JAPAN: WILL IT KICK THE HIGH SAVINGS HABIT?

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP86T00590R000200300001-0
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
S
Document Page Count: 
21
Document Creation Date: 
December 22, 2016
Document Release Date: 
January 18, 2011
Sequence Number: 
1
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
May 1, 1985
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP86T00590R000200300001-0.pdf1.01 MB
Body: 
Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Directorate of Intelligence 25X1 Japan: Will It Kick the High Savings Habit? EA 85-10098 May 1985 Copy 3 5 0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Directorate of Intelligence Japan: Will It Kick the High Savings Habit? This paper was prepared by Office of East Asian Analysis. Comments and queries are welcome and may be directed to the Chief, Northeast Asia Divsion, OEA Secret EA 85-10098 May 1985 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Secret Japan: Will It Kick the High Savings Habit? Information available Japanese savings have struck a raw nerve in Tokyo. Even Japanese as of 10 May 1985 proponents of fiscal stimulus-which is one possible response to US was used in this report. concerns-insist publicly that decisions affecting savings rates are purely Summary Recent calls by US officials for reduction or better domestic utilization of internal matters and not suitable topics for international debate. about one-third of the country's current account surplus stems from surplus savings, which is savings not used for domestic investment, but they still consider saving a virtue not to be tampered with lightly. This paper explores the relationship between excess savings and current account surpluses. It assesses the demographic, institutional, and policy factors that will guide Japanese savings rates-and, indirectly, current account trends-in coming years. The large share of wages distributed in the form of bonuses, the underdeveloped social security and consumer credit systems, and the availability of tax-free savings options are among the institutional factors examined. Most economists believe the household savings rate in Japan may fall during the next two decades because of the aging of the population and probable institutional changes, including the expanded availability of consumer credit. Such a scenario-which implies declining current account surpluses-is plausible, but we believe several caveats are in order: ? The savings-investment imbalance model on which the assessment hinges has several shortcomings, including a high level of aggregation that blurs the distinction between cyclical movements in the savings rate and permanent levels. ? Policy options under consideration in Tokyo, including a near-certain reduction in social security benefits, have the potential to cause house- hold savings rates to rise once again. ? Even if the personal savings ratio falls by 2 to 3 percentage points by the turn of the century, as is commonly expected, the government savings ratio may rise by nearly as much if Prime Minister Nakasone makes good on his pledge to eliminate new deficit-covering bond issues by 1990. Under this scenario, the prospects for a sharp drop in Japan's national savings rate seem to vanish and with them the likelihood of an end to pe- rennial Japanese current account surpluses. In light of this, we believe Tokyo's fiscal policy moves merit close attention in coming years. Secret EA 85-10098 May 1985 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T00590R000200300001-0 Secret High Japanese Savings: The Good News Excess Savings Fuel Trade Friction: The Bad News 1 The Savings Half of the Excess Savings Equation 2 Japanese Households: Extraordinary Savers 3 Demographic Factors: Improving With Age? 3 Traditional Frugality: Can It Survive the Younger Generation? 4 Institutional Factors: Key to High Savings? 5 Social Security 8 Retirement Age 9 Economic Variables: Of Declining Importance? 9 Overall Prospects for Personal Savings 10 Government Savings: Growing for the Rest of the Century? 10 Corporate Savings: Profit Driven 11 Putting the Pieces Together: The National Savings Rate 12 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T00590R000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Deciphering Savings Definitions and Data Economists define savings as current income not consumed in the year it was received. Statisticians assume households consume durable goods such as automobiles and TVs during the year they were bought, whereas the consumption of a newly pur- chased house is spread over a number of years. Personal savings data thus reflect additions tofinan- cial holdings and fixed assets (mainly houses) less increases in financial liabilities. The Annual Report on Family Income and Expendi- ture Survey, which contains extensive data on Japa- nese savings, calculates savings in such a manner. Although this survey is sent to over 8,000 house- holds, some economists allege the results are biased by the low response rate from low-income families. Fewer households are surveyed in the annual Public Opinion Poll on Savings published by the Bank of Japan, but this survey is unique in asking individuals why they save. The national income accounts put out by Japan's Economic Planning Agency (EPA) provide data on savings that cover all households as well as the corporate and government sectors (see figure 1). The EPA calculates the savings rate as a residual, what remains of income after consumption, and thus the figures are affected by any errors in the vast con- sumption category. Although the economic definition of savings is the same for corporations and the government as it is for households, there is no neat financial counterpart to the first two sectors' savings. Figure 1 Japan: Savings Ratio, by Sector, 