 105 101 to 108 113 to 126 87 to 100 58 to 70 50 to 63 countries c Trade with developing countries 100 99 to 101 which are neither "Socialist Oriented," nor oil exporters d a "Socialist Orientation" countries-Afghanistan, Burma, Cambo- dia, South Yemen, Syria, Algeria, Angola, Benin, Cape Verde, Congo, Ethiopia, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Madagascar, Mozam- bique, Somalia, Tanzania, Grenada, Nicaragua. b "Client Countries"-Afghanistan, South Yemen, Angola, Ethio- pia, Mozambique, Cambodia. c Oil-exporting countries-Indonesia, Iraq, Iran, Kuwait, Saudi Arabia, UAE, Libya, Nigeria, Ecuador, Mexico, Venezuela. be increasingly dominated by primary products and intermediate goods. The role of manufactured prod- ucts has diminished since the early 1970s. Trade by Country Group Trends in Soviet foreign trade with various country groups were also examined. Because the analysis was limited to statistics on trade with individual countries, most of the trade in arms exports (not included in country statistics) was excluded. Using Soviet classifications, 19 "socialist-oriented" countries were identified.' Real Soviet exports to and imports from the client group of socialist-oriented countries grew at above-average rates in the latter half.of the 1970s. Real. exports to the nonclient, 'These 19 countries do not encompass the six "socialist" LDCs referenced in the first section of this report. A 1982 NATO Economic Committee report-Soviet Economic Relations With Selected Client States in the Developing World-classifies Afghan- istan, Angola, Cambodia, Ethiopia, Mozambique, and South Ye- men as Soviet "clients." The report also examined separately the "oil-exporting" developing countries and an "all other" group of LDCs. (A complete breakdown of country groupings is provided in d Other developing countries-Burkina, Burundi, Camaroon, Cen- tral African Republic, Equatorial Guinea, Gabon, The Gambia, Ivory Coast, Kenya, Liberia, Malawi, Mauritania, Mauritius, Niger, Rwanda, Senegal, Sierra Leone, Sudan, Togo, Uganda, Zaire, Zambia, Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, El Salvador, Guatemala, Guyana, Honduras, Jamaica, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Trinidad and Toba- go, Uruguay, Burma, Hong Kong, Israel, Jordan, Lebanon, Macau, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, North Yemen. socialist-oriented countries as reported by the USSR actually fell from 1976 to 1980, and real imports from the group declined continuously from 1975 to 1979. Soviet terms of trade deteriorated by roughly the same amount for trade with both groups of socialist- oriented countries in the 1970s. The cumulative dete- rioration from 1971 to 1981 ranged from 33 to 47 percent for the 19 socialist-oriented countries (see table 3). Real Soviet imports from oil-exporting LDCs declined from 1978 to 1981, but real exports to these countries have grown rapidly, although quite erratically. Much of the fluctuation originates in reported exports to the three principal oil-exporting countries-Iran, Iraq, and Libya. Not surprisingly, Soviet terms of trade with this group of countries have deteriorated by an estimated 52 to 67 percent since 1971. In contrast to sales to socialist-oriented clients and oil- exporting LDCs, the volume of Soviet-reported ex- ports "to all other" LDCs declined in the first half of Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential the 1970s and has stagnated since 1975. In effect, the dynamism in Soviet civilian exports has been confined to the socialist-oriented clients and oil-exporting coun- tries. Because of the USSR's booming imports of foodstuffs since 1980, however, it is this "all other" group of countries that has accounted for most of the growth in Soviet real imports from the developing world. In contrast to the other two groups, Soviet terms of trade with this third-country grouping have improved, although nearly all of the improvement has Comparisons between the socialist-oriented and all nonsocialist countries highlight the much more rapid price increases received by the socialist-oriented group on their exports to the Soviet Union. This could be attributable to either differences in commodity com- position or to conscious price discrimination on the part of the Soviets. Also noteworthy are the consistent reported trade surpluses that the USSR ran with the socialist-oriented-particularly the core client-and oil-exporting countries in the second half of the 1970s contrasted with sizable reported deficits with "all other" LDCs as a group. Trade and the Payments Mechanism Developing countries can also be categorized by the type-of payments mechanism predominating in their trade with the USSR-by hard or soft currency clearing arrangements.' Three groups were examined: (1) those with soft currency arrangements throughout 1971-81; (2) those that switched from soft to hard currency clearing during the decade; and (3) countries that traded on a hard currency basis throughout the decade. (See appendix C for a list of the USSR's hard and soft currency trading partners.) The soft currency country group included four nations that comprise the major LDC markets for Soviet petroleum exports: Afghanistan, India, Turkey, and Morocco. The group also included Egypt and Somalia ' The USSR maintains special agreements with selected LDCs that permit the bilateral trade between the two countries to be settled in the nonconvertible local currency of the LDC partner. Trade is transacted through clearing accounts that are expected to be balanced at the end of a given period, usually a year. Thus, the USSR essentially barters its