THE ATLANTIC COUNCIL OF THE UNITED STATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC STUDIES INSTITUTE OCCASIONAL PAPER

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7
Release Decision: 
RIFPUB
Original Classification: 
K
Document Page Count: 
49
Document Creation Date: 
December 22, 2016
Document Release Date: 
September 1, 2011
Sequence Number: 
4
Case Number: 
Content Type: 
MISC
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7.pdf2.25 MB
Body: 
_._._ . __ . ~ ~. 1 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 The Atlantic Council of the United States and the International Economic Studies Institute Occasional Paper Western and Eastern Economic Constraints on Defense The Mutual Security Implications by Timothy W. Stanley with an Appendix on: Soviet Economic Constraints to Year 2000 by John P. Hardt Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 THE ATLANTIC COUNCIL OF THE UNITED STATES The Atlantic Council of the United States, now in its 26th year, is a national and bipartisan center for the formulation of policy recommendations on the problems and opportunities shared by the democracies of Western Europe, North America, Japan, Australia, and New Zealand. Its purpose is to promote understanding of major international security, political, and economic issues; foster informed public debate; and make recommendations to the Executive and Legislative branches of the U.S. Government and to the appropriate inter- national organizations. The Council is anon-governmental, educational organization, supported by tax-exempt contributions from corporations, foundations, labor unions, and individuals. Directors of the Atlantic Council (listed on the back cover of this draft paper) are private individuals with internationally recognized experience in public and private endeavor, including government, finance, business, labor, academia, the law, and the media. They volunteer their time and expertise to help forge links of policy and purpose among the developed democracies, and to improve relations with the developing nations and the communist countries. The Council's policy papers are the products of working groups and com- mittees composed of fifteen to sixty persons carefully chosen from among Coun- cil members and others representing a broad and bipartisan range of opinion and experience. The conclusions and recommendations of these papers repre- sent the consensus of these specialized groups, and include dissenting comments of individual members in footnotes or an appendix as appropriate. The papers are addressed to decision-makers and decision-preparers in government and the private sector, and are also disseminated to academic leaders, the news media, and other interested persons in this country and abroad. Certain analyses and studies prepared as background papers for discussion by the Atlantic Council's Working Groups are published as Atlantic Council Occasional Papers. These papers do not necessarily reflect the collective views of the Atlantic Council; the positions taken remain solely those of the author. They are made available to a wider public because of their outstanding merit and timely interest. The Atlantic Council of the United States 1616 H Street, N.W. Washington, D. C. 20006 Telephone: (202) 347-9353 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 TIC INTERNATIONAL ECON011DC STUDIES INSTITUTE The Institute was established in 1974 to cazry out long range analyses of issues in its broad field which are of concern to Americans. It is a publicly supported, non-profit and tax exempt research and educational organization under Sec- tion 501(c)3 of the Internal Revenue Code. Contributions and inquiries are welcomed from all sources. The Institute is affiliated with the International Economic Policy Associa- tion, founded in 1957 as anon-profit business-supported civic league, which is tax exempt under Section 501(c)4. Information about its programs are available upon request. Both organizations' boards of directors are listed in- side the back cover. The Institute and the Association have jointly undertaken a special two-year program on "American Business and the International Economy". This will involve studies by expert outside authors as well as the IEPA-IESI staffs. They will focus on American business and what is necessazy to maintain and improve U.S. well-being and competitiveness in the world economy. A central question will include the needed industrial base (beyond high-tech and the service sec- tor) and the appropriate trade, investment, exchange rate and tax policies. The interactions of American national security with economics, including trade com- petitiveness and the U.S. domestic budget and balance of payments deficits, will also be addressed. The overall program will seek, through factual rather than ideological analysis, to correct some of the widespread public misimpressions, including government, Congress, academia and the media, about the seriousness of U.S. international economic problems. The final result will be a book published early in 1988 which will integrate these interrelated topics. The International Economic Studies Institute 1400 Eye Street N.W., Suite 510 Washington, D.C. 20005 Telephone: (202) 898-2020 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 WESTERN AND EASTERN ECONONIIC CONS ON DEFENSE 'TIS 11ZUTtJAL SEC~JRiTY IlV~LICATIONS by Timothy W. Stanley With an Appendix, "Soviet Economic Constraints to the Year 2000" by John P. Hardt Washington, DC Fall 1986 Draft published by the Atlantic Council of the United States and the International Economic Studies Institute Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Additional copies of this Occasional Paper Western and Eastern Economic Constraints on Defense: The Mutual Security Implications may be ordered at $6.00 prepaid from the Atlantic Council or the International Economic Studies Institute. The Atlantic Council's Brochure, "Issues and Options, 1986-87" is available gratis upon request. Copyright ?1986 by The Atlantic Council of the United States, Inc. and the International Economic Studies Institute ,..~..,~.. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 .,...~, Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 TABLE OF CONTENTS Page Preface by Andrew J. Goodpaster ............................. vii Foreword and Overview by Ronald L. Danielian and George M. Seignious II .............................................. viii I. Introduction ................................................ 1 II. The United States ........................................... 3 III. NATO Europe .............................................. 7 IV. The Soviet Union and the Warsaw Pact ....................... 10 V. Conclusions ................................................ 13 Table I .................................................... 15 Table II .................................................... 17 Table III ................................................... 18 Appendix: "Soviety Economic Constraints to Year 2000" by John P. Hardt ................................................. 19 About the Authors .......................................... 37 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 PREFACE This paper, "Western and Eastern Economic Constraints on Defense: The Mutual Security Implications" by Timothy W. Stanley, and its Appendix, "Soviet Economic Constraints on Defense to Year 2000" by John P. Hardt, grew out of the Atlantic Council's ongoing Policy Projects on "U.S. Policy towazd the Soviet Union: ALong-Term Western Perspective, 1985-2000" which I chair jointly with Walter J. Stoessel, and "Defending Peace and Freedom: Towazd Strategic Security in the Yeaz 2000", under the co-chairmanship of Brent Scowcroft and R. James Woolsey. The two policy projects aze an integral part of the Council's overall National Security Policy Program. The two Working Groups are neazing completion of their work, and anticipate publishing Policy Papers in early 1987. Because of the substantive merit of this working paper, and the timeliness of the issues raised, both Working Groups recommended it be published immediately as part of the Council's Occasional Papers series, conjointly with the International Economic Studies Institute. The Occasional Papers aze offered as timely complements to the Policy Papers and scholazly books published by the Atlantic Council as a result of its policy working groups. Unlike the Policy Papers, which reflect the collegial views and recommendations of specific working groups, the views expressed in the Occa- sional Papers remain the sole responsibility of the individual authors. Like the Policy Papers, the purpose of the Occasional Papers is to enhance public discus- sion and debate of the most important international issues. Over the last several yeazs, it has become strikingly appazent to us, and to the elected and appointed officials, military and civilian policymakers and policy planners, businessmen, and academicians who have worked with us, that there exists a high degree of interdependence among the military, societal, and economic components of national security, and that these three aspects have traditionally been treated independently of each other, too often as if in competi- tion with each other. There is a need for a sustained and comprehensive examina- tion of the interrelationships among our military security requirements and our economic security and our socio-political well-being. We urgently need prac- tical means of replacing policy isolation, competition, and conflict with policy coordination. As a step toward meeting that need, the Council has undertaken a new program on "Integrating Economic Policy and Security Policy." This paper represents the first substantive contribution to that effort. In that light, we are particularly pleased to publish this draft jointly with the International Economic Studies Institute, which is collaborating with us on the new program. The Atlantic Council expresses its continuing gratitude to those contributors whose financial support has made the National Security Policy Program possi- ble. The Program was initiated with the support of a major challenge grant from the J. Howard Pew Freedom Trust, and matching grants from the McDonnell Douglas Foundation, Exxon Corporation, Exxon Education Foun- dation, the Texas Association of the Atlantic Council, the International Eco- nomic Studies Institute, and the Greve Foundation. Andrew J. Goodpaster Chairman Atlantic Council of the United States Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 FOREWORD AND OVERVIEW Much has been and is being written about U.S.-Soviet relations and arms control; and also about U.S. and world economic problems. What is relatively unique about this joint Occasional Paper is that it attempts to assess some of the interactions between defense (and arms control) and economics. The Atlantic Council has in progress two nearly completed policy papers draw- ing upon the deliberations of two expert and broadly based working groups, as noted in the preface. The Council leadership, including most of the co- chairmen and rapporteurs of the two groups as well as the author of this Occa- sional Paper, held consultations with NATO Parliamentarians, i.e., MP's from various European allies, in Luxembourg in late May of this year, which were followed by discussions in Moscow with leaders from the Institute of USA and Canada Studies, the Foreign and Defense Ministries and the Central Commit- tee of the Communist Party. Originally commissioned as working papers for those two Council groups, the combined efforts of Dr. Stanley and Dr. Hardt seemed so timely to current developments in East-West relations that it was deemed a useful public service to make them available in this form. Ultimately, it is hoped, these preliminary analyses will become the basis for further Atlantic Council Policy Papers under the aegis of a Standing Committee on Economic Policy which will guide on- going work on integrating economic policy and security policy in the light of future international developments. The International Economic Studies Institute, together with the International Economic Policy Association, with which it is affiliated, has published many analyses over the yeazs of U.S. and foreign economic problems and policy issues, particularly as they relate to U.S. business and its competitiveness. In addition the Institute has done considerable analysis of the interactions between inter- national economics and national security. More and more, the impact of U.S. budgetary and balance of payments deficits upon national security, and vice- versa, is coming to the fore. The Institute therefore is pleased to collaborate with the Atlantic Council in addressing these interactions, in this Occasional Paper, and in ongoing work. The basic thesis presented here is that, although U.S.