1970-82 0 1970 75 80 The rate of household saving is calculated as the ratio of aggregate saving to aggregate disposable income (that is, income net of income taxes). In analyzing the national accounts, the economist em- ploys a second ratio: the ratio of household savings to aggregate GNP. vwcuuucui Corporate Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Secret Japan: Will It Kick the High Savings Habit? High Japanese Savings: The Good News In the high-growth era of the 1960s, Japan clearly benefited from the people's willingness to save-that is, to forgo consumption-at a much higher rate than' in the United States, West Germany, and the other non-Communist industrial powers (see figure 2). High savings helped fund immense investment require- ments and prevented the inflation and balance-of- payments problems normally associated with rapid economic expansion. When the first oil crisis struck Japan in 1973-74, GNP growth and investment outlays declined, but savings failed to drop commensurately (see figure 3). Officials in Tokyo have claimed since then that Japanese savings not used at home are not wasted but are available for investment abroad. Excess Savings Fuel Trade Friction: The Bad News Despite Tokyo's attempts to put surplus savings in a positive light, most economists have concluded that high Japanese savings are not the virtue they once were. Economic theory asserts that when savings exceed investment, domestic demand will fall short of its potential. Weak domestic demand, in turn, will depress import requirements and foster export drives by encouraging firms to focus on overseas markets. The push to export makes both an expansion of trade and current account surpluses far more likely. These economic relationships are expressed in terms of national income accounting as an equation that shows savings less investment as equal to the current account Figure 2 Selected Countries: Gross National Savings Rates, 1970-82 0 1970 surplus. Japanese national income data in fact gener- ally reflect this relationship, although the statistical discrepancies involved sometimes are quite large (see figure 4). This reasoning leads many economists to describe persistent Japanese current account surpluses as fun- damentally a result of excess savings. In the United States, the Japan Economic Institute, Federal Re- serve Bank officials, and numerous academics have come to this conclusion. In Japan, the Economic Planning Agency subscribes to the excess savings thesis 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Figure 3 Japan: National Savings and Investment Ratios, 1970-82 Investment 30 1970 Figure 4 Japan: Excess Savings and Current Account Balances, 1970-84 0 Current account balance IL Savings minus investment -2 1970 Publicly, moreover, Finance officials quickly rebuffed recent suggestions by Secretary of State Shultz and Federal Reserve Board chairman Volcker that Japan alter policies affecting savings and invest- ment. We also perceive some problems with drawing an oversimplified picture of the connection between the current account surplus and excess savings. In partic- ular, the aggregation involved in savings statistics masks important distinctions between the savings generated by business or economic cycles and those generated by the structure of the economy. Cyclical, unlike structural, excess savings are not the cause of persistent current account surpluses. The weakness of the yen against the dollar, abnormally high interest rates, and depressed raw material prices during recent years have substantially inflated the cyclical segment of the savings-investment imbalance. The Economic Planning Agency (EPA) estimates these factors, along with differences in the business cycle in Japan and the United States, accounted for $11 billion of the coun- try's current account surplus in fiscal year 1983 (April 1983-March 1984). The EPA believes that structural factors such as ingrained frugality were responsible for an almost permanent level of excess savings that accounted for the remaining $13 billion of the surplus. The Savings Half of the Excess Savings Equation Despite the risk of oversimplification, we believe the theoretical model that relates excess savings and the current account surplus is a valid analytical tool to assess long-term trends in Japan's current account. To use it in this manner, the equation must be broken 25X1 2oA-I 25X1 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Secret Four-Sector Investment and Savings Model Table 1 (Billion US $) Japan: Sectoral Financial Flows, 1982 In addition to breaking down the savings/investment equation into its two component parts, detailing the sectors in which each occurs improves analysis of the excess savings problem. Traditionally, the domestic economy is divided into corporate, household, and government sectors. Economic interaction with non- residents, involving imports or exports of goods, services, or financial assets, is treated as occuring in the foreign sector. Savings and investment need not balance within any one sector but must balance across sectors. Given the diverse motives for investing and saving, such balance is by no means assured when discussions are confined to the domestic economy. Financial intermediaries- primarily banks-strive to lend all available savings to investors, changing interest rates if necessary to induce individuals and companies to deposit or bor- row more. Even this may be insufficient to achieve the desired result of using all savings domestically. In this case, the foreign sector will come into the picture (see table 1). For example, if savings are in excess of domestic needs, the surplus will be shipped abroad in the form of capital outflows. A current account surplus will be the counterpart to these financial flows. down into its component parts, namely