exports for imports from its trade partner. Trade with all other LDCs is, for the most part, settled in freely convertible currencies, such as US dollars, deutsche marks, whose political and economic relations with the USSR deteriorated sharply in the 1970s. Real exports to this soft currency group declined in the first half of the 1970s and have remained consistent with the overall growth of Soviet real "civilian" exports to the LDCs since 1975. The growth of Soviet real imports from the group, however, has lagged the overall average. Soviet terms of trade with the group improved slightly in the first half of the 1970s and also improved as a whole during 1971-81. Real exports to and imports from the group of countries, which switched from soft to hard currency clearing in the 1970s, have declined markedly in recent years, raising the question of whether this decline in trade was influenced by or contributed to the termination of earlier soft currency payments arrangements. Two of these countries, Ghana and Mali, have been characterized by Soviet writers as having deviated from or abandoned their earlier "so- cialist orientation." Soviet reported trade has flourished most with hard currency trading partners. Real Soviet exports to these countries have developed at an above-average pace, and real Soviet imports from this group doubled from 1979 to 1981, largely as the result of massive grain and food imports. Soviet terms of trade with this group deteriorated from 1971 to 1975, improved from 1976 to 1978, and have tended to deteriorate since 1978. Trade Concentration The degree of Soviet trade concentration among major trade partners has declined over the past 20 years, but not at a remarkable rate. Soviet trade still remains highly concentrated among its top partners, although the largest partners tend to change over time and can differ depending upon whether exports or imports are being considered. In 1981, 59 percent of Soviet exports to the LDCs went to just five countries, with 79 percent going to 10 LDCs. Largely because of the large increase in grain imports from Argentina in 1980 and 1981, 65 percent of all Soviet imports from the developing countries in 1981 originated in five countries, and 82 percent originated in just 10 LDCs. 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential The Soviet share of the "civilian" exports and imports of 85 developing countries were calculated for 1970- 72 and 1979-81, using LDC statistics compiled by the IMF. These calculations suggest some degree of deconcentration of LDC trade with the USSR during the 1970s. Shares of trade with the USSR tended to decline for Moscow's more important trade partners and to increase for a number of other LDCs. Al- though these calculations could not be made for all LDC trade partners, very few developing countries depend heavily on the Soviet Union as a trade partner. The Soviet share of reported LDC imports declined for twice as many countries as it increased in the 1970s. This trend, in conjunction with the concentra- tion of Soviet import growth in the primary product group, suggests that the economic interdependence of the Soviet and LDC economies probably has in- creased more slowly over the past 10 years than is often perceived in the West.and claimed by the Soviets (see table 4). Determinants of Soviet-LDC Trade The determinants of LDC trade with the Soviet Union were examined in an econometric analysis of the data developed in the first stage of the contract research. Insufficient data, however, prevented de- tailed estimations of supply-and-demand functions and, therefore, the analysis was confined to a cross section of LDC trade with the USSR in 1975. Other things being equal, it was assumed that a given LDC would trade more with the USSR: (1) the more it trades with the world as a whole (a scale factor); (2) .the more complementary its export/import structure is with the import/export structure of the USSR; (3) the closer it is geographically to the Soviet Union (because of lower transaction costs and a greater Soviet geopolitical interest); (4) if it is "socialist oriented"; and (5) if it has a soft currency clearing arrangement with the Soviet Union. Also, given the Soviet stress on machinery and equipment exports in aid agreements, it was further assumed that reported exports might be negatively related to per capita GNP in the developing countries. Various functional formats incorporating the above factors were used to construct a profile of Soviet exports to and imports from two samples of develop- ing countries in 1975: (1) all developing countries that reported trade with the USSR, using IMF statistics and (2) all LDCs with which the USSR reported trade in 1975, using Soviet statistics. The level of Soviet exports to individual LDCs was found to be positively related to a country's total imports, whether it had a "socialist orientation, " and whether it had a soft currency clearing agreement with the USSR. Soviet exports were also found to be negatively related to distance from the USSR and to the trading partner's per capita GNP. Curiously, Soviet exports were also negatively but weakly related to an index of complementarity. On the import side, Soviet trade was found to be a positive function of (1) complementarity; (2) the trade partner's total exports; and (3) whether there was a soft. currency clearing agreement between the two countries. Soviet imports were negatively related to distance and unrelated to either "socialist orienta- tion" or per capita GNP level. For both exports and imports, the differences in these explanatory variables across countries explained in