SOVSIM: A MODEL OF THE SOVIET ECONOMY

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
K
Document Page Count: 
52
Document Creation Date: 
December 21, 2016
Document Release Date: 
September 12, 2008
Sequence Number: 
1
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
February 1, 1979
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4.pdf2.19 MB
Body: 
Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 National Foreign Assessment Center SOVSIM: A Model of The Soviet Economy A Research Paper ER 79-10001 February 1979 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 National Foreign Assessment Center SOVSIM: A Model of The Soviet Economy Comments and queries on this unclassified report are welcome and may be directed to: Director for Public Affairs Central Intelligence Agency Washington D.C.,20505 (703) 351-7676 For information on obtaining additional copies, see the inside of front cover. ER 79-10001 February 1979 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Model Comparisons 5 Historical Error Analysis, 1965-77 6 General Tracking Record 7 Average Errors for Key Variables 8 A Short Run Forecasting Experiment 10 SOVSIM Impact Analysis, 1978-85 11 Impacts of Three Hypothetical Shifts 14 A Preliminary Assessment 15 Appendix A. Specification of SOVSIM 18 Appendix B. Variable Lists 38 Table 1. Comparison of Actual and Projected GNP Growth Table 2. Average Simulation Errors of Key Variables, 1965-77 Table 3. SOVSIM Forecasts of Key Variables for 1976 12 Table 5. Impact Analysis with SOVSIM: Effects on Selected Economic Variables 16 Appendix Tables Table Al. Equation List for the Production Block 19 Table A2. Equation List for the Consumption Block 22 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Table A3. Equation List for the Investment Block 24 Table A4. Equation List for the Capital Formation Block 26 Table A5. Equation List for the Energy Block 30 Table A6. Equation List for the Employment Block 33 Table A7. Equation List for the Trade Block 36 Table B1. Variable List for the Production Block 38 Table B2. Variable List for the Consumption Block 39 Table B3. Variable List for the Investment Block 40 Table B4. Variable List for the Capital Formation Block 41 Table B5. Variable List for the Energy Block 42 Table B6. Variable List for the Employment Block 43 Figure 1. General Flow Diagram of the Soviet Economic Model vi Figure 2. Condensed Model Structure 3 Figure 4. SOVSIM: Simulation of Private Consumption 8 Figure 5. SOVSIM: Simulation of New Fixed Investment 8 Figure 6. SOVSIM: Simulation of Net Exports of Fuel for Hard Currency 9 Figure 7. SOVSIM: Simulation of Hard Currency Net Exports of Oil 9 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 SOVSIM: A Model of The Soviet Economy Econometric models have become conventional tools for analyzing Western economies during the past decade. They provide a convenient mechanism for looking at the interactions of many factors simulta- neously and for studying the potential impacts of policies and economic events on the path the economy is expected to follow. The use of models in the study of centrally planned economies (CPEs) has lagged behind Western applica- tions, however. Western models are essentially descrip- tions of the structure and sources of demand, which in turn determine the levels of production, employment, and prices. Little of the understanding of the economic structure gained from Western modeling research can be transferred to the description of supply-oriented CPEs, where resources are more or less fully employed and use is determined by both availabilities and relative priorities. This paper describes the present version of sovsIM. The first section discusses the structure of the model in general and schematic terms. The second section reviews the performance properties of the model in historical simulations, and the third looks at the model as a short-run forecasting tool. The fourth section illustrates the use of the model in impact analysis of Soviet growth prospects to 1985, and the final section gives a preliminary assessment of our research. We have also included appendixes detailing the model's structure and listing all of the variables. sovsim is the outgrowth of a continuing effort to develop a model of the Soviet economy. The structure of sovsim reflects the fundamental production focus of a CPE. Capacity of the capital goods industries determines investment, which in turn establishes the pattern of growth in the stock of productive capital. Demographically determined employment together with the capital stock set the achievable level of production. This output is then divided among compet- ing uses based on availabilities and relative priorities, with private consumption generally taken as the residual claimant. The primary purpose of sovsim is to support studies of growth prospects for the Soviet economy, especially the influence that certain constraints on the supply side could have on these prospects over the next decade. Consequently, the structure of the model is designed to accommodate analysis of the impact of policy shifts and contingent events in areas like labor supply, energy, investment, and foreign trade. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 rn L Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO 1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 SOVSIM: A Model of The Soviet Economy sovsim is an annual model consisting of 207 equations connecting a like number of endogenous variables with 67 exogenous variables. Thirty-five of the equations involve econometric estimates of parameters; 90 of them use nonstatistical procedures to estimate struc- tural parameters and 82 are accounting identities. The general structure of the Soviet model is shown in figure 1. Since sovstm is basically supply driven, most of the model is devoted to describing resource avail- abilities and production relationships. This includes the effects of (a) investment on capital formation, (b) labor and capital on output, and (c) energy on capital utilization and foreign trade. A much smaller portion of the model is devoted to estimating the components of demand other than investment. ? Investment. The allocation of available investment resources among competing uses is set by policy decision. ? Government Spending. This group includes the level of personnel and the growth rate in nonpersonnel expenditures for defense, and the shares of administra- tion and research and development in gross national product. The model can be used to project seven groups of economic variables-the model's endogenous variables: ? Production. Outputs of 13 producing sectors are computed in terms of value added and then are summed to obtain GNP. Model Variables All projections from the model are conditioned by assumptions regarding six groups of external or exogenous variables: ? Energy. These variables include projected gross outputs of fuels and electric power, the energy allocation policy, and the capital flexibilities for each producing sector. ? Population and Manpower. Projections of the able- bodied population and the number of pensioners are inputs to the model. Participation rates and employ- ment rates, as well as the distribution of employment by sector, must also be established using outside information or by assumption. ? Weather. Weather conditions are defined by indexes of precipitation and temperature. ? Foreign Trade. Nonfuel exports to the West depend primarily on external economic conditions and are an input to the model. Energy exports to Eastern Europe are considered a function of both political and eco- nomic factors and are therefore set outside the model. Gold sales, arms sales, and new credit drawings also fall in this category. ? Consumption. Separate calculations are made for four categories of public consumption: administration and R&D, which are scaled as fixed shares of GNP; nonpersonnel defense expenditures, which are com- puted from an exogenous growth rate; and personnel defense expenditures, which are the product of as- sumed manpower and imputed wage rates. Private consumption is determined as the residual claimant on output after deductions are made for public consump- tion, investment, and foreign trade. ? Investment. The model computes investment in each of the 13 producing sectors plus housing and capital repair. ? Capital Formation. New additions to the stock of productive capital, retirements, and the gross stock of productive capital are estimated for each producing sector. ? Energy. Nominal requirements and actual deliveries of fuels and electric power are computed for each producing sector. Utilization rates of capital and hence the effective or active capital stock are also estimated. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 ? Employment. This group includes the civilian labor force and the level of employment in each sector. ? Trade. Exports and imports are calculated sepa- rately for trade with Communist, hard currency, and other countries. Debt, debt service, grain imports, and net exports of fuels are for hard currency also estimated within the model. Model Structure in Condensed Form The structure of sovsiM has been condensed into a set of 19 equations to facilitate discussion of the functional relationships among model variables (see figure 2). The variables and parameters appearing in these equations are also defined in figure 2. This way of reviewing the model focuses on the primary endog- enous linkages; the full specifications of the model equations are given in appendix A. The model variables are listed in appendix B: ? Production. There are constant-returns-to-scale Cobb-Douglas production functions for each nonenergy producing sector (equation 1). Value added in the energy sectors is scaled from gross output, which is exogenous for these sectors. GNP is obtained by summing value added in the 13 producing sectors (equation 2). ? Consumption. Government expenditures (equation 3) include exogenous defense spending and an endog- enous component scaled from the level of GNP. Private consumption (equation 4) is calculated as the residual claimant of GNP. ? Investment. The supply of capital goods available for domestic investment is the residual of deliveries of machinery and construction output to final demand, after deductions are made for deliveries to defense, exports, consumption, and capital repair (equation 5). Equation 6 distributes new fixed investment to each producing sector and housing with shares set outside the model. ? Capital Formation. Net additions to the productive capital stock are estimated from past investment and assumed depreciation rates (equation 7). Identity equations then link capital stock to the previous year's capital stock and net capital formation (equation 8). ? Employment. The labor force is estimated from the able-bodied population and participation rates (equa- tion 9). Total employment (equation 10) depends on the labor force and employment rates, and sector employment levels (equation 11) follow from the total employment and labor allocation shares. ? Energy. Equation 12 estimates nominal demands for oil, gas, coal, and electric power in each consuming sector from the capital stock and energy-use coeffi- cients tied to the capital stock of the given sector. Actual deliveries (equation 13) are determined by a combination of nominal requirements and assumed allocation policy. Equation 14 calculates domestic energy residuals by subtracting domestic deliveries from gross domestic output. Depending on its sign, the residual indicates either a capacity for net exports or a need for net imports. Equation 15 calculates the fraction of sector energy requirements, in terms of standard fuel units, actually met by deliveries. To- gether with an elasticity of active capital with respect to energy input, this fraction determines the rate of capital utilization and thus the active capital stock in each sector (equation 16). Any shortfall in meeting nominal domestic requirements for energy leads to a reduction in capital utilization. The degree of reduc- tion for a given shortfall varies by sector depending on the value of the capital elasticity and the relative contribution of the type of energy in short supply to the particular sector's energy consumption. ? Foreign Trade. Net exports of fuels to hard currency countries (equation 17) are the difference between the domestic energy residuals and exogenous net exports to Communist and other countries. Net exports of fuels to hard currency countries, along with other variables that represent sources of hard currency, feed into a calculation of the hard currency import capacity (equation 18), which in turn drives imports from hard currency countries (equation 19). If these imports fall below a specified floor, domestic energy use is reduced by reducing eig. and energy exports are increased (or energy imports are reduced) until sufficient import capacity exists to meet the import minimum. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 Energy 12. Ei,I=K.Xdi.l 13. Ei.J = Ei.l X ei.l 14. RJ=QJ - Ei.J- Efd,l 15. Di=(I EiJXhl)/(2; E..JXhl) j j 16. Ki=K.Xi(I - giX(I - D,)) Foreign Trade 17. EHJ = R1 - EC1 18. MH, _ I EHJ + T j 19. MH = f (MH,, MH) Ni Employment in sector i ds POP Able-bodied population Qj Gross output of energy type j Rj Residual of domestic production of energy type j after deduction for domestic deliveries Rk Capital repair T Net earnings of hard currency (other than through trade in fuels) and net credit drawings es Xi Value added in sector i icy Xk Value added in machinery and construction sectors p Participation rate ri Depreciation rate of capital in sector i t Share of output devoted to administration and research and development. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 Figure 2 Condensed Model Structure A. Equations Production Capital Formation Energy 1. X, = f (K,, N, ) 7. KF1=f(II,I(-1),,r,) 12. E,j =K1Xd,,j 2. GNP=EX, 8. K1=K,(-1)+KF,(-1) 13. E,,j = E.,j X elj i Consumption Employment 9. LF = p X POP 14. RJ=Qj -E,,;-Efd.J 3. G=tXGNP+DF 15. D, = (E E1 j X h,) /(I E, 1 X h ) 4. C=GNP-I-G-(Ex-M) 5. I=aXXk - Ck - Gk - EXk - Rk 6. I,=b,XI 10. N=erXLF 11. N,=c,XN , , j j j 16. K1= K,X,(I -g1X (1 -D,)) Foreign Trade 17. EHj = Rj - ECG 18. MH,=ZEHj + T j 19. MH = f (MH,, MH) C Private consumption G Government expenditures N; Employment in sector i Ck Expenditures on consumer durables Gk Defense expenditures on capital goods POP Able-bodied population D; Deliveries of fuels and power to sector i as a GNP Gross national product Qj Gross output of energy type j percent of nominal requirements I Total investment Rj Residual of domestic production of energy DF Defense spending I; Investment in sector i type j after deduction for domestic E.,j Nominal requirements of energy type j in K; Nominal capital stock in sector i deliveries sector i K , Active capital stock in sector i Rk Capital repair E Deliveries of energy type j to sector i KF1 Net capital formation in sector i T Net earnings of hard currency (other than Efdj Deliveries of energy type j to final demand LF Civilian labor force through trade in fuels) and net credit ECj Net exports of energy type j to Communist M Imports drawings and other countries MH Imports from hard currency countries Xi Value added in sector i EHj Net exports of energy type j to hard currency MR Minimum imports from hard currency Xk Value added in machinery and construction countries countries sectors Ex Exports MHc Hard currency import capacity Exk Machinery exports N Total employment C. Parameters a Ratio of deliveries to final demand of machin- e1, Deliveries of energy type j to sector i as a p Participation rate ery and construction to value added in these percent of nominal requirements r; Depreciation rate of capital in sector i sectors er Employment rate t Share of output devoted to administration and bi Share of total investment going to sector i Elasticity of active capital with respect to research and development. c; Share of total employment in sector i input of energy in sector i d .,j Input of energy type j per unit of capital in hj Units of standard fuel per unit of energy type j sector i Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Data Sources The empirical relations in sovsim were estimated using a data base covering 1960-77. While some data series covering the 1950s were available, the 1960-77 period was the longest for which a consistent data set could be compiled. Data sources included official statistical publications of the USSR, national income accounts estimated by the Office of Economic Research (OER), and input-output tables reconstructed by the Foreign Demographic Analysis Division (FDAD) of the US Department of Commerce. Output in the Production Block was described by sector-of-origin valued-added indexes of Soviet GNP accounts developed by OER. The corresponding OER estimates of GNP end-use accounts were the primary basis for estimating the Consumption Block. Data for total investment, new fixed investment, net additions to livestock and capital repair in the Invest- ment Block came from OER end-use accounts for GNP. In addition, various issues of the official Soviet economic handbook-Narodnoye Khozyastvo SSSR (Narkhoz)-were the source of the sector investment used to establish sector shares in new fixed invest- ments. Capital stock data for the Capital Formation Block came from OER indexes of the fixed capital stock of the USSR. Estimates of imported capital were compiled by Green and Levine ' and depreciation rates were estimated by Green.' The Energy Block uses a combination of time series and intersectoral transactions data. Production figures for fuels and power were taken from the Narkhoz, and the amount of fuels in foreign trade from the official Soviet foreign trade handbook. Sector shares in the allocation of fuels and power available for domestic use were estimated for 1972 from a preliminary recon- struction of the 1972 Soviet input-output table in producers' prices. These figures for 1972, along with estimates of apparent consumption (gross production minus net exports) and sector capital stock for all years, were used to estimate changes in the allocation pattern over time. ' See Donald W. Green and Herbert S. Levine, "Soviet Machinery Imports," Survey, Spring 1977-78, p. 114. 