savings and investment. Examination of investment prospects is beyond the scope of this paper, but most experts foresee a slight decline in Japanese corporate invest- ment as a percentage of GNP during the next decade as the economy shifts away from capital-intensive manufacturing and into service activities. We believe the ratio of government investment to GNP also will decline because fiscal policy probably will remain tight. Although these trends would raise the amount of excess savings, many economists expect significant declines in the savings rate over the decade and thus, a net reduction in trade surpluses. We believe, howev- er, that this judgment puts too much emphasis on developments in the household sector while ignoring important trends in the corporate and government sectors: thus it may prove off the mark. Household 187 76 111 Corporate 102 172 -70 Government 37 74 -37 a Balance does not add to zero because of statistical discrepancies. b Receipt of foreign funds and goods. c Disbursement of funds and goods to foreigners. Japanese Households: Extraordinary Savers According to Japan's Economic Planning Agency, the savings rate of the household sector should drop from 19 percent of GDP in 1980 to 16 to 17 percent by 2000. Other reputable economists who have analyzed the Japanese savings scene anticipate a similar de- cline. This fairly wide consensus about future trends masks sharp disagreements among economists about the factors responsible for Japan's past savings record (see 25X1 figure 5). In the following sections we will analyze these cultural, institutional, macroeconomic, and de- mographic factors and assess how they could change in the coming years. We will also examine how policy moves by Tokyo, especially in the social security program, could affect savings motives and the course of personal savings. Demographic Factors: Improving With Age? The rapid aging of the Japanese population is the prime ingredient in all forecasts of a decline in the personal savings rate. The widely accepted life-cycle theory of savings contends that elderly people liqui- date their nest eggs to make ends meet. The theory appears applicable, although only loosely, to Japan. In each of the last 10 years, Japanese over 65 as a group Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Figure 5 Japan: Explanations for High Personal Savings in Postwar Era Legend o Viewed as valid explanation for high level of Japanese household savings Argument accepted but only with major qualifications i. Considered inappropriate explanation C E 0 Analyst N C N -- ?C 0 ' (date of research) 7 O iC C) R C 0 ?9 t3 O o O O O ~ O O Sato (1980-84) 0 O 0 0 Blumenthal (1970) O O O Mizoguchi (1970) O O O O 0 Shinohara (1959) O O O O O Komatsu (1978) O Komiya (1966) O O 0 O Economic Planning Agency (1983-84) 0 0 0 Japan Economic 0 0 Institute (1982) have not drawn down their savings, but.they have saved much less of their income than any other adult age group except those under 25. As long as this pattern continues, the increase in the over-65 age group-projected to grow from 9.1 percent of the population in 1980 to an estimated 15 percent in 2000-should result in a reduction of the savings rate. The Health and Welfare Ministry has calculated that on average each household-of which there were 34 million in 1980-will be saving $20 less annually by 2000 than would have been the case if Japan's population kept the age distribution evident in 1965. Other probable demographic changes-such as in- creased life expectancy and decreased family size- have less significant implications for savings. Future shifts in these variables, moreover, probably will be minor compared with those that have already taken place: ? Life expectancy in postwar Japan has lengthened dramatically and by 1982 was the highest in the world. Past increases in longevity probably spurred savings of the working age population to meet the expanded need for retirement income. ? The average number of children per family has decreased for several decades. With fewer children, parents have put away less money for education and marriage expenses, depressing the personal savings ratio in the process. Smaller families also have contributed literally to more room for people-the floorspace per individual has doubled over the last 25 years. This has encouraged higher spending on furniture and other consumer durables, further re- ducing savings. Their share had dropped to 44 percent by 1982. By injecting new uncertainty and insecurity into the lives of the elderly, however, other recent demograph- ic changes are pushing savings up somewhat. In particular, changes in living patterns probably are increasing the perceived need for precautionary sav- ings. For example, three-generation households ac- counted for 58 percent of all households in 1967. Traditional Frugality: Can It Survive the Younger Generation? Japanese social traditions and Buddhist religious teachings place a high value on frugality. In our view, many economists have framed their analyses of Japa- nese savings too narrowly and in the process have underestimated the importance of such cultural fac- tors. Economists have generally hesitated to give much weight to cultural factors because prewar data on savings is not conclusive. Savings data first con- structed for the late 1800s and early 1900s suggested that net private savings were generally below 10 percent of GNP and, on an annual basis, frequently negative. Although such results suggest high savings Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Secret is a relatively recent phenomenon, not a traditional virtue, the original series on savings was derived indirectly from investment data and, according to many researchers, was flawed by estimation errors and methodological shortcomings. When the series was recomputed using