-Soviet relations seem destined to consist of a mixture of competition and cooperation, and neither side will, for economic reasons alone, adopt policies or military postures which it sees as harming its national security interests, the economic constraints now operating on both sides may create genuine windows of opportunity, through added incentives to reach otherwise desirable (and verifiable) arms control regimes. These could not only lower the risks of major conflict but also the defense burden for both, and for their respective NATO and Wazsaw Pact allies. With regard to the United States, Dr. Stanley's analysis finds that under the most likely long term economic growth scenarios and the most realistic assess- ment of congressional willingness to fund current defense priorities, the coun- try is unlikely to reach the ambitious strategic and force goals set by the Ad- ministration. If so, the United States will have to choose between either unde- sirable or unworkable economic policies, and major re-thinking and restruc- turing of its basic strategy and force posture for the future, preferably in com- bination with major new East-West arms control possibilities. Similar ad- justments may be needed in NATO. On the Soviet side, Dr. Hazdt documents the analogous constraints and dilem- mas facing General Secretary Gorbachev and his colleagues, although they take Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 the form of allocation of real resources rather than budgets. Options include a possible shift to a pragmatic, reduced defense burden approach. This would have to encompass updated assessments of the international environment fac- ing the Soviet Union, greater political leadership over defense requirements and programming, and economic constraints on defense stemming from the high priority being given to modernizing the civilian economy. Dr. Stanley concludes that if either side sees the other's constraints as a poten- tial vulnerability to be exploited, i.e. in zero-sum terms, a goal of mutual and stable security by the year 2000 may be even more elusive. But if both perceive their common problems as opportunities, in a positive sum context, then much could be accomplished at the planned U.S.-Soviet Summit and in subsequent negotiations. As emphasized in the preface, the views contained in Occasional Papers are those of the authors alone, and do not necessarily reflect the collegial views of the Atlantic Council, its working groups, or those of the International Economic Studies Institute as an organization. Nevertheless, we consider that the concepts and data in this paper are suffi- ciently constructive, thought-provoking, and timely that we are pleased to publish them jointly now. Ronald L. Danielian George M. Seignious II Vice President President International Economic Studies The Atlantic Council of Institute (and President, The United States International Economic Policy Association) Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Western and Eastern Economic Constraints on Defense: the Mutual Security Implications* by Timothy W. Stanley President, International Economic Studies Institute I. Introduction This paper concentrates on the period between now and the year 2000, although more immediate economic and budgetary crises, including the effects of the Gramm-Rudman-Hollings (GRH) legislation, are also considered. It deals primarily with the United States and the Soviet Union and features an analysis of the situation in the USSR contributed by Congressional Research Service Sovietologist John Hardt. (See Section IV and the Appendix.) To a limited ex- tent the analysis also touches the analogous problems of key allies of the super- powers in NATO and the Warsaw Pact. Relations among three separate but interacting variables complicate the search for strategic stability and affect U.S.-Soviet relations as they influence mutual threat perceptions and the economic consequences of the armaments programs of both sides. One useful, if admittedly simplified way of illustrating these relationships is shown in the two back-to-back right triangles diagrammed below. Side a, the altitude, is composed of the mutual threat perceptions, taking the "threat" as military capabilities discounted by intentions, which dominate U.S.-Soviet and, to a lesser extent, NATO-Warsaw Pact relations. The base of the triangle (b) represents the armaments programs in part generated by these mutual threat 'The writer wishes to express his appreciation for the helpful comments made by members of the Atlantic Council's Strategic Stability and U.S.-Soviet Relations working groups during his presen- tations to these groups in the spring of 1986. The paper also draws upon consultations held by an Atlantic Council delegation which met with NATO parliamentarians in Luxembourg on May 25-27, and discussions held with senior Soviet officials in Moscow on May 28-June 1, 1986, as well as upon insights gained at a U.N. conference of experts from East and West in Italy in April 1986. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 perceptions and includes the arms control desiderata resulting from the vulnerability of both sides to technologically sophisticated nuclear and conven- tional weapons of great power, including potential applications in space. The hypotenuse of the triangle (c) represents the economic costs and conse- quences and potential economic constraints of both sides' national security pro- grams. The drawing is intended to be illustrative of the elementazy principle that strategy (or threat evaluation and response) military programs, and defense budgets (and their limitations) aze all interrelated. No quantitative compazisons are intended. Every math student knows that the square of the hypotenuse is equal to the the sum of the squares of the other two sides, represented by the formula a2 + b2 = c2. However, in the world of politics these relationships may or may not apply. Three basic viewpoints were expressed during the discussions of the Atlantic Council Working Groups on U.S.-Soviet Relations and Strategic Stability. One view takes the "a", or perceptions of threat to national security as a given; it in turn drives the related armaments programs, limited only by arms control imperatives and possibilities. The hypotenuse is then treated simply as a derivative, representing economic consequences which must simply be ac- cepted, given the high priority both superpowers and their major allies assign to national security as they perceive it. According to a second view, the mere existence of large military establishments, bureaucracies and interlocking industrial relationships generates its own momentum in the arms race. Thus, quite frequently, the "threat" is cut to fit the desired pattern of the military-industrial complex. Scholazs of Soviet affairs note that while economic incentives and constraints may play a somewhat smaller role in the USSR than in the West, the bureaucratic and political power, as well as allocation priorities determined by the armaments elements of Soviet society are of great importance. They reinforce the ideological "threat" from the West, at once stimulating the military capabilities that the West has developed in response, and justifying still larger Soviet bloc efforts. This interaction may be particularly relevant during the current subterranean struggles as General Secretary Gorbachev seeks to consolidate power and impose his priorities on the Soviet bureaucracy. A third view is that under present political-economic conditions, the economic hypotenuse of the triangle is becoming an independent variable, which at any shorter length, will alter the dimensions of the altitude and the base of the triad for both the Western and Eastern alliance systems. This paper will explore the ramifications of this third viewpoint. ,~..~..,...,.,~..~.. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 II. THE UNITED STATES The United States has recently undergone the largest ever peacetime buildup and modernization of its defense establishment, initiated in President Carter's last year of office following the Soviet invasion of Afghanistan, and continued and expanded under President Reagan. In part this development reflects a perceived lag in the U.S. strategic posture vis-a-vis that of the Soviet Union, which continued its own long-term buildup even while the U.S. had unilaterally capped its strategic offensive forces in quan- tity, if not quality. Moreover, U.S. modernization and readiness were lagging. It also reflects a disillusionment with the progress and prospects for arms control. Some, including former arms limitation advocates, maintained that the actual effects have been at best neutral, if not indeed harmful, in ratifying (and thus encouraging) ever more and better nuclear weaponry on both sides. Arms control opponents claimed that the process has failed to impede Soviet efforts to gain superiority even as it hindered U.S. efforts to redress a deteriorating military balance. Also involved, of course, are the Reagan Administration's political-ideological campaign to shrink the role of civilian government activities, its staunch anti- communist, anti-Soviet outlook (though its more extreme rhetoric has now been muted) and its conviction of the need for expanded defense efforts to catch up to a perceived higher level of threat from the Soviet bloc. Under the Reagan Administration, from FY 1981 through 1991 as projected by OMB, there will have been no real increase in nondefense government spend- ing because both the FY '81 and '91 figures are $555 billion in constant FY '82 dollars). But there will have been a 60 percent real increase in defense, which will have grown from 23 percent to 33 percent of total government (including off-budget items) outlays, while nondefense will have fallen from 77 percent to 67 percent. Congress, of course, may or may not act accordingly. The point of this paper is not to agree or disagree with these viewpoints, but rather to explore their ramifications in defense economics. Tables I and II at the end of the text take the Administration's own figures- bejore mandated Gramm-Rudman-Hollings (GRH) cuts-and compare them with alternative U.S. economic growth paths and percentages of GNP allocated to defense. Table I (inconstant 1982 dollars, which factors out inflation) uses as growth alternatives ranges of 4 to 5, 2 to 3, and 1 to 2 percent, which are averaged to 4.5 percent, 2.5 percent and 1.5 percent real annual increases in GNP, respec- tively. It then applies defense percentages of GNP of S and 6 percent to each. Since 1970, except during the Vietnam War, the U.S. GNP share for defense has been either 5 or 6 percent-the latter primarily during the Reagan Admin- istration buildup, which OMB projects to continue through 1991, as does the Pentagon. It should be noted that the table lists or projects actual outlays, as opposed to appropriations or new obligational authority. The actual and projected calendar year 1985-91 defense expenditures in Table I exceed even six percent of real GNP for all years but one, except under a very high growth scenario of 4.5 percent, which practically no independent forecaster would predict today.' 'Early hopes that lower energy costs and interest rates would stimulate growth at such higher rates have yet to be realized due in part to badly damaged sectors of the U.S. economy such as agriculture, mining, oil and energy and basic manufacturing, and in part to major losses of market share through massive trade deficits during the high dollar era. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 The gaps between the resources thus projected and the stated requirements do appeaz manageable under the six percent alternative, on the 2.5 percent growth assumption, which appeazs to reflect current mainstream thinking in the economic community. However, over time it may be more realistic to ex- pect the defense share to run closer to 5 percent of GNP, owing largely to con- gressional sentiment for deeper defense cuts, the intractable government budget deficit, and the deficit-related GRH mandate, which is complicated for the mo- ment by the Supreme Court ruling on the role of the Comptroller General in the automatic enforcement provisions of the law. Table I suggests that the gaps will not be manageable (under the medium growth, S percent of GNP, scenazio) and could average over $50 billion in an- nualshortfall (in constant 1982 dollars) over the six calendaz yeazs from 1986-91. Table II confirms this situation and magnifies it as stated in current dollars, assuming a nominal 6 percent growth in GNP-for example 2.5 percent growth and 3.5 percent inflation-where the gaps might average $98 billion per year from FY 87 to FY 91 under a 5 percent of GNP assumption and nearly $47 billion per year even under the 6 percent assumption. It is not possible at this writing to factor in the impact of GRH on this picture, given the uncertainties of how both Congress and the Administration will finally respond to the Supreme Court decision. But assuming that the original GRH target of reducing the Federal deficit to $144 billion in FY 1987 is met, the Con- gressional Budget Office has estimated that under across-the-board cuts, a 15-plus percent cut would have to be made in the Administration's FY 1987 defense budget proposal (not outlays) of $320 billion and that such cuts would likely accelerate in future yeazs. This $50 billion GRH cut, in addition to any shortfalls projected from the preceding analysis, looms lazge in a long-range defense program in which Stealth costs maybe upward of $80 billion; 100 new attack submarines could cost $100 billion; and 5,000 army light combat helicopters might require around $30 billion. Finally, $20-30 billion would be needed for SDI's R&D phases alone, according to estimates published in Washington Post articles. (Total 10-year costs of a deployed population defense system have been projected as high as $770 billion, with more limited, e.g. silo-type defense estimated at $160 billion.') Shortfalls of such magnitudes would appear to require substantial strategic and program adjustments beyond the tighter management and procurement reforms recommended by the Packazd Commission, important as these measures may be in their own right. The conclusion, starkly stated, is that under the most realistic political assess- ment of congressional willingness to fund defense priorities'-and the most realistic economic scenarios, the U. S. cannot get from here to where the Admin- istration wants to go in its national strategy and force posture. If this conclusion proves correct, there aze a number of possible lines of policy response: (1) The government could simply ignore the budget deficit problem and let it grow as it will. Virtually all economists agree that this attitude could lead to disastrous consequences in the long run as inflation would rise, U.S. interest 'Various articles in The Washington Post, spring 1986; see, for example, March 22, 1986, p. A8. The SDI estimate is based on a study for the Johns Hopkins Foreign Policy Institute, reported in the Past, July 23, 1986, p. A12. The Pentagon disputes this or any other cost estimates at the present stage of research. 