2 See Donald W. Green, "Capital Formation in the USSR, 1959- 74," Review of Economics and Statistics, February 1978, p. 40. Data for the Employment Block came primarily from FDAD projections and compilations.' The official Soviet foreign trade handbook was the major source of trade data for the Foreign Trade Block and OER estimates were used for hard currency debt and drawdowns of credit. Model Comparisons As a model of a centrally planned economy, sovsim bears little resemblance to conventional econometric models of Western economies. The impressive econometric research effort in the West has focused on giving empirical content to an essentially Keynesian view of Western macroeconomies. This means giving great attention to the determination of the structure and level of effective demand and little concern for real constraints on growth. Obviously, the latter issue-real constraints on growth-is the core of any analysis of Soviet growth prospects. This requires giving much greater attention to descriptions of production and resource availability than to competing uses for the output produced. This was true of the earliest efforts by Niwa ? to construct a very small model of the Soviet economy and continues with both sovsim and the SOVMOD series of large-scale econometric models developed by the combined efforts of SRI International and the Wharton Econometric Forecasting Associates (SRI-WEFA). 5 Both sovsim and SOVMOD are driven by a series of sector production functions. Each uses Cobb-Douglas specifications rather than more complex forms because the statistical basis for rejecting the simpler form is, at best, weak at the sectoral level. In other areas, though, the specifications differ in critical ways. 'See Stephen Rapawy, Estimates and Projections of the Labor Force and Civilian Employment in the USSR: 1950-1990, Foreign Economic Report No. 10, September 1976. ' Haruki Niwa, "An Econometric Analysis and Forecast of Soviet Economic Growth" in P. J. Wiles, The Prediction of Communist Economic Performance (Cambridge, 1977). ' The original model is given in Donald W. Green and Christopher 1. Higgins, SOVMOD I: A Macroeconometric Model of the Soviet Union (Academic Press, 1977). Later versions of SOVMOD have been described in working papers published by SRI-WEFA. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Most of these specification differences reflect a differ- ence in the fundamental analytical objectives and assumptions underlying the development of the models. The SRI-WEFA research has assumed that any regularities in the decisions of planners that could be isolated from historical data were a preferred basis for projecting Soviet growth prospects. Consequently in certain parts of SOVMOD, important roles are played by estimated trade-offs between alternate patterns of resource use, based on indexes of planners' behavior. The sovsim research has focused, instead, on the roles that resource constraints play in shaping the pattern of Soviet growth and has assumed that past trade-off responses of the planners are not necessarily the preferred basis for judging the future. As a result, the specification of sovsim generally has less behavioral content but more effectively takes resource availabil- ities into account in projecting Soviet growth. These differences are especially pronounced in four areas: ? Investment. sovsim constrains current new fixed investment to equal the available output of the machinery and construction sectors and allocates it among sectors by share trends, or shares determined exogenously. The SRI-WEFA approach looks at investment from a behavioral perspective that tries to link realized investment with resource competition with defense, but does not limit realized investment to the investment that could be carried out with the resources available. ? Energy. sovsim was developed to examine the effects of shifts in resource supplies, especially energy re- sources, on growth potential. The sovsim specification, therefore, gives explicit consideration to sector de- mands for energy and links energy supplies to both domestic production and foreign trade possibilities. This integration of energy into the model is missing in SOVMOD. ? Foreign Trade. Soviet imports from the West depend on Soviet hard currency import capacity, which in turn is limited by Western credits and hard currency export earnings. The sovsim specification, by explicitly link- ing Western imports to import capacity, import capacity to fuel exports, and fuel exports to a set of overall fuel balances, more fully integrates trade into Soviet growth analysis. ? Employment. The sovsim specification of employ- ment is essentially an accounting framework based on outside projections of population, participation rates, and sector employment shares. The SRI-WEFA speci- fication is a much more ambitious attempt to estimate the influences on urban-rural migration and the impact this process has on overall employment. It fails, however, to impose realistic upper bounds on Soviet participation rates, which are already the highest in the industrialized world. Under certain conditions, this can lead to an upward bias in long-term growth analysis. sovsim is then much more eclectic than conventional econometric models, even of the Soviet Union. It tries to deal with the real constraints on Soviet growth while reflecting the rather underdeveloped theoretical un- derstanding of the process of central planning and the behavior of the planners who shape it. Historical Error Analysis, 1965-77 One measure of the performance of an econometric model is its ability to reproduce the historical (ob- served) growth pattern of key variables. This test, however, assumes knowledge of some data-such as nonfuel exports to the West, weather indexes, and defense spending-not available in making a forecast. Moreover, future structural changes could alter underlying functional relationships. Historical error analysis should therefore be considered only in con- junction with other tests in establishing the usefulness of sovsim in the analysis of Soviet growth potential. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 USSR: Comparison of Actual and Projected GNP Growth Figure 3 Table 1 I I I I I I I I I I I 1 1 1965 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 General Tracking Record The historical and simulated paths of GNP growth in 1965-77 are compared in figure 3. The model projec- tions follow the historical record very closely, never deviating by more than 1.5 percent from the official figures. A more demanding comparison is that between actual and projected growth rates (table 1). The projected growth rates are reasonably close to historical figures-the correlation coefficient between them is 0.54-and the direction of year-to-year changes is correctly projected in 10 out of 12 cases. Private consumption and new fixed investment are shown in figures 4 and 5. Both figures again show a close match, but the simulation errors in a given year are in opposite directions. This reflects the model's specification of private consumption as the residual claimant on GNP. Since GNP is simulated with little 1965 6.8 7.6 1966 6.4 7.0 1967 5.2 4.0 1968 6.1 5.8 1969 3.0 4.9 1970 7.7 5.2 1971 4.5 3.9 1972 1.9 2.7 1973 7.2 6.3 1974 4.1 9.1 1975 2.2 2.8 1976 4.0 4.0 1977 3.6 5.1 error, when investment is overestimated, consumption as the residual use of GNP must be underestimated and vice versa. Nonetheless, the projection error in neither variable seems to be biased since the projec- tions are not consistently above or below actual values. The value of net exports of oil, gas, and coal to hard currency trading partners is a key foreign trade variable calculated in the model. Since these exports are estimated as residuals in the fuels balance equa- tions, while gross production of fuels and exports to other countries are exogenous, the ability of the model to track hard currency fuel exports depends on the ability to project domestic use of fuels. Figure 6 shows that the model accurately tracks the value of hard currency fuel exports, including the rapid acceleration that occurred after 1973. This indicates the general validity of the underlying energy balance computations in the model. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 SOVSIM: Simulation of Private Consumption Figure 5 IIIIIIIIIIIII I I I I I I I I I I I I I The dominant variable feeding into the calculation of net exports of fuels to hard currency countries is net exports of oil. The results depicted in figure 7 show that the changing Soviet capacity to export oil to the West was captured by the model, although the historical shift was sharper than the simulations indicated. Nonetheless, there is no particular bias in the projection errors over the full period. Average Errors for Key Variables The model's ability to replicate history can be best measured by computing average simulation errors for 1965-77. No single error index can describe the predictive power of the model reliably. Three conven- tional indexes, however, taken together give a rounded picture of how well the model projections match the historical data: Figure 4 SOVSIM: Simulation of New Fixed Investment ? Mean Percentage Error (MPE) 6-The MPE will be smaller to the degree that annual or individual errors are of opposite signs and therefore offsetting. ? Mean Absolute Percentage Error (MAPS) 7-This error index is useful because it counts individual errors without regard to their signs and therefore does not allow for offsetting effects. If the absolute value of the MPE is close to the MAPE value and annual percentage errors are generally of similar size, annual errors tend to be of the same sign, perhaps signifying some built-in model bias. 6 MPE = I E (Estimated-Actual)X 100 -t N Actual ' MAPE = 1 (Estimated - Actual I X 100 N t Actual Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO135OR000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 SOVSIM: Simulation of Net Figure 6 Exports of Fuel for Hard Currency SOVSIM: Simulation of Hard Currency Net Exports of Oil Figure 7 IIIILIIIIIIII ? Root-Mean-Squared Percentage Error (RMSE) The RMSE like the MAPE, ignores the signs of individual errors. However, an individual error re- ceives more weight in calculation of this index accord- ing to the square of its size. This index has preferred statistical properties but can easily become distorted. One or two historical figures lying far from the values projected by the model can cause large RMSE values. The average simulation errors for key production, end- use, and foreign trade variables are summarized in table 2. The main characteristic of the production and end-use variables themselves is that they all show a strong time trend. With the exception of agricultural I E (Estimated-Actual)X 100 N Actual output, they are not especially volatile, but they tend to grow fairly steadily from year to year. The statistical equations used in projecting the output variables generally exhibit extremely good fits. Consequently, average simulation errors tend to be small for this group of variables. Of the 12 production and end-use variables listed in table 2, seven have RMSEs of less than 3 percent and only one has an error larger than 5 percent. The trade variables are fundamentally more volatile than the production and end-use variables. Part of the explanation for this is that trade depends on conditions outside the control of Soviet policymakers. Further- more, those aspects of trade subject to control can change dramatically from one year to another as Soviet trade policies vary. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 Average Simulation Errors of Key Variables, 1965-77 Table 2 shows that average simulation errors for the trade variables tend to be considerably larger than those for the production and end-use variables. None- theless, exports of oil and total fuels to the West, nongrain imports from the West, and Communist exports and imports are tracked fairly well over the historical period-their average errors are generally less than 20 percent. The trade balances show larger errors because they are calculated as residuals of balance relations in which the residual is much smaller in absolute terms than the variables involved in the calculation. As a consequence, small percentage errors in these variables can result in large percentage errors in the balance residuals. Just as in Western economies, prediction of Soviet trade balances probably will remain one of the areas of projection most prone to error. Comparison of the RMSEs and MAPEs for the balance variables also shows that aberrations in one or two years are a major source of distortion in the RMSE index. Mean Error Mean Absolute Error Root- Mean- Squared Error Gross National Product -0.1 0.8 1.0 Total Consumption -0.3 2.0 2.3 Total New Fixed Investment 0.2 2.0 2.4 Actual Agriculture Output -0.5 3.6 4.3 Consumer Goods Output -0.2 2.5 3.1 Industrial Materials Output -1.8 2.3 2.7 Other Industry Output -0.6 1.5 1.7 Chemicals Output 5.5 8.0 9.0 Construction Output -0.6 1.5 1.8 Machinery Output 1.8 3.2 3.6 Transport and Communi- cations Output -3.1 3.3 3.5 1.4 Hard Currency Balance of Trade - 13.1 74.4 Nonoil,Nongrain Imports -4.4 12.0 18.7 Hard Currency Net Exports of Fuel 9.1 20.0 28.0 Communist Balance of - 156.9 165.8 316.6 Communist Nonfuel Imports 0.0 3.7 6.8 Balance of Trade With World -143.5 158.8 392.8 Hard Currency Net Exports of Oil 6.1 Hard Currency Net Exports 17.7 69.4 of Coal Hard Currency Net 103.9 Exports of Gas The relatively large average-percentage error in projected gas exports primarily reflects the small absolute errors in estimating gas exports in the early years of the simulation period when they were practi- cally negligible. Although less pronounced, a similar situation exists in the case of coal exports. In both cases, simulation errors in the later years were substantially below the average. A Short Run Forecasting Experiment Historical simulations can give an unrealistic impres- sion of the strengths or weakness of an econometric model. They presume the existence of some data-for both exogenous variables and structural parameters- that would not actually be available when using the model to look into the future. They also place in a favorable light model specifications that are peculiar to the historical period but that are not necessarily the preferred way of viewing more general, long-term trends. As a second test of sovsIM, we have constructed a short run forecasting experiment free of these defects. We use data for 1960-75 to forecast Soviet economic growth in 1976 and 1977, using projections of the Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 exogenous variables for 1976-77 based on growth rates of preceding years. Comparison of the simulation results for 1976 and 1977 with actual values for the endogenous variables suggests the order of magnitude of forecasting errors one might expect in using sovsIM as a short run forecasting tool. It also highlights the parts of the model in which accuracy of exogenous data is crucial to forecasting performance and tests the general stability of the underlying structural specifications. As part of the analysis, the net forecast error was partitioned into (a) an error reflecting the approximate nature of the model's structure as a description of the Soviet economy and (b) an error reflecting the approximate nature of the exogenous variables that were extrapolated based on their 1960-75 values. All endogenous variables were first forecast for 1976 and 1977 using parameters estimated from the full histori- cal data through 1977 and actual observations of exogenous variables also through 1977. Comparing forecasts based on full historical information (through 1977) with actual observations for the endogenous variables in 1976 and 1977 gives the "model error," the forecasting error due solely to the model's approximate specification. The "net error," the difference between actual observations and forecasts using only data through 1975, reflects both exogenous data error and "model error." Therefore, the "data error" can be estimated as the difference between the "net error" and the "model error." In general, if the "model error" and the "data error" have the same signs, they reinforce each other. If not, they partially offset each other. Results for 1976 For 1976, the projections of the model (table 3) were more accurate for the production and end-use variables than for the trade variables, but this is to be expected for reasons already discussed. Most of the errors are in the range of 1 to 3 percent. In the group of production and end-use variables, only