different depreciation assump- tions, calculations showed private savings were consis- tently above 10 percent of GNP after 1900. More- over, statistics from this period of relative poverty could not accurately measure attitudes toward frugal- ity, because there was little to save, however strong the desire. In short, we believe the link between Table 2 Japan: Motives Most Often Cited for Personal Savings 25X1 25X1 cultural values and high savings has merit. Many observers believe that, like the effect of genera- tional change in other societies, the younger Japanese generation is becoming less financially cautious and is abandoning such notions as postponement of present gratification and sacrifice for the good of the family. As young adults devote more time to leisure activities and develop their own values, these analysts foresee consumption rising as a percent of personal income. The Japanese, however, have thus far been able to raise both consumption and savings at a rapid rate because of the extraordinary growth of the economy. The Economist in 1983 pointed out that the Japanese already are "almost as rabid consumers as Ameri- cans"-while maintaining their impressive savings rate. In fact, annual savings surveys by the Bank of Japan provide some evidence that generational differences may not be as great as commonly assumed. For example, only 2.4 percent of those surveyed in 1983 said it was more important to enjoy life by boosting consumption than to save. In 1966 the comparable figure was 5.1 percent. Another survey, which asked young single women why they worked, also suggests high savings will not die with the younger generation. Nearly half of those surveyed indicated they worked largely to earn money to save. Illness or accident 36.9 42.2 36.1 34.4 Children's education 16.9 16.4 18.3 18.3 House purchase 16.8 13.9 15.4 12.3 Retirement income 12.0 13.0 11.3 15.5 8.9 7.7 5.9 6.5 8.5 6.8 13.0 13.0 times the real effect, of these individual items) Institutional Factors: Key to High Savings? Although economists usually play down the cultural underpinnings of Japanese savings, they often high- light unique institutional arrangements that help ex- plain why Japanese households save more than their counterparts in other industrialized countries: ? The large share of wages distributed in the form of bonuses, which gives people a large lump sum that they tend to bank rather than spend. ? The underdeveloped social security and consumer credit systems. ? The availability of tax-free savings options. Analysts differ on the relative importance, and some- We believe institutional factors create a favorable environment for savings. We do not, however, sub- scribe to any of the popular, one-factor, institutional explanations for high Japanese savings. In our judg- ment, such theories-which give all the credit for the country's high savings rate either to the social security system, the bonus system, or tax incentives-fail to explain adequately saving trends during the past 20 years. Tax Incentives. After World War II, the Japanese In general, Japanese seem to believe saving is still Government adopted various tax incentives to encour- important, although perhaps not as much of an imper- age savings. These included a tax exemption on ative as it once was. They continue to have a strong capital gains from sales of securities, low property desire to save in order to pay for their children's taxes, and a zero-to-low tax on interest and dividend education, to buy houses, and to provide for retire- ment (see table 2). Generational changes, we con- clude, should have only a mildly depressive effect on the savings rate. 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Figure 6 Japan: Tax-Free Savings Options for Individuals a Legend 0 Postal savings account O Small savings accounts in banks O Government bond holdings O Postal installment savings for housing Wage earner's property accumulation holdings 1960 1965 1970 1975 second requirement. Moreover, although the amount of money that can go into tax-free accounts is capped, these limits are so high as to have affected only a small number of households and, in any event, are easy to evade. Many economists point out that incentives to increase savings sometimes can have perverse effects. In the- ory, a high yield on savings lowers the cost of future consumption compared with present consumption and thereby spurs higher savings. But an individual can meet lifetime savings goals with smaller annual incre- ments when the interest paid on savings rises. A recent IMF study concluded that the relative strength of these two opposing forces depends on the age distribution of the population and the distribution of financial assets among age groups. The authors of the study ascribe the recent fall in the US personal savings rate-which coincided with introduction of such savings incentives as individual retirement ac- counts-to the large share of assets held by the elderly, who are apt to boost consumption when yields increase. We suspect Japanese assets are similarly concentrated among the elderly, but data limitations prevent a more definitive statement about parallels income. The amount each individual could place in tax-free postal savings accounts, for example, was boosted from its wartime level of 700,000 yen to 3 million yen in 1947, about $8,000 at the prevailing exchange rate. Since then, Tokyo has expanded the list of accounts qualifying for tax-free status and the limits on individual holdings (see figure 6). Every Japanese is now entitled to hold 14.5 million yen ($58,000) in tax-free accounts. Such accounts totaled $900 billion, or 60 percent of all private savings, in early 1984. Observers usually praise Japan's tax incentives for meeting the key requirements of a rational savings promotion program. Tax policy specialists