MODELING SOVIET AGRICULTURE: ISOLATING THE EFFECTS OF WEATHER

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
C
Document Page Count: 
96
Document Creation Date: 
December 27, 2016
Document Release Date: 
September 30, 2013
Sequence Number: 
4
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
June 27, 1988
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4.pdf3.07 MB
Body: 
r r:-t--77.--;,?-:, , . .-:;. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30 : CIA-RDP90G01353R001c.,8001:0001-4, Office of the Deputy Director for Intelligence: Central intelligence . gency STAT ? 2>siZ 27 June 1988 NOTE TO: Director of Central Intelligence Deputy Director of Central Intelligence This is a paper that has been prepared for publication as an unclassified report. It is one of several papers that we intend to publish at an unclassified level that are aimed at providing scholars and others outside the intelli- gence area some insight into how we do our analysis. Attachment Deputy Director for Intelligence p--za ogi Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 !/ Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 ential Modeling Soviet Agriculture: Isolating the Effects of Weather (IF) Scope Note This paper is an unclassified report prepared by Office of Soviet Analysis, CIA, to document the development and use of a model to examine past trends in agricultural productivity, to measure the relative contribution of labor and capital to farm output, and to assess prospects for meeting 12th Five?Year plan goals. The weather modeling work builds on research reported in two previous DI papers Other aspects of the model development were motivated by recent research on Soviet agriculture by analysts in the Directorate of Intelligence.2 25X1 25X1 DLidial June 1988 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 STAT STAT 25X1 25X1 25X1 25X1 ! / , Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Modeling Soviet Agriculture: Isolating the Effects of Teather(U) Directorate of Intelligence Central Intelligence Agency June 1988 Unclassified Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 ! Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Modeling Soviet Agriculture: Isolating the Effects of Weather (U) Information available as of I June 1988 was used in this report Summary Gorbachev needs to improve food supplies dramatically to bolster popular support for the economic restructuring program. Moscow's campaign to 'intensify' agriculture, particularly grain production, has resulted in recent gains. But agriculture still faces serious problems, and unless strong measures are taken to stimulate productivity on the farm, Moscow will grow increasingly unable to meet the demand for more and better food supplies without resorting to substantial hard currency imports. Gorbachev has been seeking ways to overcome the gross inefficiencies of the agro?industrial sector. Agricultural reforms since Gorbachev came to power include the creation of the superministry Gosagroprom, endorsement of collective contracts for farm workers, enforc;ement of stable procurement plans, and promotion of the right of farms to directly market a portion of planned fruit and vegetable procurement. Gorbachev's call last year for a special Central Committee plenum to tackle comprehensive agricultural reform suggests that more policy initiatives in agriculture are on the way. To evaluate the effects of such initiatives, it is first necessary to isolate the effects of weather, which often mask the influences of other variables on agricultural performance. 11 Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Isolating Weather Factors A mathematical model was developed to separate the effects of weather from the effects of other factors. In developing the model, it became clear that weather factors alone were not sufficient to explain agriculture's dismal showing during the 1979-82 period. When capital, labor, and productivity changes were included in the model in addition to weather, the results tracked closely actual fluctuations in output (see figure 1). The rate at which weather?adjusted output is increasing has important implications for Gorbachev's agriculture policy. Until 1979, weather?adjusted output increased steadily, reflecting relatively stable growth of inputs, steady but slow technological progress, and the absence of sharp swings in government policy (see figure 2). Weather?adjusted output dropped precipitously in 1979 and continued to decline in 1980 and 1981. During this time, growth of deliveries to agriculture slowed as overall industrial growth slowed, and transportation organizations were increasingly unable to keep pace with the growing requirements. In addition, government policies specific to agriculture were flawed as well. ; -- Investment resources going to agriculture