value added in chemicals exhibits a net error greater than 3 percent in the experimental forecast. The estimate falls short of the actual figure because of,roughly equal negative errors due to model specification and data error. The branch output forecasts show no consistent bias; the net error in 1976 GNP is only 0.1 percent. For 1976, neither the error due to model deficiencies nor the error due to data errors consistently dominates as the source of forecasting error. Results for 1977 A comparison of net percentage errors for 1976 and 1977 (tables 3 and 4) indicates that the projections of the simulated forecast tend to be further off the mark in 1977. The difference is most pronounced for the trade variables. Six of the 12 production and end-use variables have greater net percentage errors in 1977 than in 1976 compared with seven out of the 11 trade variables. Moreover, the differences in net percentage errors between the two years are much greater for the trade variables than for the production and end-use variables. In 1977 the model error is generally lower than the data error (both measured in absolute values) for the trade variables. This means that forecasts of external events affecting trade are a more severe constraint than model structure on the ability of the model to make accurate projections more than a year ahead. Nonetheless, even for forecasts two years beyond the 1960-75 period covered by the data base used in this experiment, net errors were generally only about 1 percentage point worse for production and end-use variables and around 10 to 15 percentage points worse for most trade variables than the one-year forecast errors. The 1977 results also vividly show that a model will never be able to predict the kind of dramatic turnaround in Soviet trade balances that occurred in that year. As the error decomposition indicates, this failure in 1976-77 is essentially a reflection of trade variable sensitivity to shifts in behavior that are not anticipated in either the underlying model parameters estimated for 1960-75 or the crude extrapolations of exogenous data also based only on preceding years. SOVSIM Impact Analysis, 1978-85 All sovsiM projections depend on assumptions regard- ing the exogenous variables and key coefficients in the model. These variables and coefficients define the internal and external economic, political, and techno- logical environments. Domestic and foreign policies or economically significant events can be described by combinations of these variables and coefficients. The reaction of sovsiM to hypothetical policy changes or Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 SOVSIM Forecasts of Key Variables for 1976 Gross National Product 483.4 482.9 0.1 -0.5 0.6 Total Consumption 273.9 277.9 -1.4 0.2 -1.6 Total New Fixed Investment 108.6 111.7 -2.7 -2.5 -0.2 Actual Agriculture Output 69.6 68.7 1.3 1.1 0.2 Consumer Goods Output 62.3 61.2 1.8 -0.5 2.3 Industrial Materials Output 25.6 25.9 -1.3 -3.1 4.4 Other Industry Output 8.0 8.1 -0.4 -1.5 1.1 Chemicals Output 12.2 12.9 -5.7 -3.3 -2.4 Construction Output 33.9 33.9 -0.2 -1.7 1.5 Machinery Output 62.1 63.7 -2.6 -0.7 -1.9 Transport and Communications Output 46.9 45.6 3.0 0.4 2.6 Trade and Services Output 72.2 73.1 -1.2 -0.7 -0.5 Million US $ Hard Currency Balance of Trade -5,106.0 -5,516.0 -7.4 -18.7 11.3 Nonoil, Nongrain Imports 11,416.0 12,051.0 -5.3 -13.4 8.1 Hard Currency Net Exports of Fuel 4,708.0 4,683.0 0.5 -7.2 7.7 Communist Balance of Trade 1,014.0 1,787.0 -43.3 -17.1 -26.2 Communist Nonenergy Exports 14,969.0 16,114.0 -7.1 -5.1 -2.0 Communist Nonfuel Imports 19,642.0 19,652.0 -0.1 -2.7 2.6 Balance of Trade With World -4,119.0 -3,797.0 8.5 -19.2 27.7 Million Metric Tons 36.7 41.2 -11.0 -10.9 -0.1 11.1 8.8 26.8 -3.0 29.8 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 SOVSIM Forecasts of Key Variables for 1977 Gross National Product 504.3 500.2 0.8 1.0 -0.2 Total Consumption 284.5 289.2 -1.6 3.2 -4.8 Total New Fixed Investment 114.1 115.0 -0.8 -2.3 1.5 Actual Agriculture Output 70.6 70.4 0.3 8.6 -8.3 Consumer Goods Output 64.8 63.3 2.4 -0.5 2.9 Industrial Materials Output 26.7 26.4 1.4 -1.0 2.4 Other Industry Output 8.2 8.2 0.3 -0.8 1.1 Chemicals Output 12.9 13.6 -5.3 -3.3 -2.0 Construction Output 35.3 34.7 1.6 -0.9 2.5 Machinery Output 66.1 67.5 -2.1 -0.6 -1.5 Transport and Communications Output 50.5 47.4 6.5 2.8 3.7 Trade and Services Output 74.6 76.1 -1.9 -2.0 0.1 Million US $ Hard Currency Balance of Trade -5,354.0 -2,431 120.2 9.7 110.5 Nonoil, Nongrain Imports 13,291.0 10,229.0 29.9 -3.4 33.3 Hard Currency Net Exports of Fuel 6,260.0 6,180.0 -1.3 -17.9 19.2 Communist Balance of Trade 1,174.0 2,718.0 -56.8 -38.9 -17.9 Communist Nonenergy Exports 16,733.0 16,950.0 -1.3 0.2 -1.5 Communist Nonfuel Imports 22,739.0 20,368.0 11.6 5.3 6.3 Balance of Trade with World -4,255.0 93.8 -4,636.0 -1,337.0 -3,259.0 Billion Cubic Meters 13.8 14.8 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 external events described by shifts in particular variables and parameters can be extremely useful in evaluating the path of the economy's adjustment to such changes as well as in validating the model itself. Such projections are called conditional forecasts. Baseline Case The potential impact of particular events or policy changes is conventionally assessed by comparing two model projections, a reference case and a case incorpo- rating the given changes in terms of shifts in param- eters or exogenous variables. As a reference case, we developed a baseline projection of Soviet growth in 1978-85 that assumes a continuation of present Soviet policies and no change in the trends of critical variables like participation rates and weather: ? Exports of Fuels. Net exports of oil, coal, and gas for hard currency are the residual from domestic produc- tion after domestic deliveries and net exports to Communist countries are covered. Net exports of oil to Communist countries increase to 95 million metric tons in 1980 and stay at this level through 1985. ? Other Hard Currency Trade. Hard currency exports of commodities other than fuels grow at 9 percent a year in real terms, and new drawdowns of medium- and long-term credits increase at a real rate of 5 percent a year. Both rates are consistent with recent trends. A floor was placed on the value of hard currency imports other than oil and grain; their share of GNP in any year was not allowed to fall below one- half the 1977 figure. ? Allocation of Fuel Supplies. Sectors producing fuels and power, and public and private consumption are given priority when oil deliveries are insufficient to meet the demands of all sectors. They are always allocated 100 percent of their nominal oil demand. ? Production of Fuels. Oil production peaks at 590 million metric tons in 1980 and falls to 500 million metric tons in 1985. This is at the high end of the production range we have estimated.9 Gas output grows at 6 percent a year and coal production at 2 percent. ? Defense Spending. The real value of Soviet defense expenditures rises at an annual rate of 4 percent- consistent with the trend over the last decade. ? Population and Employment. Total population grows at 1 percent a year, but growth in the able- bodied population slows dramatically through 1985 because of demographic factors. Agriculture's share of the labor force falls from 24 percent in 1978 to 20 percent in 1985, while participation rates essentially remain at their current high levels. In the baseline case, these assumptions lead to a Soviet oil shortage in the 1980s and a deceleration in Soviet growth rates. The average annual rate of GNP growth falls to 2.5 percent in 1981-85, more than 1 percentage point below the average annual growth in 1976-80. The Soviets would export oil to the West until 1981, after which they would become net importers of Western oil. Soviet net oil exports to the world would remain positive through 1985, however, because of our as- sumption that exports to Eastern Europe and other Communist countries continue at a level of 95 million metric tons in 1981-85. Impacts of Three Hypothetical Shifts To illustrate how sovsIm can be used to make conditional forecasts, we have resimulated the model over the 1978-85 period after changing-one at a time-three of the assumptions underlying the baseline solution: ? Labor force participation rates rise by 1985 by 1 percentage point for the able-bodied population and by 2 percentage points for pensioners. The increase in participation rates implies that the Soviets make greater use of incentives and manpower regulations than assumed in the baseline to improve the tight labor situation over the next decade. ? Western economic growth is slower than the baseline case assumes for the next decade, and therefore nonfuel exports to hard currency countries grow at only one-half the assumed baseline rate. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 ? Oil exports to Eastern Europe fall from 95 million metric tons in 1980 to 45 million metric tons in 1985, as the Soviets attempt to relieve economic pressures associated with oil shortfalls in the early 1980s. The more aggressive manpower policy would have an immediate positive effect on GNP that would cumu- late over the period (table 5), eventually adding a little less than 1 percentage point to GNP by 1985. The gains in private consumption would amount to about half the gains in GNP-implying a stable share for consumption in final demand. The small increase in oil exports possible in the early years comes from the excess of new domestic production over new domestic demand resulting from the extra labor. The extra hard currency imports are simply a reflection of the extra hard currency earnings resulting from these oil ex- ports. The improved labor situation would have little impact on the hard currency and oil problems projected for 1982-85. As table 5 shows, hard currency imports in those years would not change from their baseline levels, which are the minimum allowed under the baseline conditions. The extra GNP during 1982-85 comes from two sources-primarily the in- creased labor supply and to a much smaller extent added energy production from domestic sources. Slower Western growth would cut hard currency imports immediately because of the lower-than- baseline Soviet import capacity. The early effects of trade on GNP are passed through very slowly because of the small role that imported capital goods play in the total Soviet economy. The large negative impact in the later years is predominantly due to a reduced ability to finance oil imports from the West, which is reflected in lower capital utilization rates. Imports would be restricted to almost 20 million metric tons below baseline levels in 1985 because of the need to devote increasingly scarce hard currency to keep other imports from the West at least at minimum levels. With other oil trade fixed, this means higher Soviet net oil exports by the same amount. These shifts in trade would improve the Soviet trade balance and simulta- neously reduce the level of private consumption compared with baseline levels. Consequently, con- sumption as the residual end use would absorb a larger share of the projected GNP fall-about two-thirds- than the projected 50-percent share in the GNP increase in the previous case where trade balances were essentially stable between the baseline and resimulation. In the last case, it was assumed that Soviet oil exports to Eastern Europe would fall only after pressures on oil supplies began to mount in the early 1980s. The potential impact of this policy shift is substantial-it would add more than 1 percent to GNP by 1985- because it would directly ease oil shortages, projected in the baseline for the later years. The emergence of oil shortages would be delayed, as the hard currency import constraint in the baseline is now binding in only the last three years. The shifts in the pattern of trade are now more complicated, however. When the Soviets are projected in the baseline case to have sufficient hard currency earnings to finance practically all import needs-as in 1981 and 1982-the oil released from export to Eastern Europe is used domestically in place of oil imports from the West and the hard currency savings are diverted to finance more nonoil imports from hard currency countries. Net oil exports to the world would then be unchanged from baseline levels. When, in- stead, the Soviets are projected to be under a hard currency constraint in the baseline-as in 1983-85- the oil diverted from Eastern Europe is used along with baseline projections of Western oil imports to ease internal oil shortages. In these years, imports of Western oil and other goods would be unchanged from the baseline, but net Soviet oil exports to the world would fall by the amount of reduced oil exports to Eastern Europe. Our experience with sovslM-in historical analysis, in forecasting experiments, and in impact analysis- indicates that a Soviet macroeconometric model of this kind can be a reliable and useful tool in studying Soviet growth prospects. It provides a consistent framework for investigating the effects of alternative sets of analytical assumptions and for examining the linkages between sets of interrelated issues. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Impact Analysis With SOVSIM: Effects on Selected Economic Variables Changes Due to Higher Labor Participation Rates GNP (Billion 1970 Rubles) 0 1.0 1.9 2.5 3.5 4.2 5.1 6.2 Consumption (Billion 1970 Rubles) 0 0.6 1.0 1.3 1.9 2.2 2.7 3.3 Net Hard Currency Oil Exports (Million Metric Tons) 0 0.4 0.7 0.9 0 0 0 0 Net Oil Exports (Million Metric Tons) 0 0.4 0.7 0.9 0 0 0 0 Hard Currency Imports Other Than Grain and Oil (Billion US $) 0 0.1 0.2 0.2 0 0 0 0 Changes Due to Slower Western Growth GNP (Billion 1970 Rubles) 0 0 0 0 -1.8 -2.3 -2.7 -3.1 Consumption (Billion 1970 Rubles) 0 0 0 0 -1.1 -1.4 -1.6 -1.8 Net Hard Currency Oil Ex- ports (Million Metric Tons) 0 0 -0.1 -0.2 10.7 13.4 15.2 17.0 Net Oil Exports (Million Metric Tons) 0 0 -0.1 -0.2 10.7 13.4 15.2 17.0 Hard Currency Imports Other Than Grain and Oil (Billion US $) -0.2 -0.5 -0.8 -1.3 0 0 0 0 Changes Due to Lower Oil Exports to Eastern Europe GNP (Billion 1970 Rubles) 0 0 0 0 0.3 4.8 6.5 8.1 Consumption (Billion 1970 Rubles) 0 0 0 0.1 0.3 3.0 4.1 5.1 Net Hard Currency Oil Exports (Million Metric Tons) 0 0 0 10.0 18.1 0 0 0 Net Oil Exports (Million Metric Tons) 0 0 0 0 -1.9 -29.0 -39.3 -48.0 Hard Currency Imports Other Than Grain and Oil (Billion US $) 0 0 0 1.5 2.9 0 0 0 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Applications of sOvsIM to growth studies should help improve our understanding of both the long-term prospects for Soviet economic development and the methods we use to analyze them. Therefore we tend to focus on the use of sovsim in the next phase of our research. This means applying the present version of the model to analysis of trends in such areas as labor supply, energy, and foreign trade, and their impacts on Soviet growth potential in the 1980s. These applica- tions studies should serve as a comprehensive test of the usefulness of a Soviet macroeconometric model in improving our perceptions of the range of Soviet growth options, Soviet flexibility in the face of expected shifts in resource growth patterns, and the general interrelatedness of issues facing Soviet policymakers. In the long run, however, the usefulness of sovsim can be enhanced by further development, especially in several specific areas. Production functions play a crucial role in any Soviet model and sovsim now con- ventionally employs a straightforward Cobb-Douglas specification. Considerable research has been done since 1970 on the application of constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production functions to highly aggregated Soviet data. A potentially fruitful area for future research is the application of CES or other more complex specifications to the description of Soviet production on a sector basis. These changes would be aimed at an improved depiction of the substitutability of capital and labor, and its variation across producing sectors. However, applications of more sophisticated techniques to highly disaggregated data are certain to be plagued by greater data shortcomings than aggre- gate analysis, because of the lack of offsetting error possibilities. Such problems are not fatal to disaggregated estimates of the less sensitive Cobb- Douglas function, but they will become important in estimating more sensitive functional forms for highly disaggregated sectors. There are also several other areas of sovsim that demand further development. More detail must be given to the description of production in the agricul- tural sector. At least a partial behavioral foundation must be established for projections of private consump- tion. It may be possible to explain changes in participa- tion rates through changes in real incomes. Also, the process of adjustment to intersectoral disequilibriums, which is the focus of current SRI-WEFA research, may be amenable to simulation within the framework of a macroeconometric model and will be incorporated in our own work if present experiments prove successful. Of course, any modeling effort uses much outside information to describe processes not embodied within the model itself. In sovsIM, questions of labor supply and demographic patterns, improvements in total factor productivity at the sector level, and gains in energy conservation are all handled outside the model, but they obviously have a strong bearing on the character of any analysis conducted with the model. Improvements in our understanding of such issues is a necessary ingredient in upgrading the quality of Soviet growth analysis in general. It is unlikely, though, that the near future will see much of an improvement in our ability to analyze the planning process.explicitly. Ideally a Soviet macromodel should endogenize the reaction functions of the planners and thus provide a description of the planning process itself, including the effects of plan on performance and the feedbacks of performance on future plan formulation. The failure of Soviet macroeconometric models to meet this requirement has been the center of recent criticisms of current approaches. 