have ar- gued that to increase the rewards for saving, a government must (1) avoid benefit caps that remove incentives for high-income groups to save and (2) discourage borrowing as well as encourage savings. By not permitting deductions for interest payment on consumer debt,' the Japanese tax system fulfills the with the US experience The handful of economists who have examined the relationship between Japan's tax laws and savings performance find little evidence to support the conten- tion that the country's generous savings incentives work. They have concluded that tax laws do not seem to be important in shaping the average wage earner's saving behavior. Although their findings indicate that conventional wisdom overstates the importance of tax incentives, we do not think the incentives should be dismissed as totally ineffective. The debate about the efficacy of tax incentives is far from academic. Since the late 1970s, the Japanese Government has periodically discussed tightening re- strictions on, and possibly eliminating, savings incen- tives. Tokyo has tried for years to end the widespread practice of holding multiple or anonymous postal savings accounts. Since January, individuals wishing 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Secret to open tax-free savings accounts have been required to present identification. In 1984 the Finance Minis- try recommended more drastic measures, including imposition of a uniformly low tax rate on all savings accounts. This last option would have added $2 billion to government coffers if the tax rate were set at 5 percent, but Liberal Democratic Party officials killed the proposal. the 1980s, the rate of return on such instruments before taxes probably will climb and perhaps offset Despite the failure of recent attempts to pare tax-free savings, we believe future movement on this front is likely. If incentives are cut back, savings in the upper income brackets probably will decline. But reduced yields may boost the savings rate among the elderly. Neither we nor the Japanese, however, are well positioned to assess such trends at this point because of the ongoing liberalization of Japan's financial system, which complicates analysis of interest rate movements. Since 1981, financial institutions have begun to offer individuals high-yielding instruments. As financial liberalization gains momentum through increases in the tax burden on interest income. Bonuses. Japanese workers typically save half of their semiannual bonuses, which each year normally amount to two months' salary. Several economists have pointed to the large share of wages paid in the form of bonuses as a key element in high Japanese savings. Economic theory provides some support for this idea. It contends individuals base their consump- tion on income they believe is dependable and predict- able (monthly salaries) rather than on transitory in- come (bonuses), which is therefore initially saved. Many economists doubt that the Japanese really view bonuses as transitory and unpredictable income. Bo- nus income has been less volatile than wage income since 1975, adding credence to this skepticism. The share of disposable income received in the form of bonuses, moreover, has grown and shrunk indepen- dently of savings since 1976 (see figure 7). Efforts to test the savings/bonus linkage with econometric methods suggest an accurate description of this rela- tionship lies somewhere between these extreme posi- tions. Analysis of the linkage in 1984 found that at most 3 percentage points of Japan's savings rate can Figure 7 Japan: Savings and Temporary Income, 1965-83 Bonus income Savings I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I l 1965 70 75 80 Semiannual bargaining sessions between corporate treasurers and union officials determine the share of income dispensed via bonuses. After a sharp rise in the 1960s and early 1970s, the ratio of temporary income (bonuses) to disposable income has remained quite stable-staying between 21 percent and 23 percent-since 1975, and we suspect the ratio will not move up or down by more than 1 percentage point during the next decade. Using the econometric formu- la derived from the 1984 test of the savings-bonus linkage, a shift of this magnitude would imply a change in Japan's savings rate of only 0.1 percentage point. Consumer Credit. Some observers have suggested that the Japanese save because of the difficulty of buying on credit, a legacy of the country's postwar preoccupation with industrial reconstruction. In the 1950s and 1960s, commercial banks were busy look- ing after the needs of corporate loan clients and had be attributed to the effect of bonuses Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 little desire to extend personal loans. The latter were-and still are-considered risky because con- cerns about privacy made it difficult to collect and exchange personal credit histories. As corporate fi- nancing needs diminished in the 1970s, banks took an interest in consumer business. Personal loans shot up from 0.3 percent of the loan portfolios of major commercial banks in 1965 to 9 percent in 1980. Housing loans account for almost all of the increase. Banks continue to shy away from making general consumer loans. Sarakin firms-essentially legal loan sharks-have traditionally provided this service. Pub- lic and political sentiment against these firms has, however, intensified in recent years as hundreds of suicides have been blamed on their strongarm tactics. In an effort to rein in the sarakin, the Ministry of Finance in 1978 forbade Japanese banks from extend- ing loans to these companies and in 1983 reduced the maximum lending rate charged by sarakin from 110 percent to 73 percent per annum. These changes have bankrupted many smaller sarakin, making consumer finance even scarcer. Over the next