were wastefully allocated and inefficiently utilized. Soviet authors have complained, moreover, about losses of agricultural products because construction of storage facilities and rural roads was neglected. -- Agricultural machinery downtime increased, efficiency in the use of inputs--especially machinery, equipment, and fertilizers--declined, and growth in livestock herds outstripped growth in feed availability. iii Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Billion rubles (1982 prices) Newaga--BENNETK 140 - 135 - 130- 125 - 120 - 115- 110 - 105 100 - 95 - 90 Figure 1 Observed Farm Output and the Model's Predictions 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1987 is preliminary. Jun 10, 1988 Legend o Actual data ? Model E cc ti Declassified in Part- Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 NEWAGB1--BENNETK ?Net of feed, seed, and waste. 5. 0 Billion rubles (1982 prices) o CP o 1 1 1 i - Cm 7.6 0 (78 CO (/? -- 1 0 -1 a za. 3 co 0 A0 pool naugzaia 0 ss, ? 0 ? ? C o D.AaLIID9M .J0j. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified In 1983, however, there was a remarkable recovery, reflecting improvements in efficiency stemming from the Brezhnev Food Program implemented the previous year. Since Brezhnev's death in late 1982, Gorbachev has used his influence in the leadership to reshape the program to reflect more closely his own views and priorities. In addition to measures targeted at increasing worker productivity, Gorbachev has given the 'intensive technology' program a high priority. Intensive technology, as defined by the USSR, includes many practices routinely performed in the West--use of high?yield varieties, planting after fallow where possible, implementing efficient field operation schedules, and extensive use of agrochemicals. By 1984 and 1985 weather?adjusted agricultural output had nearly returned to the pre-1979 trend, and performance was clearly back on trend in 1986 and 1987. Returns to Capital and Labor The model results also show that the return to capital is lower in agriculture than in any other producing sector of the economy except fuels, which underscores the burden imposed on the rest of the economy by agriculture's large share of investment resources. The capital elasticity was estimated to be 0.17, indicating that a one percent increase in the capital stock results in only 0.17 percent increase in output. The return to labor in agriculture, on the other hand, is estimated by the model to be over four times higher than the return to capital. vi Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified These results demonstrate why the Soviets are concerned about productivity in agriculture. The structure of the model implies that Moscow has three potential policy options for increasing farm production: 1) increase the capital stock by accelerating growth in capital investment; 2) increase the number of workers and/or hours worked per worker, including increases in the number of part?time workers; and 3) increase productivity. The low return to capital relative to alternative investments in other sectors of the economy suggests that increasing capital investment in agriculture is not in the best interest of the overall economy. Increasing the labor input is not feasible because the size of the labor force in agriculture is declining due to natural demographic trends, which Moscow is powerless to change, and the leadership is opposed to increasing part?time employment in agriculture at the expense of production in other sectors of the economy. The only remaining policy option is ?to increase the productivity of the labor and capital inputs. This can be accomplished if Moscow continues to push for programs and policies designed to increase worker efficiency. Long?standing impediments to productivity growth must be overcome before significant progress is possible, including: -- Weak link between the size, quality, and costs of harvests and the financial rewards for farm workers and managers. -- Low quality and inappropriate assortment of farm machinery. -- Rural living conditions that are still too stark to encourage younger, skilled workers to stay on the farm. vii Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified -- A rural education system that is inadequate for teaching modern agricultural practices. Outlook The model was used to evaluate prospects for meeting the 1986-90 Five?Year Plan goal for agricultural output. Farm output for 1988, 1989, and 1990 was projected after making assumptions about capital and labor growth and simulating alternative outcomes for weather and government policy. Model simulations indicate that the Soviets would be able to meet their plan only if the following three conditions prevail: -- At least 'average' weather for 1988-90. Continued growth of inputs from other