'As described in The Secretary of Defense Annual Report to the Congress, FY 1987 (Washington: Department of Defense) 1986. u?..~..,.,?...~.. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 rates would go up sharply-in part to attract more of the foreign capital which is already financing over half of the deficit. The probable result would be domestic recession or a return to the stagflation of the seventies, even without the two crippling oil shocks that disrupted that decade. (2) The Pentagon could try to muddle through, defemng some big ticket pro- curement, reprogramming, attempting to live off already appropriated but un- spent funds, and hoping for the emergence of greater national consensus on the defense buildup and an economic growth path closer to the 4.5 percent upper range. Judging from past experience, this is the most likely bureaucratic response, since all the other alternatives are politically painful and bound to meet with objections. (3) "National security" could be given enough priority to wazrant major revenue increases, for example from income and income surtaxes, consump- tion taxes, oil import levies or energy or other user fees. This response seems out of tune with the current climate of "revenue neutral" tax reform, with the GRH mandate, and with the President's firmly stated opposition to tax increases of any kind. (4) The government's nonmilitary expenditures could conceivably be trimmed even more, although many would azgue that they have already been cut to the bone and major additional cuts would encounter fierce congressional opposi- tion. In any case, what could be done in practice would seem faz too little to meet defense gaps of the size outlined above. (5) The entire U.S. approach to strategy and force posture could be revised. The challenge is awesome, to say the least, since among other things, it could reopen the bloody battles over roles and missions of the four services that raged in the late forties, call for assigning greater responsibility for European defense to the other NATO allies, essentially aburden-sharing issue; or require shifting to a reliance on mobilization as opposed to readiness. This last-mentioned adjust- ment would tacitly accept the risks inherent in reliance on political (as distin- guished from strategic or tactical) warning, predicated on the assumption that signs of a more aggressive Soviet policy or buildup would become evident in time to employ mobilization' and reserve force assets-and that the U.S. and its allies could muster the consensus and political will to do so. Major cutbacks in defense spending would also entail curtailments and cancellations of major weapons systems, each with its own constituency. It would take a lazge team of expert defense policy analysts many months to outline such structural alter- natives and estimate their costs and risks, and no such effort will be attempted here.' 'There aze, however, major questions about the adequacy of the U.S. mobilization base, as more and more capacity in certain vital but endangered industries, such as ferro-alloys, are driven off- shore or out of business, leaving the U.S. dependent on foreign sources for important components and for strategic materials, many of which the U.S. has stockpiled, but now may sell off over time under the Administration's July 1985 proposal. These questions will be addressed in a forthcoming IESI study. 'One such expert, however, has had the courage to tackle the challenge alone. In A Reasonable Defense, (Washington, The Brookings Institution, 1986), Professor William W. Kaufmann com- pares alternative U.S. force structures against major combat scenarios. The foreword by Brook- ings president MacLaury summarizes Kaufmann's finding that "if U.S. forces could be coherently designed to address major U.S. vulnerabilities, they would not only outperform the currently pro- grammed force, but would also save at least $200 billion in outlays between fiscal 1986 and fiscal 1990." (p. viii). Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 (6) The Administration could actively embrace, rather than struggle against, the possibility of major East-West azms control regimes in a way that could lead to significantly lower military requirements. But, it takes two to tango and past Soviet responses to unilateral U.S. restraints have not been encouraging. Either the Soviets have proceeded with their own buildup out of sheer bureaucratic momentum, or they have calculated that U.S. restraints reveal a weakness that could be exploited to shift the correlation of forces further in their favor. Whether the present Soviet leaders, given their current problems at home, might respond with genuine mutuality will be explored later in this paper. One must conclude, then, that the United States faces major, growing gaps between likely available resources for defense and the militazy requirements to be met.b The problem is postponable for only a short time; and ignoring it will not make it go away. There is, to pazaphrase Henry Kissinger, a "necessity for choice"; and any inability in the American polity to face and make such choices has grave implications for the country's future. ?Articles in the defense-oriented press have implied from time to time that even the spending goa/s of the Administration are inadequate to meet the actual requirements of its stated strategic objectives, a question which cannot be evaluated here; but if true, then the mismatch between fund- ing and strategy becomes even more serious! ?~~~~~~~?~-~- Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 ~-~-~?-~~ Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 III. NATO EUROPE Without in any way diminishing the overall importance of Canada to the alliance, that country's military contribution to the defense of Europe is relatively small and it has been reduced over the years. Italy, Iberia, and the defense forces of countries on the northern and southern flanks, while vital to the security of these regions, are less relevant to the center. This section, therefore, will con- centrate primarily on Germany, France and the United Kingdom, along with the Benelux countries as a group.' Both Britain and France have experienced, on a smaller scale, the superpowers' dilemma of how to maintain adequate conventional strength while moderniz- ing and increasing the survivability of their strategic nuclear components. The choices made have ultimately favored the latter, at the expense of the former. West Germany has pursued a restrictive monetary and fiscal policy, and evidently plans to continue this course, despite pleas from her allies, notably the United States, to shift to a more accommodative, lower-tax, growth-oriented approach in order to stimulate international trade. Thus real growth in the Federal Republic should average about 2.5 percent per annum for the next several years, and while defense will consume some 20 percent of total Federal spend- ing, real annual growth in defense expenditure is likely to increase only by about one half of one percent, far below that of the economy as a whole. The Ger- man government's 1985 White Paper on defense states clearly that no substan- tial increases in defense are in sight, although an average expenditure of over 3 percent of GDP should continue. In addition, Germany is facing demographic problems which will, over time, shrink the available manpower pool for com- pulsory military service to a marginal level. Britain is plagued with high and rising unemployment, despite substantially lowered inflation and a return to respectable real growth of about 2.5 percent. The Thatcher government's medium-term financial plan, with its tight fiscal and monetary policies, may generate tensions between defense programs and civilian public expenditures programs, especially as the sharp drop in world oil prices cuts into government revenues from North Sea oil. Following a few years of significant increases, mainly for nuclear modernization and the eventual replacement of Polaris submarine missiles, Britain's defense spending is likely to level off at or below inflation rates, i.e., with little or no real increases in the near term. France is trying to adjust to an unprecedented "cohabitation" between a socialist President and a conservative Prime Minister and government, and the resulting strains will intensify as the next national elections approach in 1988. Both parties have been staunch in maintaining and improving France's indepen- dent nuclear deterrent, albeit at the expense of some other military programs; and France will likely continue to allocate about 4 percent of its GDP to a defense posture which, while increasingly coordinated with NATO, is not integrated 'In 1985, according to NATO data, the United States contributed nearly 75 percent of the total US$358 billion defense spending by alliance members. Britain contributed 6.2 percent, France 5.4 percent, and Germany 5.3 percent. All the others together only add up to 7.7 percent of the total. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 with it. As elsewhere in Europe, unemployment remains a significant problem, even with 2-3 percent real growth rates in the economy.' Despite periodic crises as coalition governments are shuffled, both Belgium and the Netherlands have been able to allocate close to a 3 percent average of GDP for defense, even during disappointing economic performances. But the competition for resources for social welfare programs, especially those aimed at industrial restructuring and unemployment, will continue to limit defense expenditures to modest real annual increases at best. Overall, NATO Europe's defense expenditures in constant prices have re- mained essentially flat over the years 1970-85, rising only slightly since the late seventies. And in current dollars (converted at current exchange rates)9 they have shown a slight downward trend since peaking in 1980.10 The best one can say, is that, absent some sharp upturn in threat perceptions, NATO Europe will barely hold its own, while the practically available resources will remain insufficient for highly ambitious conventional force improvement programs, let alone high-tech weaponry for some of the newer strategic concepts such as deep interdiction, air-land battle, and follow-on forces, or for strategic missile defense beyond limited R&D participation in SDI. This not-too-optimistic over- view, reached independently by the writer in the course of economic surveys of Western Europe, is also confirmed by the International Institute for Strategic Studies reference to "the looming difficulties which will face NATO as its ef- forts to accelerate conventional defense improvements collide head-on with stringent resource constraints."" Certainly, there is no realistic prospect that Europe will fill the gap implied by the preceding analysis of the U.S. requirements versus resources. This fact may be increasingly relevant if the U.S. balance of payments deficit remains intractably high, possibly forcing curtailment of U.S. government foreign ex- change expenditures for various purposes, including NATO defense. The ef- fect would be a rerun of the problems experienced by the U.S. and NATO in the late sixties. Finally European opinion will remain vulnerable to Soviet "peace" initiatives, especially if they appear to offer some real substance which might lower defense burdens and relieve some of Europe's internal political tensions. However, as outlined in a forthcoming Atlantic Council study, there are other approaches to burden-sharing in a broader alliance context that ought to be explored.' It would seem, then, that NATO as a whole faces the same dilemma of how to use limited resources more effectively in the defense, against a backdrop of a continuing Warsaw Pact conventional superiority, nuclear parity, and escalating costs of "smart" and other military technologies. 