decade consumer credit should be more available even if the sarakin continue to scale down their operations. The Finance Ministry last year gave small credit associations and labor cooperatives per- mission to undertake consumer lending and recom- mended that commercial banks become more active in this field. More important, government officials have said they may draft legislation to encourage greater competition in consumer finance and to improve protection for borrowers. Better access to consumer finance should depress precautionary savings not associated with any particu- lar future consumption. The number of Japanese who said they saved primarily to ensure "peace of mind" drifted down during the 1970s, perhaps in response to improved consumer credit options (see table 2). Survey results on questions about the savings/income ratio the Japanese believed they should maintain show a similar pattern of decline punctuated by temporary savings spurts whenever external economic shocks struck home (see figure 8). These trends suggest to us that precautionary savings in Japan are influenced by economic prospects as well as by the availability of Figure 8 Japan: Personal Savings Targets, 1966-84 1 1 1966 75 80 credit. Similarly, other factors-including the lack of widespread legal precedent for individuals to seek redress for costly injuries resulting from negligence, and the perceived inevitability of natural disasters- are certain to lead the Japanese to continue to set aside money for peace of mind. Thus the reduction in the savings rate associated with an expansion of consumer credit may not be as large as is commonly assumed. Social Security. Nearly every economist who ana- lyzes Japanese household savings examines the possi- ble causal relationship between the country's high savings ratio and the small share of GNP devoted to social security. Those who see such a relationship consider the benefit levels in state-run pension schemes low and claim this forces young Japanese to amass huge amounts of savings to provide retirement income. These economists claim that the need to save 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T00590R000200300001-0 Secret for retirement while young will force up the national household savings ratio. Other economists, however, insist that benefit levels of the current system are not underdeveloped and therefore do not act, in effect, to boost the savings rate. We believe both arguments contain some truth. Not- withstanding the growth in the number of senior citizens, Japan's population is comparatively young. This is the key reason, in our view, for the small share of social security in national income. In fact, on paper, benefit levels of Japan's old age pensions are more generous than those in the West. In 1983, for exam- ple, a Japanese retiring at the age of 60, after contributing to the government plan for 30 years, could receive benefits equal to 44.2 percent of his previous year's earnings. In West Germany, the Unit- ed States, and the United Kingdom, men got an equivalent amount only after reaching age 65. The Economist points out, however, that such comparisons are somewhat misleading. The public employees' pen- sion plan that covers almost half of all Japanese workers was not established until 1961, so no one in that plan yet qualifies for the high benefit levels mentioned. Although some foreign observers continue to chastise the Japanese Government for its underdeveloped so- cial security system, officials in Tokyo worry that the system could exhaust its reserves by the turn of the century if not reformed. The Health and Welfare Ministry has proposed boosting contributions and capping benefits. The Diet passed these measures in late April. Although such action may boost the savings rate of future generations, most adults appear to have anticipated such measures, and we doubt the changes will soon alter the savings rate much. Fears about possible changes explain the recent resurgence in the "saving for old age" motive. Annual polls reveal the percent of respondents who said they saved pri- marily for old age climbed from 12 percent in 1970 to 15.5 percent last year, even though social security benefits improved substantially during that period. feature involves the traditional gap between the age at which large firms force employees to retire-55-and the age at which they are eligible for a state pension- 60. Firms generally give employees a lump-sum pay- ment to help tide them over this period, but individ- uals also are compelled to take low-paying jobs at smaller companies and to liquidate savings to make ends meet. For the Japanese, the need to fill this retirement "gap" has made target levels of lifetime savings relatively high. Some larger companies now allow employees to re- main on the job until they are 60. If this practice spreads, it could lower target savings levels. Its effect may not be as great as first appears, however, because planned changes in social security annuities would delay the onset of full benefits until age 65. Even once these changes are implemented, partial payments will still begin at age 60, allowing savings targets to fall Retirement Age. We believe economists' standard emphasis on social security slights a feature of the Japanese employment system that has profound ef- fects on the level of savings for old age income. This somewhat. Economic Variables: Of Declining Importance? In the 1980s, Japan's economy appears to be on a steady course, making it unlikely that random eco- nomic shocks will affect savings rates much. Inflation and unemployment have stayed below 3 percent for several years, and GNP growth is running at 3 to 5 percent annually. The ease with which the economy digested the 1979-80 round of oil price hikes makes us somewhat optimistic that stable noninflationary eco- nomic