sectors at a rate equal to that of recent years, which was four percent in 1986, together with timely deliveries. -- Productivity gains equivalent at least to a one percentage point increase in productivity growth above that required to offset employment losses. If any of these conditions are not met, the goal will be out of reach. Even with good weather, substantial gains in productivity are required to meet the five?year plan. Regardless of how successful ongoing and potential additional agricultural policies are, however, bad weather--especially if it occurs in both 1988 and 1989--could spawn an agricultural failure severe enough to exacerbate current consumer dissatisfaction with food supplies and threaten the success of Gorbachev's reform effort. While the probability that bad viii Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified weather will occur in two consecutive years is low, the impact on Soviet domestic policy--and foreign trade--would be high. ix Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Contents Page Summary ii Gorbachev Needs A Success in Agriculture 1 A Model of Soviet Agriculture 3 Factors Influencing Performance 3 Capital Stock and Investment 4 Labor 5 Material Inputs Technology 6 Weather 7 Government Policy 8 The Model 8 Modeling Policy and Productivity Changes 10 Applications of the Model 15 Weather?Adjusted Output 15 Returns to Capital and Labor 19 Total Factor Productivity Adjusted For Weather 20 Prospects for the Future: Can the 1986-90 Plan Still Be Met? . . 23 Assumptions 23 Capital 23 Labor 24 Ix Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part- Sanitized Copy Approved forRelease2013/09/30 : CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Page Weather 25 Material Inputs and Technology 26 Government Policy 26 Scenarios 27 Conclusions 28 Appendixes A. Development of the Model Al Preliminary Models Al Final Model A4 Testing For the Effects of the Industrial Growth Slowdown A6 Comparison of Preliminary and Final Models A7 B. Data Farm Output Bl Bl Agricultural Capital Stock Bl Employment in Agriculture B2 Weather B3 Farm Output Value?Added Farm Output B5 B5 xi Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Modeling Soviet Agriculture: IsoLating the eFfects of weather Gorbachev Needs a Success in Agriculture Agriculture will play an important role in determining how successful Gorbachev will be in revitalizing the Soviet economy. The next few years will be difficult ones for the economy as a whole as Soviet managers and workers attempt to cope with the numerous and wide?ranging elements of the reform program. Gorbachev has already encountered serious opposition to the pace of reform, and additional resistance is expected as implementation spreads. Gorbachev, who built his career in part as an agricultural expert, needs a success in agriculture; failure to improve the food supply will not only be damaging to Gorbachev politically, but could also undermine popular support for the economic restructuring program. Increasing productivity in agriculture--increasing output per unit of inputs--is as important as increasing the supply of food because of the high resource cost of farm production in the Soviet Union. The food production ; sector--agro?industrial complex in Soviet parlance--in the USSR is immense, claiming roughly one?third of total annual investment (including related housing and services) and employing nearly 30 percent of the labor force.1 Direct farm production activity alone claims about 20 percent of annual 1. The food production sector includes not only farms but also several branches of industry supplying farms with materials, such as tractors and other farm machinery, repair services, and agrochemicals, and branches of industry that process food products. Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part- Sanitized Copy Approved forRelease2013/09/30 : CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified investment and 20 percent of the labor force in comparison with less than 5 percent each in the United States. Despite the huge investment in agriculture, however, the Soviet Union must still import large quantities of agricultural products, particularly grain (see figure 3). Productivity increases in agriculture would enable Gorbachev to divert resources (labor and capital investment) from agriculture to the industrial modernization drive as well as reduce outlays of scarce hard currency for farm products. Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 NEWAG1-3ENNETK Composition of Hard Currency Imports US $ Figure 3 Soviet Dependency on Other Countries for Farm Products Other pr? 8.3% 1986-87 Agricultural 19.47. Grain Meat & Dairy products, animal fats, eggs 1.7% Ruble Value of Agricultural Imports (All Countries) The category "Other" includes vegetables, fruits, sugars, natural fibers, animal byproducts, tobacco, spices, coffee, tea, wine and fruit beverages. Data for 1987 are preliminary. 