each case from 60 to 80 percent of the total variation in trade levels. The import and export equations tend to confirm that even the pattern of civilian exports to LDCs is more heavily influenced by political fac- tors-as shown in the correlations with "socialist orientation" and per capita income and the lack of correlation with the complementarity index-than is the pattern of Soviet imports from the developing world. (See appendix D for more detailed information on the methodology and statistical results.) Price Discrimination in Soviet Trade With the Developing Countries Price discrimination by the USSR in its trade with the developing countries is plausible for two basic reasons. First, the Soviets might offer preferential prices to selected LDCs considered to be political and/or military allies. The existence of such price discrimination is supported by the finding of Marrese and Various that the pattern of implicit trade subsi- dies in Soviet trade with the European CEMA mem- bers correlates somewhat with their evaluation of the political-strategic importance of these countries to the Soviet Union.' Soviet concern with the "economic 'Marrese, M. and Vanous, J., Soviet Subsidization of Trade With Eastern Europe, Berkley: Institute of International Studies, Uni- 25X1 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Table 4 Unweighted Average Soviet Share of Individual Developing Country Exports and Imports, 1970-72 and 1979-81 Soviet Share Soviet Share of LDC Exports of LDC Imports Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential Table 4 Unweighted Average Soviet Share of Individual Developing Country Exports and Imports, 1970-72 and 1979-81 (continued) Soviet Share Soviet Share of LDC Exports of LDC Imports Mali Malta Virgin Islands a 1972 only. b Percentage shares are probably understated because the IMF extrapolates data when information is incomplete. c Reported as NA ("Not Available") here because available figure is clearly of the wrong order of magnitude. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential burden" of Moscow's "extended empire" in the Third World, including Cuba, Vietnam, Ethiopia, and Af- ghanistan, is based in part on the presumption of price calculating separate price discrimination indexes for: (1) all commodities; (2) all commodities except petro- leum and petroleum products; and (3) all commodities except petroleum, petroleum products, and machinery discrimination in favor of these countries. A second basis for Soviet price discrimination is the existence of bilateral clearing agreements with LDCs that account for roughly one-half of identified Soviet trade with the "nonsocialist" developing world. Al- though the number of developing countries with which the USSR trades predominantly on a soft currency basis has declined in recent years, many of its main LDC trade partners still deal with the Soviets in this way. The monopoly power conferred to the USSR and other large state-trading countries, which gives them potential power to exercise price discrimi- nation against smaller partners, was pointed out 40 years ago by such prominent international trade theorists as Jacob Viner and Howard Ellis. The USSR, however, might also use such agreements to trade with certain countries at prices more favorable to them than the prices obtainable on the world market. This might explain why some LDCs have clung tenaciously to these agreements while others have let them lapse. Data and Methodology Significant data and methodological problems were encountered in examining the issue of price discrimi- nation. The proportion of trade for which quantities are reported and for which unit values can be calcu- lated fell sharply after 1975. A second problem common to any study that relies on reported foreign trade values and quantities to calcu- late unit values is the possibility-and indeed the probability-that the commodities traded with differ- ent countries under a given commodity position, such as a Communist Trade Nomenclature (CTN) number, are not homogeneous. Much of Soviet trade with the LDCs consists of primary products and intermediates, however, and Soviet trade in consumer manufactures with the LDCs is unlikely to feature significant heterogeneity within commodity groups across coun- tries. Consequently, there is little problem of hetero- geneity within product groups CTN 2 to 9, with the exception of CTN 21 and 22-trade in petroleum and petroleum products. CTN 1 covers machinery and equipment. The study addressed this problem by and equipment. A third problem stressed by Marrese and Vanous is the tendency to focus simply on export and import prices. The full measure of the importance of price discrimination, in terms of the net implicit trade subsidy involved, is obtained by weighting each price differential by the quantities actually traded. There- fore, the study took into account both prices and quantities for both exports and imports. Finally, there is the issue of benchmark prices. The measurement of the implicit trade subsidy requires a search for some common opportunity cost basis. Mar- rese and Vanous used actual, or in many cases "constructed," East-West trade prices as their mea- sure of the alternative prices that the Soviet Union could receive for its exports or that it would have to pay for its imports. A different measure of price discrimination was developed because: (1) there is general skepticism of such constructed prices, espe- cially for machinery and equipment; (2) much of Soviet-LDC trade may be even less homogeneous than is Soviet/East European trade relative to Soviet trade with the West; and (3) interest