growth can be maintained unless an extremely severe external economic shock strikes. The volatility of the yen may prove a major exception to the stability scenario. Even in this case, however, the impact would be greater on the corporate than on the household sector because imports of raw materials- used by businesses-exceed those of consumer products. Although not expected to be particularly important in guiding savings in the future, economic variables- particularly changes in inflation and disposable in- come-figure prominently in past saving rate trends. The sharp rise in personal savings in 1973 and the subsequent gradual decline can be partly explained by Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T00590R000200300001-0 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Secret movements of these two specific factors as Japan adjusted to the 1973-74 oil price crisis and its after- math. The behavior of the Japanese in the 1970s demon- strates that their inclination to save can be directly affected by their ability-or failure-to anticipate inflationary spirals. Most analysts view the jump in inflation in the mid-1970s-from less than 5 percent in 1972 to nearly 25 percent two years later-as a prime contributor to an upswing in the savings rate. Because the inflation was unexpected, individuals had failed to shift their savings into assets, such as real estate, capable of retaining their value in the face of price increases. The spending power of their nest eggs dwindled, providing an impetus for a one-shot savings spurt to bring holdings back to the desired level. Tokyo's subsequent policies to check inflation have been successful, facilitating a return to lower savings rates. Personal savings rates have ebbed and flowed in reaction to changes in disposable income as well. Healthy increases in real per capita income in the early 1970s allowed the Japanese to boost consump- tion and savings simultaneously. But growth in real disposable income slackened following the first oil crisis as employers moderated wage increases and the government abandoned indexation of income taxes. To maintain improved living standards in the face of income restraints, Japanese households reduced their savings rates. Income trends obviously were not the only factor behind the decadelong decline in the savings rate. Institutional changes-such as increased consumer credit and later retirement-also played a role. Moreover, we believe the growing self-confidence of the Japanese increasingly will bring them to see economic reverses as temporary and to behave more calmly in maintaining consumption levels. Overall Prospects for Personal Savings The "high saver" label for Japanese has remained appropriate throughout the postwar era, but the mo- tives for household savings have changed apace with changes in the economic and institutional environ- ment. Economic factors played a prominent role in forcing personal savings rates down during the latter half of the 1970s. We believe demographic factors will become more important in coming years, with the aging of the population pushing the savings rate down. Most anticipated institutional changes, including im- proved access to consumer credit and later retirement, should further reduce savings rates. But other factors, particularly reform of the social security system, hold the potential for reversing this trend. A savings ratio decline of 2 to 3 percentage points between now and the turn of the century is quite likely, but it certainly is not the only possible outcome. And even if this projected decline occurs, Japanese households will remain high savers largely because of society's em- phasis on personal and familial responsibility that is central to the social, cultural, and historical roots of the nation. Government Savings: Growing for the Rest of the Century? Following the first oil crisis the Japanese Government switched from being a net lender of funds to being a net borrower. In other words, it began to run budget deficits. The central government deficit peaked at 6 percent of GNP in 1979. In the same year the deficit of the general government sector, which also includes local governments and the social security fund, reached 4.4 percent of GNP. The deficit in the more- inclusive general government sector usually is smaller than its central government counterpart because the social security system traditionally runs a substantial surplus. Despite these deficits, the government managed to chalk up positive savings rates throughout the 1970s (see figure 9). The distinction between current and total expenditures is central to the apparent contra- diction between budget deficits and positive savings. When calculating budget balances, total government spending is subtracted from total income. But when calculating savings, only noninvestment expenditures are considered. Japanese public works spending, 15 percent of central government outlays, is thus not counted and the result is a positive government sav- ings rate 25X1 P 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Secret Figure 9 Japan: Government Savings and the Budget Deficit, 1970-82 Net lending or borrowing -6 1970 Fully funded systems, unlike the pay-as-you-go pro- grams of the United States and West Germany, earmark the contributions (and interest on those contributions) for retirement benefits for the genera- tion making the payments. Tokyo, however, has in- vested accumulated reserves in infrastructure proj- ects, which often yield negative real rates of return. Thus, the ability to fund future benefits has decreased while potential benefit levels have been increasing. As no change in social security investment practices appears imminent, Tokyo faces a dilemma: either the present system will have to be made less generous or the government will have to subsidize