12000-Thousands 10000- 8000- 6000- 4000- 2000- 0 Jun 10,1988 Legend Meat Sc Diary products, animal fats, eggs flfi Grain MI Other 1971-75 Avg 1986-87 Avg Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified A Model of Soviet Agriculture2 The impact of government policies to raise agricultural productivity is often hard to detect because weather effects are so overwhelming that they obfuscate the influences of policy changes and changes in quality and quantity of inputs. To properly evaluate any new program that Gorbachev may implement, it is first necessary to isolate the effects of each of the main factors influencing farm production. Factors Influencing Performance Any macroeconomic model of the agricultural sector must account for six broad categories of factors that influence production:-capital stock, labor, material inputs (such as manufactured fertilizers), weather, technology, and government policy. In the Soviet case, some of these factors are completely controlled by Moscow, whereas others are only partially controlled or completely outside government's influence. For example, Moscow controls the flow of capital investment and material inputs into agriculture through the planning process. - The supply of labor, on the other hand, is partly determined by demographic trends, over which Moitow has no direct control. Moscow can, however, influence the supply and 'quality' of the agricultural workforce to some extent through government policies such as those directed at relocating labor and at providing incentives to attract skilled workers to agriculture. Weather, of course, is completely outside Moscow's control. 2. The model deals strictly with agricultural output per se, and thus does not address other important components of the agro?industrial complex, such as the food processing industry and the supply of industrial products to farms. Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Capital Stock and Investment. Since 1970 the. stock of machinery, equipment, and nonresidential structures has more than tripled in Soviet agriculture. Fixed productive capital in agriculture at the beginning of 1987 totaled 330 billion rubles, of which 61% represents nonresidential buildings and installations, 17% represents agricultural machinery and equipment, 3.8% represents transportation equipment, 0.5% represents draft animals, 9.5% represents productive livestock, and 4.6% represents perennial plantings.3 But while the overall size of the capital stock has been growing, the rate at which it is growing has been slowing since the mid-1970s (see figure 4). Growth of the stock of tractors in agriculture, for example, has fallen from about 3% per year in the mid-1970s to nearly zero percent in 1986. Because technological advances in design and engineering are embodied in new capital, capital investment is the carrier of much of the new technology going into agriculture.4 Growth of investment in agriculture fell from a high of 15 percent in 1971 to less than zero percent in 1984 (see figure 5). In 1986, however, investment growth rebounded to a irate approximately equal to that of the mid-1970s (6 percent). 3. Data are from Narodnove khozvavstvo SSSR Za 70 let, p. 204. The Soviets measure capital in 1973 'comparable' prices. 4. Capital investment in agriculture includes new machinery and equipment, new construction and installation of new farm buildings (including new livestock rearing facilities, irrigation and drainage systems, and agricultural research institutions), net additions to livestock, and capital repair. Unclassified Draft ')cY1 25X1 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 NEWAG2--BENNETK Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 14 - 12 - (-.) - 40- a) a) ? 8 - a) 0 L (1) 6- -$- 0 0 6_ 4 2- 1964 Figui--e- 4 Growth of Capitol Stock in Soviet Agriculture 1 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 Jun 10, 1988 Legend ? Capital stock (exclusive of livestock) 0 Stock of tractors used in agriculture Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Figur'e'5 Growth of Capital Investment and Employment in Soviet Agriculture Growth rate (percent per year) NEWAG3--BENNETK 20 ? 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 Jun 10, 1988 Legend ? Capitol investment 0 Employment in hours worked (excluding the private sector)? ?The USSR does not report statistics on private labor, but Western estimates have remained relatively stable during this time period. ? Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30 : CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Labor. The size of the agricultural workforce in the Soviet Union is shrinking slowly, as is its share of total employment in the economy as a whole. Over 35 million people are presently employed in agriculture, and many more engage in part?time farm work and gardening for personal consumption. During the 1970s there was little change in the size of the labor supply in terms of hours worked. Since 1984, however, agricultural employment has been decreasing at about 1 to 2 percent per year (see figure 5). Unless the Soviets do something to spur labor productivity, labor requirements in the future will exceed the supply and possibly result in a serious labor shortage in agriculture. Moscow has issued numerous decrees to improve the productivity of the farm labor force, but the decrees have not yet had a widespread positive effect.5 Material Inputs. Material inputs are produced by non?agricultural sectors of the economy for use in the agricultural sector, exclusive of capital ,? investment goods. They include chemicals, fuels, electric power, animal feed supplements (including by?products from food processing), and machinery spare parts. Among the most important are manufactured fertilizers and agrochemicals. Aided by large imports of Western equipment and technology during the 1970s, the Soviet Union is presently the world's leading producer of manufactured fertilizers (nitrogen, phosphate, and potassium).6 Increases in crop yields 2 Unclassified Draft 25X1 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified since 1960 are directly attributable to the rapid growth in fertilizer deliveries. After 1975, however, growth of deliveries to agriculture slowed (see figure 6) because of lags in expanding production capacities and underutilization of existing capacities which were caused by shortages of skilled labor, equipment failures, and transportation problems. Since 1979, growth of fertilizer deliveries has fluctuated at about half the rate of growth of the early 1970s. Chemical control of insect pests, plant diseases, and weeds has also been an important factor in increased yields, particularly for grain. Since 1984 the Soviets have made special efforts to increase purchases of sophisticated forms of Western herbicides, insecticides, and fungicides. In contrast to fertilizers, more than half of the pesticides used in the USSR are imported from the West and from Eastern Europe. Although the use of chemical pesticides has increased in the Soviet Union, the average application rate is still far below that of Western countries.7 Technology. Technology in agriculture encompasses both enhancements to resources, such as new seed varieties and livestoak breeds, and innovations in the way in which resources are used, such as crop rotation schemes and Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 - C3- 2 Central intelligence gency Office of the Deputy Director for Intelligence 27 June 1988 NOTE TO: Director of Central Intelligence Deputy Director of Central Intelligence This is a paper that has been prepared for publication as an unclassified report. It is one of several papers that we intend to publish at an unclassified level that are aimed at providing scholars and others outside the intelli- gence area some insight into how we do our analysis. Attachment )4(iitilitiC>444,^S60010.564CoiRRitf-Krqq itl Scale adjustmenta A, 0.507255 Capital elasticity 2.151013 0.5837644 3.685 0.0042 Weather variables intercepta Al 1.643758 BOTNDRY A, ?14.945366 4.7595395 ?3.140 0.0105 1/BOTNDRY A3 ?0.043465 0.0177473 ?2.449 0.0343 WINTEMP A4 0.028784 0.0080357 3.582 0.0050 Analysis of Variancea Degrees of Sum of Source Freedom Squares Mean Square Probability of Durbin? F?value a greater F VE2 Watson D Model 4 0.10621403 0.02655351 29.384 0.0001 0.8902 1.958 Error 10 0.00903678 0.00090368 Corrected total 14 0.11525081 a The model was initially estimated with only six parameters, including a parameter for the sum of A, and Al. The parameter for the sum of A, and Al was determined to be 2.15101 with a standard error of 0.58376. A0 was estimated to be 0.507255 (standard error=0.02076) by fitting the following model (excluding the years 1979-82): Log(Q/L) = A0 + BLog(K/L). Al was then determined by solving A0+A1=2.151013 for Al. Note: a, = a2(W) = A e 0 eAl+A21101ND1Y+A3(1/HOTNDRY)+A4WINTEMP A-4 Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified tests indicated that these variables did almost nothing to reduce the remaining unexplained variation. To the extent that these variables are positively correlated with time, the capital input is probably serving as a proxy. In the case of hectarage sown, the year?to?year variation was perhaps too small to measure the effects of the variable on output in the presence of much stronger influences like weather. Final Model The final step in development of the model was to account for changes in productivity that occurred during the 1979-82 period and during 1986-87. For this purpose, the