centers primarily on the pattern of possible Soviet price discrimination among the developing countries. Specifically, Soviet price discrimination was exam- ined among the group of LDCs that includes the three non-European members of CEMA (Cuba, Mongolia, and Vietnam) and three other LDCs classified as "socialist" in Soviet foreign trade statistics (China, Laos, and North Korea). The benchmark used was the weighted average price at which each commodity is traded in Soviet-LDC trade. The resulting net relative measure of implicit trade subsidies that is calculated for each Soviet LDC trade partner has the theoreti- cally appealing property that the sum of all such country subsidies is equal to zero. These implicit trade subsidies were calculated for each LDC for 1970, 1975, and 1980. (See appendix E for a more detailed description of the methodology used to calculate price discrimination.) Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential Results Only three somewhat consistent patterns of Soviet relative price discrimination emerged in the study. First, relative price discrimination in favor of the three LDC members of CEMA was apparent in 1980 in terms of trade-normalized relative trade subsidies and for all three years-1970, 1975, and 1980-when these relative subsidies were measured against trading partners' population or GNP. Second, relative price discrimination against soft currency clearing agree- ment trade partners was apparent in 1970 and 1975, particularly in terms of trade-normalized relative subsidies. Third, countries with a "socialist orienta- tion" appeared to be systematically discriminated against in 1975 on the basis of trade-normalized relative trade subsidies. This evidence of relative price discrimination in favor of CEMA members and against socialist-oriented and soft currency trade partners may be provisionally interpreted as follows. The Soviet Union would appear to be price discriminating in favor of LDC members of CEMA, perhaps increasingly over time. This dis- crimination probably results from a combination of political factors and the inertia built into the intra- CEMA foreign trade price system. It conforms both to anecdotal accounts and to conventional calculations of trade subsidies to Cuba in sugar and oil and also is consistent with the Marrese and Vanous perception of massive absolute implicit trade subsidies in Soviet trade with the European members of CEMA. In the past the Soviet Union may have systematically discriminated against the socialist-oriented and soft currency countries. Given the presumed "socialist orientation" of the first group and the close Soviet political relationship with members of the second group-for example, Afghanistan, India, and Syria- it is difficult to believe that this discrimination was the conscious result of political factors. A more plausible explanation might be that historically these countries have encountered greater difficulties, for a variety of reasons, in gaining access to world markets at favorable prices than have the oil-exporting coun- tries or "all other" developing countries. (The latter group is composed mainly of Southeast Asian newly industrialized countries [NICs] and a number of Latin American and African exporters of minerals and foodstuffs.) The Soviets may be forced to trade pri- marily at world market prices with the NICs. Soviet trade with the socialist-oriented and soft currency countries, on the other hand, may systematically enable the USSR to command higher export and lower import prices. In effect, the USSR may have considerable bilateral bargaining power with these countries, and this may be reinforced by the strongly bilateral nature of their trading relationships. F_ If indeed the Soviets have tended to discriminate against their soft currency clearing partners, one may wonder why these countries might continue to press the USSR to maintain these agreements, as Soviet analysts claim. Two qualifications should be noted, however, to the findings. First, there is no econometric evidence that either the socialist-oriented or the soft currency countries were still being systematically discriminated against in 1980. Second, soft currency agreements have been terminated with several LDCs since 1975. This could have represented LDC re- sponse to perceived price discrimination against them. On balance, the pattern of Soviet relative price dis- crimination that emerged in identified trade was not always clear and not particularly consistent across the three years examined. Furthermore, an economet- ric analysis of the determinants of the pattern of, relative subsidization across countries was not very successful. One possible reason for this lack of success may be that the proxies for political and economic explanatory factors, usually in the form of country group dummy variables, were simply not precise enough and failed to differentiate adequately among individual developing countries. Another possibility is that, despite efforts to achieve commodity homogeneity across countries, significant heterogeneity remains. Large measured price differ- entials may have been simply the result of such heterogeneity and not price discrimination. Differ- ences in timing of Soviet imports in the course of a given year could also explain many observed price differentials across countries, particularly in the case of primary products such as sugar. Both product heterogeneity and timing differences could be seen as significant random elements that may have negated most of the impact of political and market-structure determinants on Soviet price discrimination. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential Growth and Stability of Soviet Imports of Primary Products The Soviets have long claimed that the USSR, and the "socialist" countries more generally, represent relatively fast-growing and stable markets for the primary product exports of the developing countries. This was a common assertion in Soviet writings of the 1950s and 1960s, and it was frequently voiced in the United Nations Conference on Trade and Develop- ment (UNCTAD) forums in the 1970s. Previous Investigations In terms of methodology and product coverage, the contract research replicates earlier work of Egon Neuberger, who examined these issues for 1955-61, and of Philip Hanson, whose study focused on 1960- 68.8 Soviet imports during 1960-81 were examined, as well as in the two subperiods, 1960-70 and 1971-81. Comparing the Soviet Union with a group of Western countries for the late 1950s, Neuberger found that the USSR was a relatively small market for LDC exports of primary products. Perhaps for that very reason, the Soviet Union was a relatively rapidly growing market as well as a relatively unstable one in terms of annual fluctuations of unit values and LDC export revenue. Hanson found that, during 1960-70, the USSR was still a relatively fast-growing market for LDC exports compared with certain Western countries but that its "margin of superiority" in this respect was "not very great." Soviet imports, in terms of both volume and value, were still relatively unstable, but Hanson ar- gued that the instability was not significant. Hanson concluded that the evidence "hardly seems to support the view that there is a substantial and interesting difference between the two kinds of economic systems (Soviet type versus market type) as importers of primary products in the stability of their import flows, as conventionally measured." 'Neuberger, Egon, "Is the USSR Superior to the West as a Market for Primary Products?", Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 46, 1964. Hanson, Philip, "The Size, Growth, and Stability of the Soviet Market for Primary Products," Jahrbuch der Wirtscha t Data and Procedures The so-called core commodities included in the UNCTAD Integrated Program for Commodities were used as the basis for product selection. The stabiliza- tion of sales of these commodities is of particular interest to the developing countries. The commodity coverage of this study is compared with the UNCTAD list and those of the earlier Neuberger and Hanson studies. Consistent and comprehensive 1960-81 trade data for the Soviet Union and the three main Western trading nations-West Germany, Japan, and the United States-were available in trade statistics published by the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) for seven of the 10 UNCTAD "core" commodities: raw sugar, coffee, cocoa beans, tea, natural rubber, raw cotton, and jute. Also analyzed were rice and tobacco, two other commodities origi- nally examined by Neuberger and for which consis- tent and comprehensive FAO data were available. Developing countries account for a majority of world exports in most of these products and for more than 95 percent of world exports in four of the commod- ities. Results The Soviet Union accounted for only 16.7 percent of combined four-country-United States, West Germa- ny, Japan, USSR-imports of the nine sampled pri- mary products during 1960-70. In terms of the sum of individual size-of-market rankings by product, the USSR ranked third after the United States and West Germany. During 1971-81, however, Soviet imports amounted to 23.2 percent of combined imports, and the USSR was tied for first place with the United States in terms of the sum of individual size-of- market rankings by product. The study found that the Soviet Union ranked second among the four countries examined in terms of real growth of primary product imports over the entire period. In the 1970s the USSR narrowed the lead of first-place Japan in this regard, and, for that decade as well as the entire 1960-81 period, the Soviet Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential Table 5 Estimated. Average Annual Growth Rates of Selected Real Raw Material Imports From Developing Countries, 1960-81 United States West Germany Japan Soviet Union 1960-70 1971-81 1960-70 1971-81 1960-70 1971-81 1960-70 1971-81 -25.9 12.0 Sum of rankings 28.0 27.0 26.5 23.5 14.0 19.0 21.5 20.5 Overall ranking 4.0 4.0 3.0 3.0 1.0 1.0 2.0 2.0 a Estimated growth rates are only shown if they are statistically significantly different from zero at least at the 20-percent level. market grew more rapidly than that of the median Western country. As shown in table 5, during this period Soviet real imports grew at relatively high rates for rice (particularly in the 1970s), sugar (1970s), cocoa beans (1960s), and jute (1960s and 1970s).0 Weak evidence was found suggesting that Soviet real imports of primary products were relatively variable compared with those of median Western importing .countries in 1960-81.9 Although the USSR ranked last in terms of variability of real imports in the 1970s, the differences in this case were not great enough to be statistically significant. Soviet imports became absolutely less variable in terms of the meas- ured stability indexes for six of the nine products during the 1960s and 1970s. ' The measure for stability of the volume imports, unit values, and total import values in the study was the modified coefficient of variation index used in the Neuberger and Hanson studies. The coefficient of variation was modified so that the standard deviation was calculated with respect to the estimated trend, rather