'A national service requirement is traditional in most nations on the continent. The writer has tested informed opinion in several European countries about the possibility of supplementing the cancer and conscripted forces with a voluntcer force designed to utilize the large pools of unemployed manpower by providing salary incentives for longer tours of service. These could be paid for, in part, by transferring equivalent resources from social welfare agencies to defense ministries. Despite some apparent advantages in utilizing the unemployed for national defense functions, the concept has been coolly received, to say the least, and often simply dismissed as impractical. 'This situation partially reflects the strength of the dollaz against most foreign currencies, until recently. '?Source: NATO Press Release, December 1985. The International Institute for Strategic Studies Strategic Survey, /985-86 (London: 1986), p. 92. "Sce "Comprehensive Security: Balancing National Contributions to Western Well-Being" by Leonard L. Sullivan Jr. and Jack A. LeCuyer (forthcoming 1986). Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Something therefore may have to give in the central region of NATO, whether planned resort to tactical nuclear weapons at an earlier than desirable stage of conflict; greater reliance on resources and mobilization potential at the expense of readiness, the use of heavier screening forces backed up by concentrations of mobile counterattack formations and defined strong points-at the expense of the "forward defense" which is politically vital to the West Germans; or bold new efforts on mutual force reductions and anti-surprise attack measures with the East. Failing any of the alternatives, the alliance leaders may have to take draco- nian steps to force economies of scale by improving the division of labor in defense procurement, intensifying standardization and inter-operability, and constructing a better two-way procurement street across the Atlantic. Difficult as such steps may be politically, savings or effectiveness increases of up to 25 percent have been postulated by some experts. Again, painful choices would be involved, and the instincts of NATO's civilian and military bureaucracies would be to maintain the flexible response strategy in effect for twenty years, despite a diminishing "thin blue line", making im- provements at the margin when possible and in procurement when forced to do so. The point, of course, is that the U.S. and its allies must try to seek com- mon solutions to shared problems, rather than unilateral ones. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 IV. The Soviet Union and Warsaw Pact" In March 1986 the CIA and DIA together submitted to the Joint Economic Committee of Congress a comprehensive report on "The Soviet Economy under a New Leader." Much has been written about that leader, General Secretary Mikhail Gorbachev, including the rapidity with which he has consolidated power, the concessions he may have made or will have to make to various power centers and factions, his assertiveness in establishing his agenda, with domestic economic reform at the top, during the 27th Party Congress and subsequently, and his supposed flexibility in dealing with the West. Less has been said, however, about the state of and prospects for the Soviet economy. Gorbachev inherited an economy that was largely stagnant, with productivi- ty declining as both investment and growth in the labor force tapered off. Energy and materials inputs reflected rising costs and the 1981-85 five year plan (FYP) was well below targets. One of the factors, other than general sluggishness, cor- ruption and inefficiency, was the direct and indirect costs of the massive military buildup. That effort increased from roughly 12 percent of GNP in the seven- ties to about 16 percent in the eazly eighties. Moreover, the recent annual growth rate of that buildup has outstripped the growth of the economy, which aver- aged under 3 percent for the FYP just ended, in effect robbing the nonmilitary sector of vital inputs, although there is a complementarity between the military and civilian industrial complexes which must be taken into account.'' One must add to these factors the dramatic decline in world oil prices, especial- ly when priced in cheaper dollars, which may lead to a $5-7 billion loss in hard currency in 1986, as well as the $2.8 billion estimated costs of the Chernobyl nuclear accident. It is clear as Gorbachev starts his effort to reform and mod- ernize the Soviet economy, that he faces an uphill struggle and is unlikely to achieve his ambitious goals." His objectives envisage GNP growth of 3.5 per- cent ayear for 1986-90, S percent from 1991-2000, with the agricultural target at 3 percent and industrial output at 4.5 percent, an increase of 150 percent in productivity by 2000, higher oil and gas production, and large order of magnitude increases in both the quantity and quality of consumer goods. Few Western observers believe such goals are attainable, at least without "unleash- ing" the economy in ways that could be dangerous ideologically and politically. Dr. Hardt's analysis of the Gorbachev dilemma (Appendix) postulates three alternative scenarios: (1) The projection of past trends, with defense allocation characterized as incremental, ideological, and institutional; (2) A defense buildup in response to perceived foreign threats or oppor- tunities, with defense allocations essentially unconstrained by civilian needs; and (3) A pragmatic approach, with reduced defense burdens and a reassessment of the world environment, strategy, forces and budgets. This would in- volve the triad of elements in the triangulaz analogy outlined in Section I. It would appear to be in the West's interest to respond to current Soviet arms control initiatives in ways that would encourage the third scenario. If the Soviets "Although this section draws heavily upon the analysis of "Soviet Economic Constraints on Defense to Year 2000" by John Hardt, which is incorporated into this paper as an appendix, the evaluations and comments are those of the writer. "See IISS, Military Balance, 1985-86, pp. 17-18. This source, however, also underscores the many unresolved methodological problems in assessing Soviet military expenditures. "See Appendix for details. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 ~,.,,,~?-,,,,~,a Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 choose to face the hard choices, as Dr. Hardt points out, they will be faced less in the fiscal-budgetary terms which are the driving constraints in the West than in the difficult and costly allocation of specific physical resources and plant capacity, particularly machinery and procurement, manpower, and the ingre- dients of scientific development. Qualified R&D personnel will be in short sup- ply, as will computer-literate workers and the owners of other high-tech skills. Moreover, the Soviet demographic problem is growing; most population in- creases are occurring in the non-Slavic and Central Asian regions to the point that the Great Russians may already be a minority in "Russia." More detailed analysis can be found in the Appendix. It implies, however, that the West may have available both a carrot and a stick. To choose the latter, in which case the West would observe no arms control constraints and proceed to maximize its technological advantages, such as SDI and new subnuclear military potentials, would probably propel Gorbachev toward the second, or buildup scenario. He would then be forced to abandon his goals for the civilian economy, except for its spinoff benefits from military modernization. But this course would also intensify the West's own dilemma of resources versus require- ments; and totalitarian states have an inherent advantage over democracies when it comes to enforced belt-tightening, even though the latter, as wealthier coun- tries, may have more slack to take up. The political consequences of a renewed cold war and essentially unconstrained arms buildup on the chances for stable security by the year 2000 are also formidable, for a high threat perception and response by one side will almost inevitably produce acounter-response by the other. The carrot on the other hand, could offer a lower threat perception, make possible clear constraints (if verifiable) on defense and especially strategic, deployments, and hence bring about the shorter economic hypotenuse suggested in Section I. This prospective easing of their guns vs. butter dilemma would encourage the Soviet leadership towards Scenario 3, the "pragmatic reassess- ment," which could prove mutually reinforcing in terms of East-West relations, and a favorable vector toward stable and mutual security as the century winds down.16 In purely military-economic terms, the Soviet Union's Warsaw Pact allies contribute less than 10 percent to the total Pact expenditures of approximately US$275 billion."This contrasts with the more than 25 percent provided by the U.S. NATO allies. Nevertheless, their manpower, economic potential, and geographic location are of great strategic and political importance to the U.S.S.R. Because of the high degree of Pact military integration and to a lesser extent, economic integration under CMEA, we need not discuss the six non- Soviet Pact members individually, after noting that their national interests vary. (In MBFR negotiations, for example, East Germany hewed closely to the Soviet line; Poland made known its own interests in achieving a reduction of the Super- power (read Soviet) deployments in Europe and easing both the manpower and economic burdens of defense; and Rumania played its customary maverick role.) For this discussion we can assume that the future options of the other War- saw Pact countries are tied to those outlined above for the Soviet Union. But they display even greater tendencies to seek butter over guns in their economic 16For more details of this scenario-and its alternatives, see the writer's article on "Strategic Stability and Mutual Security in the Year 2000, Getting There From Here" in the U.N.'s Disarma- ment magazine (forthcoming) in a report on a U.N. meeting of experts in Erice, Italy, April 1986. "As estimated and converted in the IISS, Military Balance, 1985-86, cited. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 tradeoffs, for with spotty exceptions, the CMEA economic performance in re- cent years has been plagued by economic reversals and debt problems. Thus the Soviet Union can expect even less help from its Warsaw Pact allies which, as the Appendix points out, are a net cost to Moscow in both military and economic terms, than can the United States from its NATO allies. In neither case, however, can the superpower concerned look to its alliance system for significant relief from its own resource squeeze. ..,.., ..~.?...a?.. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 _.. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 V. CONCLUSIONS A medium-to-low threat perception on both sides coupled with medium-to- low economic growth rates, could reinforce other incentives toward arms con- trol and even limited disarmament. But initially there will not likely be signifi- cant savings, since nuclear forces are a relatively small part of the whole, and for the United States, at least, achieving substantial budgetary savings would require cancellation of entire weapons programs, closing of installations, and large-scale reductions of personnel-which, however, could be accomplished on the military side by greater emphasis on reserves. There is always a high initial cost for such measures, which only pay for themselves over time. Some rough indications of current budget breakdowns by n-ission are contained in Table III. It should be emphasized, however, that potential economic savings of what- ever magnitude are not enough of a magnet to draw either superpower away from a course it considers essential for its major national security objectives. And their mutual relations will be characterized for the foreseeable future as a mixture of competitive and cooperative elements. Even though it is unlikely that there will be a substantial detente dividend in an economic sense, the stresses and strains of coping with a growing divergence between defense requirements and resources on both sides, as a minimum, may create incentives to reduce the pressure by easing off on the requirements side, improving the climate for the third scenario for the USSR in Section IV and making way for a parallel reassessment for the United States and for NATO. Arms control negotiators are, by necessity negotiating about each other's in- tentions as well as capabilities. Under any but the worst scenazio, however, structural change will probably have to come to the Pentagon over time; but the real squeeze, one hopes, would come only after renewed arms control progress is on course and verifiable. As President Reagan stated in his February 26, 1986 address to the nation, percep- tions of U.S. weakness or lack of will in defense can only weaken Soviet incen- tives for arms control concessions. The need for effective dialogue between East and West is thus apparent. On the other hand, a high threat perception by either side would generally produce a reciprocal response by the other, leading to renewed tensions and higher defense requirements. The Soviet Union would find it easier to cope politically with such a development than would democracies, especially under low-growth assumptions. For the United States, this situation could mean a significant rise in the overall tax burden, unless we also postulate along-term high growth scenazio, which is without precedent in this