function a3(P) was created to reflect our subjective estimate of relative changes in productivity owing to government policy actions. The derivation of this function is explained in the main body of this paper. By adding a3(P) to the model, it was possible to include the years 1979-82 when estimating parameters. The results are shown in table A3. All parameters were highly significant statistically, and the Vr2 (R2 adjusted for degrees of freedom) was 0.970. The capital elasticity was 0.17, which is slightly higher than the estimate made using only information on capital and labor. Figure A2 illustrates how closely the model predictions correspond to the historical record. A-7 Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Table A3 The Final Model Model Log(Q/L) = Ao + P*log(K/L) + Al + A2*H01'NDEY + A3*(1/HOTNDRY) + A4*WINTEMP + As*PRODCHNC Parameter Estimates Variable Parameter Standard t for Ho: Parameter estimate error Parameter=0 Probability > Iti Scale adjustmenta Ao 0.507255 Capital elasticity 0 0.168433 0.0073280 Weather variables intercepta As 1.722217 HOTNDRY Al ?15.692849 2.0572757 ?7.628 1/HOTNDRY A3 ?0.045175 0.0076127 ?5.934 WINTEMP AA 0.035548 0.0037783 9.408 Productivity change variable As 0.048822 0.00363540 13.430 22.985 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 Analysis of Variancea Degrees of Sum of Mean Probability of Durbin? Source Freedom Squares Square F?value a greater F Watson D Model Error 13 0.00257557 0.00019812 Corrected total 18 0.11808509 5 0.11550951 0.02310190 116.605 0.0001 0.9698 2.123 a The parameter for the sum of Ao and As was estimated to be 2.22947 with a standard error of 0.25126. As was estimated using the value for Ao derived in table A2. A? Undlassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Note: al = a2(W) = a3(P) = eAo Al+A2HOTNDRY+A3(1/HOTNDRY)+A4WINTEMP eAsPRODCHNG A-1 Unclassified Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 NEWAGA2--E3ENNETK Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30 ? CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 0.80 0.75 0.70- c?0.65- 0 Cr) 0 _J 0.60 - 0.55 - 0.50 - 0.45 Figure A2: Model Predictions Using Full Model 1978 1983 - 1985 1972 1975 1981 1986 (7) -0.2 1 Feb 22, 1988 Legend o Achiol doh-) 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 ? Mo,IPI Log (K/L) pr Ddictlons Footnote Q is farm output in billion 1982 rubles. L is labor in billion manhours. K is capital in billion 1973 rubles. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30 : CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 The final model is: = al a2(W) a3(D) 0 1,1?P e, where Unclassified al = e eA,A1HOTNDRY+As(1/HOTNDRY)+A,WINTEMP al(W) = I- eA,PRODCIING as(P) = 0 = capital elasticity parameter, Q = value of agricultural output, excluding farm output used within agriculture (such as feed for livestock and grain for seed), billion 1982 ruble's, K = annual capital stock in agriculture at the beginning of the year, excluding livestock, billion 1973 rubles, L = total work?hour employment in agriculture, billion hours, HOTNDRY = ratio of average temperature (degrees centigrade) to cumulative precipitation (millimeters) for April through July, weighted by total sown area, WINTEMP = average winter temperature (degrees centigrade) for October through March, weighted by area sown to winter wheat, PRODCHNG = productivity change variable, Ao...As = statistical parameters, and e = stochastic error term. There are two factors that can influence agricultural output that are not explicitly included in the model--technological progress and material inputs (such as agrochemicals). Technological advances such as higher yielding A? 11 Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified strains of grain or higher livestock growth rates resulting from genetic improvements would contribute to higher growth. Similarly, increases in grain yields can be attributed in part to increased use of fertilizers and pesticides. Efforts to estimate the model with an additional time?trend variable representing technological progress and variables representing deliveries of agrochemicals to farms were unsuccessful. However, the capital input embodies technological progress to the extent that the value of new machinery and equipment reflects increased efficiency over the old machinery and equipment. 