the system more heavily in the future. Legislation to trim benefits somewhat has already been passed. Implementation of the new measures will reduce the need for, but will not rule out, increased official subsidization of the system. A decrease in government savings attribut- able to social security responsibilities thus remains a possibility. In recent years, Japanese policymakers have been intent on sticking to austere budgets to contain the deficits. Prime Minister Nakasone has pledged to eliminate new deficit-covering bond issues by 1990. Realization of this goal implies that government savings as a share of GNP will rise, perhaps by as much as 2 percentage points, through the end of this decade. Typical business cycle developments, such as a recession-induced fall in tax revenues or an increase in outlays for unemployment benefits, are unlikely to derail Tokyo's plan. Estimates by the OECD indicate that cyclical movements in Japan's budget in recent years have been only about one-tenth as severe as dislocations in other countries) The government's growing responsibilities for social security pose one threat to the decreasing deficit/ increasing savings scenario. Officials in Tokyo have made dire predictions about the future of the social security system. Some economic observers blame "half-prudent" government policies for these poor prospects because Japan's fully funded system theo- retically should be immune to demographic changes. The other threat to a rising savings scenario is the unhappiness of LDP leaders with tight fiscal policies. Party faction leader Toshio Komoto and prime- ministerial hopeful Kiichi Miyazawa have repeatedly called for increased public spending. They argue that stimulating domestic demand might help ease trade friction. This argument has grown in importance as US concern about the Japanese trade surplus has mounted. Stimulative action by Tokyo might also benefit construction firms, a key constituency of proponents of pump priming measures. Japanese corporate savings performance depends largely on profitability (see figure 10). For example, the ratio of corporate savings to GNP tumbled in 1975 as raw material price hikes and large wage demands slashed profits. The corporate savings ratio has been relatively stable since then, as inflation has subsided. Successful efforts to reduce the raw materi- al requirements per unit of output also played a part Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Figure 10 Japan: Corporate Savings and Profitability Ratios, 1974-82 Savings as a share of GNP Ratio of current profit to total liabilities and I I I I I 1 0 1974 75 80 Putting the Pieces Together: The National Savings Rate The contradictory trends in personal and government savings rates suggest that predictions of a falling national savings rate are premature. Moreover, pro- jecting a national savings rate based on estimates of Japan's household, government, and corporate savings rates is more than a simple additive operation. Econo- mists have long recognized that corporate and house- hold savings affect each other and that there are trade-offs between these savings rates and govern- ment savings as well: ? A jump in the national wage scale frequently in- volves a trade-off between corporate and private savings. If wage increases exceed productivity gains, profits will suffer and corporate savings will fall. But personal savings may increase if the resulting income gain was unexpected. ? An increase in taxes, which by itself boosts govern- ment savings, may in its wake cut into personal or in the improved profits and increased savings during the late 1970s. Despite these efforts, dramatic changes in Japan's terms of trade still hold the potential for pushing around the corporate savings rate. Specifically, continued softness in world oil markets could brighten corporate profit and savings pictures. On the other hand, a sharp appreciation of the yen-although of benefit to some sectors, such as petrochemicals-could shave savings rates. Removal of Japanese barriers to imports is likely to impinge on profits and savings in the future, although probably only slightly. The protection afforded do- mestic industries by current barriers may have im- proved the industries' profitability, but we believe the fierce competition among domestic firms makes it unlikely such profits are very large. Thus, the removal of trade barriers through import liberalization proba- bly will have a minimal impact on the savings rate compared with the potential fallout from sharp changes in the terms of trade and exchange rates. corporate savings rates. We believe it is too early to predict how these relationships will affect future Japanese savings rates. Prime Minister Nakasone has promised that govern- ment budget deficits can be eliminated without tax increases, but political leaders within his own party are now freely advocating tax reform. We believe tax reform may prove a precursor of tax increases. If income taxes are raised, personal savings as a share of GNP probably will decline even further than the 2 to 3 percentage points mentioned above. In this case, despite the increase in government saving, the nation- al savings rate probably will decrease. If it falls enough, the estimated 1 to 2 percent of GNP structur- al saving/investment imbalance may be erased. If such trade-offs do not occur or if consumption rather than income is taxed, however, the prospects for a sharp drop in Japanese savings rates seem to vanish and with them the likelihood of an end to perennial Japanese current account surpluses. In light of this, we believe Tokyo's fiscal policy moves merit close attention in coming years. 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0 Secret Secret Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/01/18: CIA-RDP86T0059OR000200300001-0