country. Burden-shazing may again become an issue within the alliance unless the U.S., European, and Japanese assessments of the threat are more nearly parallel than they have been traditionally. It is a common assumption that real threats to the peace are more likely to arise in the Third World than in Europe, and unless the other industrialized countries feel themselves directly at risk, this attitude could become divisive, endangering the cohesion of the alliance and impeding its approach to common problems of resource allocation. As we look ahead to the yeaz 2000, it appears that both East and West are likely to face an increasingly painful ends and means dilemma which is parallel in some respects, and asymmetrical in others. If each'side sees the other's pro- blem in a zero-sum game context as a weakness to be exploited, then little can be expected beyond continued mutual insecurity at mounting costs and conse- quences to the economies of all concerned. But if each side is prepared to look Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 at its strained "economic hypotenuse" in positive-sum terms, then perhaps im- proved mutual security may be obtainable at lower costs-and even more im- portant, with lower risks of military conflict and escalation to thermonuclear disaster. This is the crux of the issue facing both leaders. Some of President Reagan's advisers are urging that this is precisely the time to maximize the armaments squeeze on the Soviet Union, hoping thereby to intensify its economic crisis and force major concessions. The writer believes this misjudges the Soviet chazacter, which has always responded negatively to perceptions of external pressure, and underestimates their ability to sustain a gazrison state if necessary. Additional viewpoints by Soviet specialists aze noted in the Appendix. Conversely, advisors in Moscow undoubtedly point to the West's economic constraints as reasons why they should not pay any substantial price, in arms controls or other concessions, for the more tranquil external environment Gor- bachev has said he needs in order to concentrate on domestic problems. This, too, seems to the writer to be a misjudgment of the Western resolve. Nevertheless, by the end of the decade, the United States is probably going to have to choose between the difficult options outlined in Section II, specifically No. 5: major defense restructuring, which would be better done in conjunction with major arms control measures, not as ends in themselves, but as the other side of the overall security coin. And here, the Soviet dilemma is quite parallel, as suggested by new signs of greater civilian control over military spending and deployments, as in the Far East and Afghanistan. The possibility of an East-West superpower summit meeting within the next six months offers the chance to explore and test whether a real window of oppor- tunity for improved East-West relations is there to be opened, or whether it is only an illusion created by the so-called "Americanists" who now hold key positions in the Soviet foreign policy establishment, in order to affect western public opinion. With both Secretary Gorbachev and President Reagan self-confident and relatively secure in the leadership of their respective constituencies, the time seems ripe for a real dialogue, with all of the cazds on the table, about future East-West relations and arms control possibilities. Some general and positive guidelines from the top, for example about SDI limitations and strategic of- fensive cuts, would then enable the negotiators for both sides to seek real pro- gress in their various fora. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 ?~ Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 ESTIMATES OF REAL GNP GROWTH AND PROJECTED DEFENSE SPENDING AS A PERCENTAGE OF GNP (billions of 1982 dollars) 4.5% Percentage 2.5% Percentage 1.5% Percentage Projected Defense Real of GNP Real of GNP Real of GNP Total as a % of GNP 5% 6% GNP 5% 6% GNP 5% 6% Outlays Defense Outlays GNP 1985 3576 179 215 3576 179 215 3576 179 215 846 227 27 6 1986 3736 187 224 3665 183 220 3629 182 218 856 232 27 6 1987 3905 195 234 3757 188 225 3684 184 221 829 238 28 6 1988 4080 204 245 3850 193 231 3739 187 225 824 243 29 6 1989 4264 213 256 3947 197 237 3795 190 228 830 236 30 6 1990 4456 223 267 4045 202 243 3852 193 231 828 266 32 6 1991 4656 233 279 4147 207 249 3910 196 235 830 275 33 6 1992 4866 243 292 4250 213 255 3968 198 238 1993 5085 254 305 4356 218 261 4028 201 242 1994 5314 266 319 4465 223 268 4088 204 245 1995 5553 278 333 4577 229 275 4150 208 249 1996 5803 290 348 4691 235 282 4212 211 253 1997 6064 303 364 4809 240 289 4275 214 257 1998 6337 317 380 4929 247 296 4339 217 260 1999 6622 331 397 5052 253 303 4404 220 264 2000 6920 346 415 5178 259 311 4470 224 268 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 TABLE I (continued) HISTORICAL AND PROJECTED DEFENSE AND NON-DEFENSE OUTLAYS (billions of 1982 dollars. Numbers may not add up due to rounding Percentage of GNP Total Outlays Defense Non-Defense For Total Outlays For Defense 1971 509 203 307 38 8 1972 528 191 337 34 7 1973 528 175 352 31 6 1974 529 163 365 30 6 1975 586 160 426 26 6 1976 610 154 456 24 5 1977 623 154 468 24 S 1978 652 155 497 23 5 1979 660 159 501 23 5 1980 699 164 535 23 5 1981 727 171 553 23 5 1982 745 185 560 25 6 1983 777 201 576 26 6 1984 789 210 578 27 6 1985 846 227 619 27 6 1986 856 232 618 27 6 1987 829 238 592 28 6 1988 824 243 582 29 6 1989 830 256 574 30 6 1990 828 266 562 32 6 1991 830 275 555 33 6 Source: Office of Management and Budget, "Historic Tables: Budget of the U.S. Government," Table 6.1 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 .. _.. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 ESTIMATES OF GNP GROWTH AND PROJECTED DEFENSE SPENDING AS A PERCENTAGE OF GNP (billions of current dollars) FY GNP estimates' % Nominal Growth of GNP Defense Spending= Defense Spending as % of GNP 1987 4,538.1 8.3 311.6 6.9 1988 4,902.9 8.0 332.4 6.8 1989 5,268.9 7.5 353.5 6.7 1990 5,623.4 6.7 374.7 6.7 1991 5,955.2 5.9 395.5 6.6 'Office of Management and Budget, "Historic Tables: Budget of the U.S. Government," Table 6.2 'Department of Defense, "Annual Report to the Congress-Fiscal 1987, Executive Summary," Table 2 ESTIMATES OF 6% NOMINAL GNP GROWTH AND PROJECTED DEFENSE SPENDING (billions of current dollars) GNP Nominal Percentage of GNP Defense Defense Department Projections minus Defense Spending as % of GNP FY Growth of 6% 5% 6% Spending' ~5% ~6% 1987 4,538.1 226.9 272.3 311.6 84.7 39.3 1988 4,810.4 240.5 288.6 332.4 91.9 43.8 1989 5,099.0 255.0 305.9 353.5 98.5 47.6 1990 5,404.9 270.3 324.3 374.7 104.4 50.4 1991 5,729.2 286.5 343.8 395.5 109.0 51.7 'Department of Defense, "Annual Report to the Congress-Fiscal 1987, Executive Summary," Table 2 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 TABLE III PROGRAM COSTS FY 1986 (Billions of dollars of budget authority) ProgrAm Strategic forces 29.9 General purpose forces 132.1 Intelligence and communications 27.9 Airlift and sealift 8.0 National Guard and Reserve 16.9 Research and development 30.4 Central supply and maintenance 26.5 Training, medical and other general personnel activities 35.6 Administration and associated activities 5.9 Support of other nations 0.5 Total budget authority 313.7 Source: Budget ojthe U.S. Government, FY 1986 and estimates of William W. Kaufmann in A Reasonable Dgjense (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1986), Table 2.7. Kaufmann estimates total direct and indirect "strategic nuclear retaliation" costs at SS 1.5 billion, theater nuclear retaliation at $3.2 billion, and conventional defense of NATO Europe, excluding the Atlantic, as $107.2 billion, /bid., Table 2-6. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 APPENDIX SOVIET ECONOMIC CONST'F~AINTS ON DEFENSE TO YEAR 2000 by John P. Hardt* Associate Director for Senior Specialists Congressional Research Service July 1986 *Personal views of the author, not necessarily those of the Congressional Research Service, the U.S. Congress or any U. S. Government agency Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 ?..~...-...-..~. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Defense Economics in Flue The Soviet Union, like the United States, appears to be at a point of poten- tial change in the priority and process for economic allocations to defense. While Gorbachev's focus on the revitalization and reform of the economy as the cen- tral task of the leadership for the rest of the century suggests that changes in methods of planning and management may occur throughout the economy, in- cluding defense support, the outcomes remain uncertain. In this context, we may see one of several different scenarios developing with respect to both the way economic decisions are made in the defense sector and the kind of deci- sions that result. (1) The first scenario consists of a projection of the past trends established under Brezhnev. In this case, a defense buildup may be supported in areas of competition with the United States and in azeas of perceived opportunity even though requirements for improved economic perfor- mance could have a dampening effect on defense budgets. This Past Projection scernario also would seem to find the Soviet defense establish- ment continuing to dictate the progress of new programs within the policy framework of the defense philosophy of the past, i.e., responding to new technological developments in the West and servicing global com- mitments, while retaining capabilities for the defense of the homeland. Under this scenario, defense allocation decisionmaking might be describ- ed as incremental, ideological and institutional. Under Brezhnev, military allocations were constrained by economic perfor- mance, but increased sufficiently to support a substantial military buildup, the policy basis of which was both ideological and pragmatically political. Con- strained by civil needs and performance, defense allocations were incremental; although influenced by pragmatic, Great Power politics, the policy framework was dominated by ideological and institutional criteria. The Soviet Union may continue to increase its military expenditures in this way. With slowing overall growth, defense growth (measured in dollars) is estimated to have remained at a two percent rate from 1974-1985-half the rate of the previous decade. (Measured in rubles and assuming increasing cost of procurement, the slowdown would be somewhat less severe.) Even with slower overall growth in the economy, according to United States intelligence estimates the share of GNP allocated to defense increased from 13-14 percent of Soviet GNP in the early 1970s to 15-17 percent by the early 1980s; in dollaz equivalents defense was $146.2 billion in 1985. In this period, the qualitative inputs to the military balance from Soviet military procurement, manpower and R & D were sufficient to assure attain- ment of bi-polar parity. (2) Perceptions of threats or foreign opportunities may dictate an increase in the growth of allocations to defense. A breakdown in arms negotia- tions and a decision to confront the U.S., NATO, and other Western countries more aggressively might lead to an increase at least to the trend lines of the pre-1974 period that is, 4.5 percent growth per annum. In this Defense Buildup scenario, decision-making would be largely un- constrained by needs and performance of the civilian economy and would be largely ideologically and institutionally driven. If the Soviet leadership decides to allocate more to defense in response to perceived opportunities or threats and if the economy grows as planned, the Soviets might be able and willing to devote twice the increase of resources to defense without materially changing the defense share of total output. The Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 defense procurement rate of the early Brezhnev period (1968-74) of 4-4.5 per- cent might return or be exceeded. However, assuming economic growth and constrained defense allocations aze closely related, a high defense budget would probably have to be pursued at the expense of civilian programs and stepped- up performance. A resumed buildup of manpower, as occurred during the late Khrushchev period for manning the China border and replacing Czech forces in the Warsaw Pact, might not fully return but the pressure to reduce military manpower might be resisted. Military research and development would likely be increased, but how effective it would be in meeting the new technological challenges may be open to question. (3) A modified, restructured and lower defense claim on the economy might be an outgrowth of Gorbachev's new strategy. A greater emphasis on regional over global threat assessments, greater attention to the economic and political value of the tradeoffs to defense, and an increased Party involvement in military policy and defense planning could together lead to a Reduced Defense Burden, Pragmatic scenario. Such a scenario would be closer to the more pragmatic, politically oriented process of U.S. defense planning and more likely to produce a reduced economic burden. If some further restraint on defense were to derive from Gorbachev's priority to domestic investment and consumption and a perception of an environment conducive to arms negotiations, the defense shaze would likely fall. The late 1980s and 1990s may be a period of change in the trend and level of growth of resources for defense in both the Soviet Union and the United States. Economic and political modernization, revitalization and reform are the central ingredients of the strategy of Gorbachev coming out of his first Party Congress-the 27th Congress of the CPSU in February-Mazch 1986. With the possibility of restraints on defense budget growth deriving from budgetary con- straints and the possibility of a process of arms control negotiations relating to bilateral Summits, the United States may shaze a prospective down-turn in defense priority and a reform in the administration of defense, at least in procurement. Soviet change under the spirit of the Gorbachev strategy of the 27th Party Congress would move away from the past resource policy of incremental growth-an increasing shaze of absolute and relative goods and services devoted to defense; ideological threat assessment-balancing a global view of Moscow- centered Communism with a more pragmatic Great Power and regional perspec- tive; institutionalization in defense planning and programming that relies less on the decisions generated by the military-industrial complex and rather more on the broader political view of the top Party. The ideological component would be less in enforcing a Suslov-Brezhnev type doctrine with the CMEA-Warsaw Pact and more in flexibility in dealing with Communist parties abroad as similar to other parties in non-Socialist countries. The `commanding heights' approach of politicalization takes power for policy and planning up from the Ministerial and regional party levels to the `super` Ministries and Politburo and Secretariat of the Central Committee with skilled staff at the Secretariat level providing the administrative muscle for increased top Party control. Applied to the military bureaucracy, this would, by analogy, shift the policy decision-making and key information support and implemen- tation up to the level of the Party Secretariat. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 ,.~,..h_M.?.~,~....__ _ _ Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Let us explore these three scenarios in the context of the defense decision- making process with emphasis on the third: a scenario with constrained defense spending and restructured defense decision-making that moves toward the more pragmatic, politicized American model. Such a scenario may be considered most consistent with Gorbachev's rhetoric and his requirements: it would respond to the incremental burden of rising military costs, address the special require- ments of space-age research and development, and support Gorbachev's com- mitment to improved economic performance. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 I. Triad of Dea.9on Malting: Gorbachev's Movement Toward A Reduced Defense, Pragmatic Model. Mikhail Gorbachev seems to be interested in changes in the triad of defense decision-making: a reassessment of the world environment or a revised threat assessment; a reevaluation of military programs and security strategies; and a consideration of military programs and budgets in the context of economic con- straints or burden assessments. It remains a question, however, in just what sequence these changes may be considered, and whether the institutional im- peratives of the defense establishment rather than threat or environment assess- ment still drive military programs. But just as the leadership in the United States seems constrained by budgetary limitations that restrict militazy and domestic programs, the Soviet leadership may feel the burdens of budgetary limitations as the competitive claims of in- vestment and consumption restrict their defense allocations [Gramm-Rudman in the USA; Gorbachev-Ryzhkov in the USSR]. The budgetazy constraints may in turn lead to re-evaluation of the other aspects of decision-making. A. International Environment Estimate. (Threat Assessment) The assessments of the international security environment by the Party leader- ship and defense institutions are becoming global assessments of requirements based more on a pragmatic Great Power role rather than on ideological con- siderations as in the past. The appointment of Anatoly Dobrynin to the Secre- tariat of the Party, assuming the position occupied for years by Boris Ponomarev, presents some evidence of this shift from ideology toward prag- matism by focusing more foreign policy expertise and clout in the Party Secre- tariat. Power in foreign and security policy (arms negotiations) has shifted towazd the Secretaziat. Although the regional and global assessments that result may still be inimical to U.S. interests, they may nevertheless be more pragmatic. These threat assessments may thus be likened in Gorbachev's calculus to some political cost-effectiveness scale that would provide a basis for negotiation and for the limitation of military claims on resources. B. Requirements Planning and Programming. Military programs and security strategies that may have been driven in the past by bureaucratic pressure (from the Defense Council and the Ministry of Defense complex) may now be coming more under top leadership control. More- over, the psychology of past defense orientation and post war experience may be giving way to a new generation's assessment based more on pragmatic Great Power politics. Such trends in defense planning might be advanced if the Soviet leadership applies the same principle of economic reform to the defense economy that is being adopted in agriculture. In this case, it might centralize key policy analysis and decision-making for the defense establishment at top Party and govern- ment levels and decentralize management decisions. A national security unit created in the Party (such as the Economic Department in the Secretariat of the Central Committee) could take on a role similar to that of the National Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Security Council in the United States with the Party Secretariat unit develop- ing its own staff. A Party Politburo member such as Lev Zaikov, who currently holds the defense industry portfolio in the Politburo, might be Gorbachev's designated civilian security adviser, with the Defense Council taking on a role like that of the Joint Chiefs of Staff and with the new Party Secretariat securi- ty unit staff providing support for Zaikov. On the government side, the crea- tion of a National Security Committee (such as Gosagroprom for agriculture) could provide Gorbachev and Ryzhkov a unit above the Ministry of Defense Industries that could coordinate and oversee both defense and civilian management. C. Economic Constraints and Defense Burden. New strains could be placed on defense spending under the pressures of Gor- bachev's economic prescriptions: (1) his emphasis on energizing the economy and using the best cadres for civilian production enterprises; (2) the intensifica- tion of industry and agriculture requiring lazger shares of growth for invest- ment and consumption; (3) improvement in the scientific and reseazch establish- ment to compete in the technological-information revolution. In each case, the deferral of military claims, an increase in the openness of the military produc- tion and research establishment, and the sharing of high quality military assets may be required to bring about improved economic performance. The Gorbachev Five-Yeaz (1986-1990) and Fifteen Year Plans (1986-2000) call for higher growth, improved capital efficiency, labor productivity and quality of output for which a dynamic and productive research and development en- vironment is essential. The formula for reaching these economic goals, necessary for the political and military claimants alike, involves short term military sacri- fices and change. Such changes could be necessary to attain an improved civilian technological-economic base that will allow for long-term civilian and military competitiveness (this could be called the larger thrust of SDI). Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 II. Gorbachev's Tradeoffs: Guns or Growth Even more than budgetary pressures, limited physical resources and capacity may severely constrain growth of Soviet military allocations. Soviet leadership is not constrained by its state budget but by physical resource limitations. More- over, the aggregate levels are not the burden, specific physical resource limita- tions present the tradeoff problems. The hard choices are to be found especi- ally in procurement, manpower, and research and development: Procurement-The incremental priority requirements of machinery for ful- filling Gorbachev's Five and Fifteen Year Plans of modernization squeeze incremental military procurement demands. Manpower-The reduction in the available draft age, manpower cohort and the increasingly non-Slavic character of this cohort will make it difficult to maintain current military manpower levels without denying increments to the civilian labor force and without enhancement of the education of the cadre; there will be more competition for the limited number who are educated. R & D-Future military and civilian needs in the age of SDI require open- ing, diversion or amalgamation of the priority military R & D establish- ment with the backwazd and less productive civilian scientific establishment. A. Military-Civilian Tradeoffs: Procurement To the extent the Soviets have difficulty finding the resources to simultane- ously meet Gorbachev's industrial modernization goals and satisfy military re- quirements in the near term, a central problem of choice will arise in the machinery sector which traditionally has allocated a large portion of its output to the military.' As noted by U.S. intelligence assessments, the increased demands for resources needed for these programs will be centered around several areas: ? Factory Capacity. Implicit in Gorbachev's call for increased output of ad- vanced machinery is the competition-in the absence of rapid plant expansion- for modern workspace at production facilities. In this connection, robots, computer-numerically-controlled machine tools, computer-aided design systems, flexible manufacturing systems, and other highly automated manufacturing sys- tems are important for the production of both advanced manufacturing equip- ment needed for boosting industrial productivity and for producing sophisticated weapon systems. ? Basic Materials. Chemicals and metals are used in producing both weapons and advanced machinery. The ferrous metals ministry, for example, has failed to meet its targets for many types of steel in recent years. ? Intermediate Products. Engineering plastics, advanced composite materials, electronic components, and microprocessors are currently in high demand in the defense industry and, as modernization proceeds, will be needed increas- ingly by civil industry as well. These products, however, are in short supply. 'The Soviet Economy Under a New Leader, A paper prepared jointly by the Central Intelligence Agency and the Defense Intelligence Agency submitted to the Subcommittee on Economic Resources, Competitiveness, and Security Economics of the Joint Economic Committee, U.S. Congress, March 19, 1986, 43 pages. ,~~,.~~?~.,,,~ Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 ~,_. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 ? Labor. Both the defense industry and modern civil industry require highly skilled workers, particularly computer technicians and software engineers. The near-term competition for factory floorspace and investment goods has been mitigated by the substantial expansion and upgrading of defense-industrial plants over the past decade. Comprehensive programs to modernize many weapons production facilities began in the early 1970s. Efforts to modernize defense industry accelerated in the late 1970s, and we believe a large portion of the best domestically produced machinery was delivered to defense industry during this period. In addition, the defense sector was helped by a surge in clandestine and open acquisition of Western manufacturing equipment= In the short-run-into the eazly 1990s-competition for additional investment goods for new capacity will not, they argue, be critical, as the joint CIA-DIA assessment sees the investment crunch coming in the 1990s: As a result of this investment in defense industry, almost all of the pro- duction capacity required to support Soviet force modernization over the next six yeazs or so is already in place. Our calculations suggest that virtu- ally no additional investment in the plant and equipment is needed to manu- facture the military hardwaze that we believe will be in production in 1986-88 and that most of the capacity required to turn out the military equipment projected to be in production in the eazly 1990s is already available. Moreover, weapons development and industrial construction indicate that investment in defense industries will continue at a high level, adding new capacity with greater capabilities. Thus, military production would not be constrained in the near term by a reallocation of new fixed investment in favor of civilian machinery and other priority sectors. Although the Soviets have the production capacity to maintain or even increase the current level of weapons production, competition for labor and material inputs used in the production process could force some trade-offs at the margin between military and civilian production. The nature of this competition is shown in the Figure, (p. 30)) which summarizes our judgments on (a) the degree of need for the particular resource in civilian machinery, (b) its availability in non-machinery sectors of the economy, and (c) how easy it would be to shift the resource from military defense industry to civilian machinery. High-quality steel and energy, for example, will be in great demand to manufacture machines needed for both industrial modernization and weapons production. The high targets the Soviets have set for machinery production will place tremendous demands on the ferrous metals branch. This industry, however, has been doing poorly in recent yeazs and appazently will receive little, if any, increase in investment during the 1986-90 FYP. Although there is likely to be some growth in the energy sector, the energy situation may be tight. Others see the defense claims affecting economic performance in the current 1986-1990 Plan differently in terms of the timing of the difficult choices. Dr. Jan Vanous notes, "we found that the amount of machinery available for in- vestment and defense use combined will not be adequate, at least in 1986, under any reasonable scenario to satisfy both domestic investment and defense needs. Moreover, except in the case when the growth of domestic defense machinery production is slashed to 4% per year during 1986-90, which is an extremely slow Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 v10~ ~t~O~~0o0N~O~~O~~OI~ONOOl~~G7I"7N~[~~N~~O~O~ . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . M M~~~~~~~ o~O O- ~ N N N N N N N N N N~~~ N N N N N N ~~ vi.-.~O~000~~--X0000[~l~N~~TO~vi~viO~000~~~OQ~~--~M~O--~ . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . OOO~O~O~--~NNM ~~n~0[~O~O~O~O~000OO~OO~~~NNMM ~--~^~ ~-+NNNNN~NNNNNNNNMMMMNMMMMMMMMM ~~+=gyp ~~i D Of a U ~ O a ai u y ~ p 06 E" ~, O~ a~GTr V as t~0~0 v11~1~v~v1~Ol~O~MMNTM~~O ViN~0~0 ~+v1N r+Ml~ N~~~OC~Ncnvif~O~??vioOMe+i TOooooo0~p 00000000??tVri~ MMMMM~~~~~V1 V1 V1~D ~O ~~O I~~D ~O ~O ~O ~O ~O ~O f~[~[~t~l~l~ H y h u F ems u t ~ C b h V ~ rr. ~y V R 1~ ~ .??~ V1 00 h V1 00 ~O 00 ~O ~f ?-~ `7 00 00 O~ ~O ~ ~O N ?--~ '~! M ...i ..r O O~ I~ M . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . v~'1 Y~01 V~p1 vMl Vtf1 h VN1 V1 h V01 ~ ~ ~ 7 ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ Q ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ OoON~NOON~--~O~~MO~O[~viN~vioOVi~nO~~N~OviOvi.~.~0 .r.-r.~-iM,~?~~V1~G ~0[~[~~O [~~O V1 V1~~M~~M~~~V1 V1 ~~D ~O t~I~ MNN~~vl~pbr0000N0~~~0v~1Y~1VN1~~~VM1V'71h1Mpb1~rr0~00~00~ ..q ~ ~I rl H ti ti r1 rl ~--~ ~--~ ~--~ rl rl ~--~ rl .--~ .--1 rl rl H r1 rl ~--~ rl ~--~ rl rl H ti rl V1 V1M PVIO t~N V1~0 ^?~/1 OOO~~nMNOO ~~n ~ON~00 ~~00 l~ 00 00 ?~-~ ~ V'1 ~O 00 00 .-..-..-r N N O ?~-~ ?~-~ N N M V1 ~ \O 1~ OO Q .-~ N ~ v1 l~ ~"~ ~"~ ~"~ NN NNNN MMMMMMMMMMMMMMMM v ~ ~ ~ ~ N_N_~NOO V'1l~?-.N(~~^'h~~Q~~~~~Ovl VM1 V~1 V[~1 V001 ~Db~~O M M M M M ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~~~~V1V1V1~O~O~~O~D~O~D~O~O~D~O~D~0~0~~0~0~0[~rl~f~0000 00 ~Ot~vi^?[~vi0~Y~0 NOON ~D~nM0~0~~ _MN7~D~n~--~~-+ VI~NN~ONMMVI O~OMMt~~p 000~~--~~~~pp ~~pp Mv11~0~~--~N NNNMMMMMMMNN~00~~ 0000010~0~0~ OOOOC--~~-+ O~l~ ~700~vi~OM 0~7??~M~O?-.N ~~O [~~O aOMN~~~O ~O T?-?o00~ N. [~~ NO~~l~p00 OOM~O ~--~p V1N ~M MOO M00 OON N~~--~~Q'Q~n~n~O~O~OetMNr+~0000~--~~~-+NNNMM ~v~ N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N N O--~NM~vi~Of~000~O~NM~v'~~Ot~o00~ NM~v'~ [~a0 c~~rrrr~t~t~rooooo000000oooooaooo~~~~~~ ~~ rno~o~o~o~o~o~o~o~o~o~o~ao~o~ao~o~o~o~ Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 growth rate by historical standazds-the Soviets do not stand a reasonable chance of freeing enough machinery for investment purposes to achieve their ambitious investment and capita! modernization target. "' B. Military-Civilian Tradeoffs: Manpower. Quantitatively hard choices will have to be made among allotments for the civilian labor force, the university student cadre and the military. The difficult decisions on qualitative allocations involve regional, ethnic, and educational limitations on quality and reliability of current draft age cohorts. During the 1980s, the `second echo of World War II,' is preventing the Soviet leadership from maintaining the military manpower level, while increasing the civilian labor force. (Table 1 left). As indicated by Dr. Murray Feshbach's analysis of the Soviet census, the U.S.S.R. will not be able to keep up military force levels and expand the labor force at the same time until the 1990s. Thus, the short-term competition for human resources could be even more intense than for investment and material resources. Extensive underemployment exists in the Soviet economy, and Gorbachev may hope that he can support his moder- nization program by mobilizing currently underemployed engineers and labor. But shortages persist in the U.S.S.R. in several skill areas (as indicated in the Figure, next page). Critical to both defense and modernization, for example, are systems analysts, computer programmers and selected types of engineers and skilled machinists. Thus, the most likely immediate source of additional specialists for the civilian machine building metal working industry is a realloca- tion ofthe employees already working in the machinery sector through increased labor productivity. Soviet additions to the military will be predominantly non-Slavic, especially youth from Central Asia and Kazakhstan. This change in the draft age, labor force pool adds a qualitative factor to the quantitative shortage. Rural Central Asians tend to be less skilled and educated, and many have limited Russian language facility. C. Military-Civilian Tradeoffs: R&D In the past, military R & D has received priority over civilian programs. Well funded and staffed, with supplementary inputs to its core military programs gained from effective foreign intelligence, the military R&D program has pro- vided abasis for keeping up, closing the technical gaps in many traditional military areas, and moving ahead in some. In the 1990s, military and civilian technological needs alike will be met only if the Soviet scientific establishment can join the technical information revolution of the West. The research base required for the U.S. Strategic Defense Initiative [SDI] is an important factor in determining the range of likely needs for efficient and effective military and civilian establishments. The demands of new weapons development, the shift to an intensive economy and the greater emphasis on innovation, point to the need for reform in the Soviet approach to defense allocations. The continued 'Jan Vanous and Bryan Roberts, `Time to Choose between Tanks and Tractors: Why Gorbachev Must Come to the Negotiating Table or Face a Collapse of His Ambitious Modernization Pro- gram,' Plan Econ, Inc., Volume II, June 27, 1986. [original underlined] Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 6 ~~E 8 ~~ E ;o ~e^o'~e^o~e^o 'x x ;a ;d ~ x ~o~o~o^o;~ ,'?ero ~+ xsx ~$ ~ u ~ ~ x~ ~~ ~ ~~~~ ~~ ~ ~ N eo B ~ u ~g~ ~ 0 a 's N V L L _h h ~ ~ h y c~ h Y u .~ ~ 'u N ~. Z m p ..Vi ~~+ V N ?~O ~ V OO l" ~ G" C G ~ Fn d F'-' o ~ ~+ 'g O N ~ H .O R O ~+ X00 ?C a w 00 .~, ?+ p r .:.; OO C 00 ~ 'n ?. y ~' Vl ~ ~ vi ~ T 3 00 ~ ~ ,6) '~ ,~~. O ? ?'~ C~ Q u ~ b ?~ L~?y O 0. "' ~~" ~' G .q ~u. N C Ri ~ '~ .nq Q~ ~ ~ ~ In yr ..w . ~ 1 Q 1 .~ 0 ~ iw ..s ?+'b f/1 Qti ~ ~..'Lr ..n Ln V C ~" h 'fl ~ U N ~ ? ~ Ir In ~ ~ .~ G V '+ ~ U a ...n O U a U W V i" Chi' ??V-~ ~ ~ Y O L ~ ^ .w~+ ld ~ ..V-i ~ ..Vi U 0 .-Ni O N O y ld 'fl ~y ~ W ~~~ ?.r'UW~ v~QFU ~ oWG.oW~U~ a"U W~npG~~ p..7 ae ~m ~ aU Q ~~n ~ ~n .. ? Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 decoupling of defense and civilian sectors of the economy deprives the total system of a stronger advanced technological base and reduces prospects for overall productivity increases. The U.S. SDI program is organized in five specific research areas. These con- sist of Kinetic Energy Weapons Technologies (KEW); Directed Energy Weapons Technologies (DEW); Systems Analysis and Battle Management (SA/BM); Surveillance, Acquisition, Tracking and Kill Assessment (SATKA); and Sur- vivability, Lethality and Key Technologies (SLKT). The scope of technologies embedded in the SDI symbolize the enormous difficulties inherent in preparing the Soviet military for the next century if the reforms in research and develop- ment now under consideration by Gorbachev aze not implemented.' Condoleeza Rice of Stanford University writes: There are those in the Soviet military who are arguing that it is really in the area of new technologies, microelectronics, particle beam weapons, and artificial intelligence that there is a challenge from the West. These people may be willing to forego short-term acquisition in favor of research, develop- ment, and investment in militarily promising technologies. Their time horizon might not be the same as that of those who wish to invest in basic research and to divert funds from military research, but it could bring about a tem- porary bazgain between those who seek investment in technology for civilian purposes and those who seek the same for military use. In the short-term, this could lead to a less intensive purchase of hardware and investment in future technologies. Then, should promised reform of the economy bring an end to the period of economic stringency, the Soviet military would be well prepazed to acquire forces for the battlefield of the twenty-first century.' The technologies under development to support the U.S. SDI are creating a pool of innovative concepts which will have potential applicability to the U.S. defense industry in strong interaction with the civilian sector. For example, Battle Management/Command, Control and Communications requires the develop- ment of computer hardware and software on an unprecedented scale. KEW systems require research on microelectronic controls, advanced infrared and radar sensors, compact chemical propulsion devices, and electro-magnetic launchers which could lead to advanced anti-tactical weapons and propulsion systems. DEW creates a focal point for laser research, particle beam concepts, and large space structures. Systems analysis involves studies of large space transportation systems paving the way for space exploration in the 21st century. Finally, SDI countermeasure studies are evaluating the vulnerability of defense systems to possible offensive responses which could drive improvements in technologies such as nuclear radiation hardened electronic means to counter a Soviet maneuvering missile threat. The scale of the U.S. SDI effort will probably incline the Soviets to restructure their efforts in the reform of research and development planning. The dual character of SDI technology may require Gorbachev to incorporate technological reforms for both civilian and military needs. For example, investment in com- puter technology has a military and civilian commonality. Institutional pressure 'The discussion of SDI is essentially from communication with Bazry Breindel, Manager, Research and Defense, Washington Operations, AerojeF Telesystems Co. ' Condolezza Rice, `The Development of Soviet Military Power,' The Gorbachev Erq, i~,dited by A. Dallin and C. Rice, Stanford Alumni Association, Stanford, California, 1986, p. 137. ? ,Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 may build to force greater cooperation between research institutes and the scien- tific enterprises, serving both the civilian and military sectors. It is widely assumed in the West that the Soviet Union can only adequately compete in the technological information revolution if it opens its advanced military and civilian reseazch establishments to the effective scientific com- munication systems successful in the West. Openness with a relevant scientific community is a requisite for a dynamic, technologically successful R&D establishment. Foreign imports must be effectively assimilated in a system of incentives and rewards for a successful innovation system to work. To the military, such an amalgamation of its research within the civilian establishment and immediate priority toward developing a new, more dynamic system would require the deferral of traditional, short-term military claims on their R & D establishment and along-term sharing of the scientific results. A leading factor in this new revolution is the civilian economy. Logically, the military cannot satisfactorily meet its needs from its own privileged, R & D monopoly; how many in the military hold this view is not known. Furthermore, the require- ment of openness to foreign research makes the reliance on espionage less effec- tive. Use of KGB middlemen in an era of space age research is likely to be less effective and inefficient. The opening of the scientific establishment to provide results for the entire scientific community also runs directly counter to the strongly held penchant for secrecy in the Soviet system. It is easy to say that the militazy and KGB-the powerful institutions in the Soviet system-will not allow openness of their scientific reseazch and R & D establishment and broadening of priorities for civilian-military research. But if they do not, they will probably lose ground, falling farther behind the United States, Japan and other industrial countries in critical areas. Gorbachev seems to understand this problem of `neo-backwardness.' Still, he may not appreciate the full political and economic cost of the tradeoffs in institutional and resource priority changes, or the resistance of the traditional military support institu- tions to change. ,.,,..w,.,,?...~- Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 ~?~.....,..~a_. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 III. Gorbachev's Political Tradeoffs: Cost of Empire and Great Power Status A. Cost of Empire and Alliances The Soviet Union provides support to its allies and clients through military and economic transfers. The value of military deliveries has been increasing as indicated in Table 2 below. To the extent these are not sales of state of the art, military equipment for hard currency or `hard' goods [oil], but rather are military aid of less modern equipment or non marketable, `soft' goods, the resource burden may be modest; the political risk may be the major factor. Still, Gorbachev at the Party Congress seemed to be leading Angola, Cuba, and Ethiopia to expect less support. Certainly Soviet leaders have been telling their East European allies that they plan to reduce what the Soviets perceive as a subsidy. How they follow through on limiting aid in hard goods will determine the incremental economic burden of their global role. Table 2. USSR: ESTIMATED VALUE OF MILITARY DELIVERIES, 1974-85 (billion U.S. dollars)* Recipient 1974-79 1980-85 1974-85 Six Warsaw Pact countries 8.7 9.8 18.5 Syria 4.5 10.3 14.8 Iraq 6.0 8.2 14.2 1 ibya 5.4 5.8 11.2 Vietnam 2.1 4.9 7.0 India 2.0 4.8 6.8 A 1 geria 1.6 3.6 5.2 Cuba 1.3 3.9 5.2 Ethiopia 1.5 2.6 4.1 Ango 1 a 0.7 2.8 3.5 60 other countries 7.7 11.3 19.0 Total 41.5 68.0 109.5 Source: "Soviet Economy Under A New Leader" CIA-DIA Statement, March 19, 1986. The Soviet Union also provides economic as well as military aid to the same countries to assist them in pursuing goals of common interest. Oil exports on barter terms and soft currency accounts provide some measure of the cost. Various estimates of the implied subsidy of these transfers center on the supply of oil for reduced hard currency (dollar) imports compared to what may be obtainable by sale of oil in the world market. There are varying estimates of the volume of the net transfer but unless increased it may be a tolerable burden. The question for Gorbachev for the future may be whether the resource costs of these alliances provide sufficient benefits in usable political terms. Soviet relations with East Europe have been by far their most important in political-military terms and the most costly. The Soviet total and relative East Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 1 I . ! .I'I I Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 European contributions to Warsaw Pact and hard goods trade make policy changes in this region most important. The Soviet Union might like to have its East European allies take on a larger burden of the Warsaw Pact costs, in- crease their delivery of high quality machinery and consumer goods to the Soviet Union and hold down their imports of oil and gas, but it seems very unlikely that these wishes will all come true. Moreover, East Europeans have always favored the claims of domestic investment and consumption on scarce quality resources over fulfillment of Soviet perceived economic needs for the Warsaw Pact. Soviets also favor revival of East European growth for resultant favorable trade and political stability. As a result, the least attainable of Soviet hopes among these competing claims would be an increase in East Europe's military burden sharing. B. Cost-Benefit Outlook for Confrontation or Comity. The policy of Gorbachev's predecessors since 1975, especially Brezhnev, has been to opt for military augmentation and confrontation in regional issues rather than economic cooperation and comity. This policy is best illustrated in the northern flanks of the Soviet Eurasian policy: North Asia and Scandinavia. In North Asia the policy of military buildup has been costly. Whether the benefits have been proportional is open to question. Shared development of Soviet East Siberia and the Far East would certainly be facilitated under a policy of comity, e.g. with Japan. Likewise, in North Europe the buildup of defense in the Kola peninsula and elsewhere has been expensive; the benefits may not have been commensurate. Negotiation of conflicting claims and joint development of oil in the Barents Sea would seem to be a benefit of a policy of comity with Nor- way. In this past policy of Eurasian defense buildup and confrontation the greatest economic costs have been the foregone benefits of joint development of Soviet resources. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 IV. Negotiable Lssues From the assessment of Gorbachev's tradeoffs as he may see them, some im- provement in benefits and reduction of resource costs or burden seems possi- ble in three areas of the Great Power agenda: Strategic Arms Reductions: Mutual need for stability and reduced likelihood of strategic weapons use or reduced perceptions of external threat could generate a basis of agreement, especially if tied to constraints on SDI. Conventional military forces in Europe and Asia: Mutual need to reduce insta- bility and economic burden through reduction of current order of battle buildup to maintain control in East Europe. Global Policy Understandings: Acceptance of some implicit codes of con- duct, e.g., mutually acceptable levels of support to insurgencies, common op- position to international terrorism. Whether and under what circumstances the Soviet leadership feels economic pressure to reduce the defense burden is a matter of conjecture. Some Western specialists would argue with scenario one or two that allocations to defense are not likely to be constrained. Others accept a version of scenario three (reduced defense, pragmatic scenario), that it is currently imperative for Soviet leader- ship to reduce the defense burden. Jan Vanous and Bryan Roberts, for exam- ple, feel that the Soviet General Secretary's view should be that now is the time for negotiations in order to avoid `collapse' of his ambitious economic mod- ernization program: It is apparent that the Soviets will not unilaterally sacrifice what they perceive to be an adequate defense capability in order to improve the performance of the economy. They will try to come to the negotiating table and, in all probability, offer the U.S. unprecedented concessions for economic reasons outlined below. If they cannot secure a `satisfactory' arms deal, they will follow the U.S. lead and mount acounter-SDI program, even though this may well push the Soviet economy perilously close to an unprecedented economic crisis.? ?Vanous and Roberts, op. cit., pp. 1-2., this Appendix. 35 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 _.. _. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 ABOUT THE AUTHORS Dr. Timothy W. Stanley is a lawyer and economist who has combined a career in government in the national security area with private sector work on inter- national economic problems. He is Chairman of the International Economic Policy Association, having been President from 1974-1984, and also founder and President of its affiliated International Economic Studies Institute. He has taught at Harvard, George Washington, and Johns Hopkins (School of Advanced International Studies) universities, and was a visiting research fellow at the Council on Foreign Relations. He received his education at Yale (B.A.) and Harvard (LL.B. and Ph.D). He has written widely on both securi- ty, including NATO, East-West relations and arms control, and international economic topics, ranging from politico-economic studies of major foreign coun- tries to the U.S. balance of payments, raw materials, multinational corpora- tions and foreign economic policy issues. These writings include half a dozen books (some with co-authors) and numerous articles, monographs, professional papers, and congressional testimony. Dr. Stanley's government service has included two tours of military duty and civilian assignments at the Pentagon, the White House staff, NATO (as Defense Advisor and Minister at the U.S. Mission in Paris and Brussels) and the U.S. ACDA, where he was an arms control negotiator in Vienna. He has been award- ed the Distinguished Civilian Service Medal. He also serves on various U.S. government advisory bodies, and has been a consultant to the United Nations Department of Disarmament Affairs. He is a Director of the Atlantic Council of the U.S. and is active in a number of other professional organizations, in- cluding the Council on Foreign Relations and the International Institute for Strategic Studies. Dr. John P. Hardt is associate director for senior specialists and senior specialist in Soviet economics of the Congressional Research Service. He is also adjunct professor of economics at both George Washington and Georgetown Universities. His doctoral degrees in economics and Soviet area training were received at Columbia University. Dr. Hardt is a frequent traveler to Eastern Europe, the People's Republic of China, and the Soviet Union, especially with Congressional delegations. He has authored and edited numerous books and articles for commercial, government and academic publications on East-West commercial relations and the economies of Eastern Europe, the Soviet Union, and the People's Republic of China. He has participated in the annual, bilateral United Nations Association Ex- change with U.S.S.R. Since 1978 he has been the American representative on the steering committee of the Panel on East-West Initiatives based in the Insti- tute of Comparative Economics, Vienna, Austria. He has frequently served on State and Defense Department Advisory Committees. Dr. Hardt is an active member of the Council on Foreign Relations, United Nations Association and American Association for Advancement of Slavic Studies. Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 ~,~,,,,,,,~,,,,, 1 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 International Economic Studies Institute (IESn Board Of Trustees David C. Acheson John L. McLucas Harlan Cleveland Myer Rashish Ronald L. Danielian James D. Santini Isaiah Frank Timothy W. Stanley Jacob J. Kaplan Ib Thomsen Officers President and Treasurer, Timothy W. Stanley Vice President, Ronald L. Danielian Secretary and Assistant Treasurer, N. Ethelyn Thompson International Economic Policy Association (IEPA) Albert L. Baldock Harry F. Bliss Juan C. Cappello James E. Courtney Ronald L. Danielian James S. Hearons H. L. Johnson James W. Nethercott W. C. Brian Peoples H. Chapman Rose Timothy W. Stanley Ib Thomsen Ronald S. Wishart Richard A. Yudkin Honorary Directors John Marshall Briley Henry H. Fowler Walter L. Lingle, Jr. Officers Chairman of the Board, Timothy W. Stanley President, Ronald L. Danielian Vice President, Secretary and Treasurer, N. Ethelyn Thompson Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7 The Atlantic Council of the United States 1986 BOARD OF DIRECTORS Chairman Andrew J. Goodpaster Vice Chairmen Treasurer David C. Acheson William H. G. FitzGerald Henry H. Fowler John E. Gray U. Alexis Johnson President Carol Laise George M. Seignious II Wm. McCh. Martin Eugene V. Rostow Executive Vice President Kenneth Rush Joseph W. Harned Directors David M. Abshire Martin J. Hillenbrand Paul H. Robinson, Jr. Theodore C. Achilles, Jr. Walter E. Hoadley Olin C. Robison Donald G. A~gger Claire Giannini Hoffman H. Chapman Rose Stephen Ailes Robert D. Hormats Nathaniel Samuels Madeleine K. Albright J. Allan Hovey, Jr. J. Robert Schaetzel Dwayne O. Andreas B. R. Inman James R. Schlesinger Willis C. Armstrong John N. Irwin II Brent Scowcroft W. Tapley Bennett, Jr. Isaac C. Kidd, Jr. Raymond Philip Shafer James H. Billington Lane Kirkland William E. Simon George S. Blanchard Jeane J. Kirkpatrick Joseph J. Sisco Gene E. Bradley Henry A. Kissinger Helmut Sonnenfeldt Harold Brown Juanita M. Kreps Frank A. Southard, Jr. L. Dean Brown Peter F. Krogh Timothy W. Stanley Zbigniew Brzezinski John M. Leddy George J. Stathakis Harry F. Byrd, Jr. Lyman L. Lemnitzer Walter J. Stoessel, Jr. Daniel J. Callahan, III Sol M. Linowitz Ralph I. Straus Sol C. Chaikin Sanford N. McDonnell Robert S. Strauss William B. Dale George C. McGhee George A. Strichman Kenneth W. Dam Donald F. McHenry Leonard Sullivan, Jr. W. Kenneth Davis Robert M. McKinney John J. Sweeney Russell E. Dougherty Robert S. McNamara James W. Symington Lawrence S. Eagleburger Lawrence C. McQuade William C. Turner Robert F. Ellsworth Leonard H. Marks Stephen L. Van Sherwood L. Fawcett Thomas J. Murrin Cyrus R. Vance Gerald R. Ford Edmund S. Muskie Richard D. Vine George S. Franklin, Jr. George R. Packard Thomas J. Watson Richard N. Gardner Edmund D. Pellegrino Watson Wise Dale E. Good Jacques J. Reinstein Joseph J. Wolf Lincoln Gordon Stanley R. Resor Lawrence M. Woods Alexander M. Haig, Jr. Emmett J. Rice R. James Woolsey Pamela C. Harriman Elliot L. Richardson Honorary Directors George W. Ball Ralph C. M. Flynt Sam Nunn Edward W. Barrett Andrew Heiskell Henry H. ,Porter Andrew H. Berding John D. Hickerson William P. Rogers Eugene R. Black Tom Killefer Robert V. Roosa Leslie S. Brady Ruth C. Lawson Dean Rusk Harlan Cleveland Oswald B. Lord Adolph W. Schmidt Emilio G. Collado Jay Lovestone Cortlandt v.R. Schuyler C. Douglas Dillon John J. McCloy Charles M. Spofford John Ferguson III Lauris Norstad Approved For Release 2011/09/01 :CIA-RDP93T01142R000100020004-7