than the mean value of import volume, unit value, and total import value, respectively. The rankings and statistical significance of the results were essentially the same regardless of whether linear or nonlinear estimating techniques were used or the rankings were weighted by The slightly reduced relative variability of Soviet unit values in the 1970s appears to explain the diminished relative variability of Soviet total import values in this decade. Soviet import values were significantly more variable than those of the median Western country in the 1960s, but since then they have not been signifi- cantly more variable than the Western median. No systematic relationship was found between stabil- ity indexes and the average values of import volumes, unit values, or total trade values, respectively. The empirical results, therefore, suggest that the explana- tion for any apparent Soviet variability probably lays in differences in the Soviet foreign trade system and/or Soviet foreign trade policies and not in market size differences. In sum, examination of more than 20 years of Soviet imports of primary products suggests some slight relative improvement in the stability of the prices the USSR pays for LDC exports, although it still must be considered as essentially no different from that of the Western market economies. The volumes of Soviet 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential imports of these products continue to be a bit more variable than those of the median Western country, but they are relatively less variable than before. In the 1970s Soviet import volumes could not be considered to be more variable than the real imports of the median market economy. The net result of these trends in relative variability of Soviet real imports and import prices has been to reduce the variability of Soviet import values from clearly above average in the 1960s to essentially average levels in the past decade. Thus, the stability of Soviet import behavior (prices, volume, and value) with respect to primary products is now more similar to that of the major Western trading countries than it was in the 1960s. The Role of Bilateral Clearing Agreements The importance of bilateral clearing agreements in explaining Soviet trade patterns with developing countries was also assessed. This is comparable to asking whether bilateral clearing agreements serve a useful purpose, because such agreements presumably are valued at least partly for the effect that they are perceived to have on trade. Sample The sample distinguished between the USSR's soft currency (SC) and hard currency (HC) developing country trade partners. The distinction referred to the difference between hard and soft currency LDC trade partners of the USSR. Although the soft currency trade partners maintain bilateral clearing agreements with the Soviet Union, it was neither assumed that all Soviet trade with these countries was transacted through the formal clearing mechanisms, nor that all trade with supposedly HC trade partners was settled in convertible currencies. The SC trade partners considered in this study are the same as those identified previously. As mentioned in that discussion, the number of SC partners has de- clined since the early 1970s. For the most part, therefore, the study focused on the 10 "core" nonso- cialist (Soviet definition) SC countries, namely those developing countries that apparently still maintained bilateral clearing agreements with the Soviet Union as of 1980.10 According to Soviet sources, by 1983 this core group had been further reduced to just six countries: Afghanistan, India, Iran, Pakistan, Syria, and Egypt." The study does not include the six "socialist" LDC trade partners-Cuba, Mongolia, Vietnam, Laos, North Korea, and China-each of which is commonly believed to do business with the USSR on the basis of bilateral clearing agreements. These countries were excluded to isolate the marginal effect of bilateral clearing agreements on Soviet trade with countries that do not have centrally planned economies. Hypotheses Tested 25X1 The report was organized around six plausible expla- nations, none mutually exclusive, for the existence of bilateral clearing agreements between certain devel- oping countries and the Soviet Union. In all but one case, these explanations were tested and the empirical results used as a basis for judging the relative persua- siveness of these different arguments. While the im- pact of bilateral clearing agreements per se on Soviet- LDC trade flows could not be isolated, it was possible to demonstrate that Soviet trade with countries hav- 25X1 ing bilateral clearing agreements with the USSR is different in some fundamental respects from Soviet trade with other developing countries. The first explanation explored was the traditional rationale for bilateral clearing agreements: they rep- resent a second-best way for countries with exchange controls to push trade, and presumably economic welfare, above the levels that would be possible if all trade were conducted on a convertible currency basis. The cross-section regressions for 1975 from the report indicated that LDC trade levels with the Soviet Union were higher for SC trading partners. Whether the clearing agreements were responsible for the higher levels of trade, however, was not clear. Furthermore, although roughly half of the HC exporters to the Soviet Union in 1980 were reported by the IMF as Egypt, Guinea, and Morocco. " The Annual Report on Exchange Restrictions for 1983, published by the International Monetary Fund, indicates that Bangladesh continues to maintain a bilateral clearing account with the USSR. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential maintaining "restrictions on payments for current transactions," all of the SC trade partners of the Soviet Union were so designated. The finding for the SC countries is consistent with the trade expansion argument, but the question remains why the other exchange control countries did not have bilateral clearing agreements with the Soviet Union. Moreover, the countries that no longer had clearing agreements with the USSR during 1970-83 were not reported by the IMF as having eliminated the ex- change controls. It should be noted, however, that the IMF designations are very rough and probably cannot be used to measure precisely the relative severity of exchange controls across countries. An implicit assumption that often seems to underlie the second-best argument for bilateral clearing agree- ments is that the signatory countries have a range of exportables that fall into the category of "soft goods" in Soviet-East European parlance. Considering ma- chinery and equipment and manufactured consumer goods to be the preeminent soft goods, in 1980 the SC trade partners of the USSR had an above-average proportion of "soft goods" in their exports to the Soviet Union. Taken together, these rather crude empirical measures do provide some support for the trade expansion argument, but the evidence is certain- ly nothing more than indicative. A related argument would be that bilateral clearing agreements facilitate LDC export diversification, which might be a policy objective of some developing countries. By two measures of export diversification, SC exports to the Soviet Union in 1980 were signifi- cantly more diversified than those of equally large HC exporters to the USSR. It could not be shown that the clearing agreements encouraged this greater diversifi- cation, but the correlation is very suggestive. Relative export diversification does not appear to be a good predictor, however, of whether clearing agreements will be allowed to lapse. Another attraction of bilateral clearing agreements to developing countries might be the perception that LDC exports to the Soviet market will grow more rapidly if they are paid for on a soft currency clearing basis. Neither overall trends in Soviet imports in the latter half of the 1970s, however, nor detailed com- parisons for 1965-77 for individual countries yield any evidence that clearing agreements facilitate the growth in exports to the USSR. The possibility that developing countries having bilat- eral clearing agreements with the Soviet Union might obtain better terms of trade was also examined. The SC trading partners as a group actually suffered a deterioration in their terms of trade with the USSR in the 1970s, and the HC group's terms of trade im- proved. Price trends in Soviet petroleum trade obvi- ously played a big role in this divergence, while clearing agreements probably had little influence.F- As discussed earlier, no evidence could be found of Soviet price discrimination in favor of the SC coun- tries. On the contrary, some weak evidence was found of price discrimination against this group of countries in 1970 and 1975 but not in 1980. This finding of possible relative price discrimination against the SC countries does not rule out the possibility that: (1) the USSR provided absolute Soviet implicit trade subsi- dies to these countries, using average world market prices as a benchmark; (2) the SC group might have obtained better prices in trade with the Soviets than they could actually get on the world market for their marginal deliveries (purchases); or (3) prices in trade with the USSR are more predictable, if not actually more favorable on average, in the context of bilateral trade agreements than those available on the world market. The Soviet Union might have used its bilateral mo- nopoly power with clearing agreement partners to obtain favorable prices for itself, while the partners received benefits in terms of trade expansion, diversi- fication, and stability. As noted previously, however, any systematic relative price discrimination against SC countries may have had less to do with the clearing agreements than with the greater difficulty that these countries have had in gaining access to world markets, compared with oil-exporting countries, the NICs, and various Latin American and African exporters of minerals and foodstuffs. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential Finally, the argument that clearing agreements foster stability in LDC exports was investigated. As it turned out, the SC countries as a group experienced about the same degree of instability in export unit values and in the volume and value of trade with the USSR during 1975-81 as did the HC group in the aggregate. " A more refined test of instability was made for 1965- 77 using calculated "fluctuation indexes" for individ- ual SC and HC country exports, respectively, to the Soviet and world markets. The results of this test point to the stabilizing benefits of clearing agree- ments. The mean fluctuation indexes for the two country groups for nominal exports to the world market were virtually identical. HC exports to the Soviet market were more than twice as unstable, according to this index, than were HC country exports to the world. This is not surprising, given the much greater size of overall exports of these countries to the world at large. More surprising was that SC exports to the Soviet market were less than half as unstable as SC exports to the larger world market. In both of these two comparisons, the mean fluctuation indexes were statistically significantly