10 Given our limited theoretical understanding of planner decisionmaking, the sharp discontinuities possible in planning behavior, and the insufficient set of historical precedents that exist, it is not likely that a purely statistical solution to modeling planning behavior will be found. A second best procedure may be combin- ing, within a series of analyses or conditional forecasts, the use of a macroeconometric model with sound judgment on how underlying policies might change as decisionmakers adapted to events projected by the model. It is this approach that we will continue to follow in our research. 10 See Richard Portes, Macroeconometric Modelling of Centrally Planned Economies: Thoughts on SOVMOD I (Harvard Institute for Economic Research, May 1978). - Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO135OR000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 This appendix describes the structural equations in sovsIM. The equations are divided into seven blocks, corresponding to the groups of endogenous variables discussed in the condensed version of the model. Brief discussions of each block and tables listing the equations are provided below. For regression equa- tions, the RZ statistic is adjusted for degrees of freedom while t-statistics appear in parentheses below esti- mated parameters. Production Block (Table Al) There are 14 endogenous variables describing sector production levels in this block and they are influenced by eight exogenous variables. Value added in agricul- ture is estimated in a two-step procedure. First, normal agricultural output is estimated based solely upon land, labor, and capital inputs. Then, actual output is estimated from normal output and current indexes of temperature and rainfall. Production functions for agriculture and the eight nonagriculture, nonenergy sectors were estimated using a constant-returns-to- scale' Cobb-Douglas specification, implying an elas- ticity of substitution among inputs equal to unity. Other production-function specifications gave gener- ally inferior statistical results. The nonagriculture production functions were estimated using generalized least squares (GLS) since results using ordinary least squares (OLS) showed strong autocorrelation of the residuals. ' The constant-returns-to-scale assumption requires only the capital coefficient to be estimated statistically. The labor coefficient is simply one minus the capital coefficient and it does not have an associated t-statistic. Because we expect over the next decade substantial reductions from historical levels in the marginal products of labor and capital in the energy sectors, we have not used production functions estimated from historical data for these sectors. Value added in the energy sectors is calculated instead from scale relation- ships that apply value-added weights to exogenous indexes of gross output. Gross outputs of the energy sectors are exogenous to the model, but provision exists for computing marginal changes from reference output levels in response to marginal shifts in labor and capital inputs to these sectors. The capital stocks for the machinery, chemicals, and oil-producing sectors are separated into domestically produced and imported components, although it was not possible to estimate separate coefficients for each type of capital. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08S01350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDPO8SO135OR000100110001-4 Equation List for the Production Block Equation Number Dependent Variable Equation R 2 Durbin- Watson Statistic Estimation Method 1 Normal agriculture output log (normal agriculture output) = - 5.08 + 0.01 X time + 0.738 (-16.07) (12.82) X log (agriculture employment) + 0.111 0.974 1.10 Ordinary Least Squares (15.98) Actual agriculture output actual agriculture output = normal agriculture output 0.969 + 0.140 X precipitation index + 0.519 (78.71) (5.10) (2.52) 0.699 1.32 Ordinary Least Squares Construction output log (construction output) _ - 4.49 + 0.779 X log (construction employment) (-54.77) + 0.221 X log (capital in construction sector) (17.14) 0.978 1.59 Generalized Least Squares 4 Transport and communications output log (transport and communications output) = -1.87 + 0.173 X log (transport and 0.989 2.04 Generalized Least Squares (-15.11) communications employment) + 0.827 (31.74) X log (capital in transport and communications sector) 5 Trade and log (trade and services output) = 0.958 0.72 Generalized services output Least - 5.33 + 0.836 X log (trade and services employment) Squares (-69.19) + 0.164 X log (capital in trade and services sector) (11.97) 6 Industrial log (industrial materials output) = 0.995 1.15 Generalized materials Least output - 3.10 + 0.538 X log (industrial materials employment) Squares (-40.71) + 0.462 X log (capital in industrial materials branches) (30.36) Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDPO8SO135OR000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Table Al (Continued) Equation List for the Production Block Equation Dependent Equation R 2 Durbin- Estimation Number Variable Watson Statistic Method 7 Consumer goods output log (consumer goods output) _ - 2.97 + 0.635 X log (consumer goods employment) 0.975 1.39 Generalized Least Squares (-17.84) + 0.365 X log (capital in consumer goods branches) (12.73) 8 Machinery output log (machinery output) _ - 2.57 + 0.452 X log (machinery employment) 0.988 1.65 Generalized Least Squares (-16.63) + 0.548 X log (domestic capital in machinery branch (20.08) 9 Chemicals output log (chemicals output) = - 2.92 + 0.507 X log (chemicals employment) (-29.07) + 0.493 X log (domestic capital in chemicals branch (23.65) 0.987 1.28 Generalized Least Squares 10 Other industry output log (other industry output) = -4.22 + 0.690 X log (other industry employment) (-41.13) + 0.3 10 X log (capital in other industry) (16.87) 0.982 1.00 Generalized Least Squares I I Gas output Gas output = 1.798 X(gross gas output 197.9 12 Oil output Oil output = 7.549 X (gross oil output 353.4 13 Coal output Coal output = 4.945 X gross coal output 624.1 14 Electric power Electric power output = 7.268 X (gross electric power output output ` 740.9 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Consumption Block (Table A2) The consumption block consists of nine endogenous variables and is affected by 11 exogenous variables. GNP is computed as the sum of value added in the 13 producing sectors. Total private consumption is calcu- lated as the residual claimant on GNP once the other end uses (investment, public consumption, and the balance of trade) are deducted. Reduced-form equa- tions that allow for both demand and supply influences were estimated for per capita food consumption and per capita durable goods consumption. In both equa- tions the demand influence is represented by national income per capita. The supply influence in the food consumption equation is lagged agricultural output per capita, and in the durables equation it is machinery output per capita. Unallocated production as a GNP residual is estimated as a function of time and serves to close the GNP accounts on a sector-of-origin basis. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Equation List for the Consumption Block Equation Dependent Equation R 2 Durbin- Number Variable Watson Statistic Gross national Gross national product = product industrial materials output + machinery output + chemicals output + consumer goods output + other industry output + gas output + oil output + coal output + electric power output + construction output + transport and communications output + trade and services output + agriculture output + (unit wage of military X military manpower) 2 Total Total consumption = consumption gross national product - (total new fixed investment + capital repair + livestock investment) - (government administration share + government R&D share) X gross national product - (nonpersonnel defense spending + (unit wage of military X military manpower)) - (0.001 X (ruble balance of trade) + invisibles ruble/dollar ratio X earnings on invisibles except official transfers) - end-use residual 3 Consumption Consumption per capita = per capita total consumption population 4 Food log (food consumption per capita) = 0.995 1.77 consumption per capita -0.937 + 0.652 (-16.96) (37.56) X log(gross national product %\ population J + 0.132 X log/actual agriculture output(.,) (3.57) 1\ population 5 Food Food consumption = consumption food consumption per capita X population 6 Durables log (durables consumption per capita) = 0.987 0.56 consumption per capita - 1.69 + 0.868 X log gross national productl (-2.15) (1.69) population + 0.857 X log achinery output (2.67) ` population 7 Durables Durables consumption = consumption durables consumption per capita X population 8 Nonpersonnel Nonpersonnel defense spending= defense (I + growth in nonpersonnel defense spending) X nonpersonnel defense spending(_,, 9 Sector-of-origin Sector-of-origin residual = 0.997 2.36 residual 3.00 + 1.81 X time (4.18) (56.43) Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Investment Block (Table A3) Investment calculations involve 19 endogenous variables and are affected by four exogenous variables. New fixed investment is set by the supply of capital goods and does not reflect demand considerations. Deliveries to final demand from construction and machine building are estimated by scaling value-added figures that are derived from production functions. Scaling coefficients are calculated from Soviet input- output data. The claims of defense, capital repair, consumer durables, and exports are deducted from gross construction and machinery output to give net domestic production available for new fixed invest- ment. In addition, the calculation of construction available for new fixed investment involves an adjust- ment to maintain consistency between the estimated new fixed investment component of the GNP accounts and the estimated output of machinery and construc- tion available for investment.' Total new fixed invest- ment is then distributed among the 13 producing sectors and housing according to given shares reflect- ing historical trends or assumed policies. Investment models using endogenous share calculations have also been investigated, but they have a weak statistical basis and generally lead to unacceptable projections in long-run growth analysis. 2 Construction and machinery output data are not fully consistent with independent figures on investment. To maintain correct accounting in the model, we have developed an adjustment applied to the construction series, where consistency is established with the smallest distortion of original sector output figures. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Equation List for the Investment Block Equation Dependent Equation Number Variable Machinery for Machinery for new fixed investment = new fixed investment 1.238 X machinery output - (0.5 X capital repair Durbin- Watson Statistic 2 Investment Investment adjustment factor = 0.893 0.98 adjustment factor 0.877 + 0.0122 X time (32.40) (10.03) 3 Construction Construction for new fixed investment = for new fixed investment 2.751 X investment adjustment factor X construction output - (0.5 X capital repair + military construction) 4 Total new Total new fixed investment = fixed investment machinery for investment + construction 3 for investment +E (net imported capital formation in the ith sector i=1 + 0.06 X imported machinery in the ith sector) 5-17 New fixed New fixed investment in the ith sector = investment in the ith the ith sector share of total new fixed investment sector X total new fixed investment 19 New fixed New fixed investment in the housing sector = investment in the the housing share of total new fixed investment housing X total new fixed investment sector 24 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Capital Formation Block (Table A4) Capital formation in sovsiM is described by 32 endogenous variables and is influenced by one exoge- nous variable. This process is concerned with the increase in the productive capital stock that comes from commissionings of new plants, which in turn depends on expenditures on capital goods. The stock of productive capital in a particular producing sector during a given year is computed from an accounting relationship involving last year's stock and last year's net formation of productive capital. Net capital formation equations are estimated for each producing sector based on assumed depreciation rates and invest- ment levels in the last two time periods. A plan cycle variable representing the Soviet tendency to start a wide range of capital projects during the early plan years and to push projects to completion in the later years was found to be a significant explanatory variable in the gas and coal sectors and was therefore also included in those net capital formation equations. The estimated net capital formation equations reflect two factors: the general failure of Soviet capital stock census data to be fully consistent with data on annual investment expenditures, and the variable gestation periods and patterns of unfinished investment across producing sectors. For the machinery, chemicals, and oil sectors, distinctions are made between capital produced domestically and capital imported from hard currency and other Communist countries. For im- ported equipment, we simply assume a one-year average lag between the import of capital goods and their inclusion in the stock of productive capital. Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Equation List for the Capital Formation Block Equation Dependent Equation R 3 Durbin- Number Variable Watson Statistic Capital in the Capital in the agriculture sector = agriculture sector net capital formation in the agriculture sector t_11 + capital stock in the agriculture sector t_,1 2-10 Capital in the Capital in the ith sector = ith sector net capital formation in the ith sector t_1l + capital stock in the ith sector (_,) 11-13 Domestic capital Domestic capital in the jth sector = in the jth sector 14-16 Imported capital Imported capital in the jth sector = in the jth sector net imported capital formation in the jth sector t_~1 + imported capital in the jth sector t_1l 17 Net capital Net capital formation in the agriculture sector formation in + 0.05 X capital in the agriculture sector = the agriculture sector / investment in the agriculture sector 0.0312 + 0.796 X (`+ investment in the agriculture sector t_~) (0.05) (17.86) 2 18 Net capital Net capital formation in the construction sector + 0.968 2.22 formation in 0.06 X capital in the construction sector = the construction sector / investment in the construction sector 0.0348 + 1.11 X + investment in the construction sector t_~1 (0.26) (22.19) 2 19 Net capital Net capital formation in the transport and communications sector + 0.025 0.926 1.99 formation in X capital in the transport and communications sector = the transport and communications investment in the transport and communications sector sector 1.11 + 1.03 XC investment in the transport and communications sector t_il (2.01) (14.19) 2 20 Net capital Net capital formation in the trade and services sector + 0.02 X 0.866 1.57 formation in capital in the trade and services sector = the trade and services sector / investment in the trade and services sector - 0.873 + 1.01 X 1\+ investment in the trade and services sector t_I1 J (-0.72) (10.22) 2 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Approved For Release 2008/09/12 : CIA-RDP08SO1350R000100110001-4 Table A4 (Continued) Equation List for the Capital Formation Block Equation Dependent Equation Number Variable Durbin- Watson Statistic 21 Net capital Net capital formation in the industrial materials branches + 0.845 2.18 formation in 0.045 X capital in the industrial materials banches = the industrial materials investment in the industrial materials branches branches -0.459 + 0.679 (+ investment in the industiral materials branches (-0.99) (9.40) 2 22 Net capital Net capital formation in the consumer goods branches 0.904 1.38 formation in + 0.05 X capital in consumer goods branches = the consumer ( investment in consumer goods branches goods branches 0.209 + 0.935 X1} investment in consumer goods branches(_,) (0.85) (12.29) \ 2 23 Net domestic Net domestic capital formation in the machinery branch + 0.05 0.901 2.36 capital X domestic capital in the machinery branch = formation in investment in machinery goods branch \ the machinery 1.03 + 0.985 X( investment in machinery goods branch(_1~ J branch (2.34) (12.08) 24 Net imported Net imported capital formation in the machinery branch + 0.06 capital X imported capital in the machinery branch = formation in n nc V .,.