different. Summary Strong evidence was found that, when compared with LDCs that do not have bilateral clearing agreements with the USSR, those LDCs that do have such agreements: (1) are more likely to have exchange controls; (2) trade more with the Soviets; (3) have a relatively high proportion of "soft goods" in their exports to the USSR; (4) have more diverse export structures in trade with the Soviet Union; and (5) have a record of greater stability of exports to the Soviet market, both compared with the HC group's exports to the USSR and, more importantly, compared with SC exports to the larger world market. The first three findings tend to support the conven- tional trade expansion explanation for clearing agree- ments as a second-best policy of promoting economic welfare through expanded trade in the presence of exchange controls. The next two, which deal with the diversity and stability of LDC exports to the USSR, may be related and provide plausible and empirically persuasive reasons for these countries to have entered into and/or to have clung to bilateral clearing agree- ments with the Soviets. No evidence has been found: (1) that LDCs with bilateral clearing agreements with the USSR have received preferential prices in trade with the Soviet Union compared with the prices available to the USSR's HC trade partners among the LDCs; or (2) that the clearing agreements have facilitated faster growth of LDC exports to the Soviet Union. Unfortu- nately, no relatively low-cost way could be found to test the trade predictability argument for clearing agreements. Although there are positive correlations between the existence of bilateral clearing agreements and the volume of LDC exports to the USSR, the diversity and stability of these exports, and the pro- portion of soft goods in the exports, we cannot be certain that the existence of bilateral clearing agree- ments explains these results in every case. Moreover, we have not found a correlation between changes in these measures and the termination of clearing agree- ments with the Soviet Union. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential Appendix A Methodology for Calculating Price and Quantity Indexes Paasche unit value (hereafter referred to as "price") indexes for Soviet trade with the developing countries were chosen for two reasons. First, there was an overriding need to select indexes that were method- ologically congruent with the quantity indexes em- ployed in official Soviet foreign trade statistical publi- cations. This would permit the use of results in conjunction with Soviet-produced indexes for certain analytical purposes. Second, although ideally the construction of both Paasche and Laspeyres indexes would be desirable for purposes of delimiting export and import prices and real trade trends, the highly labor-intensive nature of the project precluded calculation of both types of index-that is, all data had to be extracted from statistical publications, and disaggregated price index calculations were done by hand. While using just one index may give biased estimates of price and real trade movements, this problem is probably only poten- tially significant for the 1971-75 subperiod. Overall Paasche price indexes were calculated for both exports and imports. The overall index for period t relative to some base period, o, is defined as: ; 2 Phi hi hi Pt(o) - P?. Qt h j h' h' where P {,o, is the Paasche price index for commodity group i traded with country j, X . is the value weight for commodity group i in total trade with j in period t, Xi is the value weight for country j in total Soviet trade with LDCs in period t, and 1 / ~(X i/P'>+(o) ) would be the Paasche price index for total trade with country j in period t, or P{(.). Individual nonresidual commodity group Paasche price indexes for each country were first aggregated into a single country index according to expression (3): Pi t(o) - t(o) t(o) Only if the utilized unit value sample for CTN 3 to 9 accounted for more than 25 percent of a country's total identified CTN 3-9 exports (imports) were com- modities in this group included in this aggregation stage. Except for 1975/71 index, the exclusion of some countries' CTN 3 to 9 trade on this criterion had little impact on the aggregate value of "utilized" trade. For both exports and imports the total value of utilized,trade always exceeded 96 percent of the total value of identified trade after 1975. The second aggregation stage involved aggregating these country indexes in accordance with expression (2). For exports, two aggregate price indexes were derived: one for "identified" exports (I), constructed as above, and one for residual exports (R). The overall export price index was then calculated according to expression (4): where Pt(o) is the overall Paasche price index, Phi, and Qhl refers to the unit value and quantity, respectively, of the hth commodity traded with the jth country, and superscripts t and o refer to the current and base periods, respectively. Expression (1) may be rewritten as: Pt(o) Xjt 2; nll j i Pt(o) (2) o nl E J + PR to t(o) (4) Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/01/19: CIA-RDP86T00591 R000100050002-7 Confidential where Al and AR are the value weights for total identified and total residual exports, respectively, and P R o,. is the assumed price index for residual exports. Derivation of Laspeyres Quantity Indexes and the Terms of Trade The Laspeyres, or base-year weighted quantity index, is equal to the value index (Vt,o)) divided by the Paasche price index: 2; 2; PhjQhj V0, and where it is positive if the product is a Soviet importable and RS; j