'Disembodied' technological progress could also occur as a result of more efficient management and adoption of new farming technologies. To the extent that this disembodied technological progress is an increasing function of time, the capital input--which is also an increasing function of time--acts as a surrogate, or proxy, for it. For the same reason, capital also serves as a proxy for material inputs. Testing For the Effects of the Industrial Growth Slowdown The model was used to conduct a statistical test to determine if the industrial growth slowdown during 1979-82 had a detrimental affect on agricultural performance. The final model presented in table A3 was re?estimated after replacing the function a3(P) by a dummy variable (DUM) consisting of 'i's for the years 1979-82 and 'O's for all other years.4 A 4. A dummy variable is a time?series sequence of l's and O's. Use of the dummy variable in hypothesis testing is equivalent to performing an analysis of variance and testing for significant group effects--where the two time periods represent two groups--while simultaneously accounting for variation between the two groups that is due to differences in capital and labor inputs and weather. Unclassified Draft Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified parameter value for DUN that is not significantly greater than zero would suggest that non?weather factors other than capital and labor had little to do with the poor agricultural performance during this time. As shown in table A4, the parameter for DUM was highly significant statistically (that is, the probability of a greater t?value under the null hypothesis that the parameter's true' value is zero was less than 0.0001), indicating that non?weather factors other than capital and labor were indeed responsible for the associated growth slowdown in agriculture during 1979-82. Comparison of Preliminary and Final Models To perform simulations with the model, it is important that the parameters be measured without significant bias. One source of bias common to econometric models is 'multicolinearity.' Multicolinearity is a sample problem for which the sample does not provide 'rich' enough information on the explanatory variables (such as BOTNDRY, WINTEMP, K, and L) to prevent one variable from inordinately influencing the parameter estimate of another variable. In other words, multicolinearity is a problem when the explanatory variables are not sufficiently independent to meet the requirements of the model. In the final model presented above, there is potential for multicolinearity between the functions al(W) and a3(P). One way to determine if multicolinearity is a problem is to compare parameter estimates of the full model with parameter estimates for a restricted model. Such a comparison can be made here by contrasting the preliminary model in table A2, which excludes 423(P), with the final model in table A3, which includes a,(P). Parameter A? (3 Unclassified Draft nprlaccifiari in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Table A4 Testing For Effects of the Industrial Growth Slowdown Model Log(Q/L) = A0 + Oalog(K/L) + A, + li,*HOINDRY + A3*(1/HOTNDRY) + A,*WINTEMP + As*DUM Parameter Estimates Variable Parameter Parameter estimate Standard error t for Ho: Parameter=0 Probability > Id Scale adjustmenta Capital A, 0.507255 elasticity 0 0.168434 0.0160888 10.469 0.0001 Weather variables intercepta Al 1.607773 HOTNDRY A, ?14.646667 4.41654502 ?3.316 0.0056 1/HOTNDRY A, ?0.042382 0.01635564 ?2.591 0.0224 WINTEMP A, 0.026284 0.00769052 3.418 0.0046 Dummy variable for 1979-82 A, ?0.104958 0.01952918 ?5.374 0.0001 Analysis of Variancea Degrees of Sum of Mean Probability of Durbin? Source Freedom Squares Square F?value a greater F Vr2 Watson D Model 5 0.10619527 0.02123905 23.222 0.0001 0.8606 1.552 Error 13 0.01188982 0.00091460 Corrected total 18 0.11808509 A? ;'1/ Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified a The parameter for the sum of Ao and AI was estimated to be 2.11503 with a standard error of 0.53949. Al was estimated using the value for Ao derived in table A2. A? Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified estimates for the two models differ very little. Furthermore, there is little difference in model predictions for years other than 1979-82 and 1986-87, as shown in table A5. In the final model, the function a3(P) adjusts for the additional non?weather factor influencing farm output during 1979-82 and 1986-87 and thus produces better predictions for those years. Most importantly, trends in the weather?adjusted farm output series created using the two models are almost identical (see table A5), even for 1979-82 and 1986-87. These results indicate strongly that if multicolinearity between weather and the productivity change variable exists, it is not biasing parameter estimates for the weather variables to any significant extent. Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified 'fable A5 Billion 1982 Rubles Comparison of Preliminary and Final Models Farm Output Predicted Weather-Adjusted Farm Output Year Actual Data Final Model Preliminary Model Final Model Preliminary Model Differencea 1968 105.061 106.393 106.242 105.757 105.901 -0.144 1969 100.303 100.732 101.856 105.939 104.788 1.151 1970 112.535 112.464 111.797 108.749 109.428 -0.679 1971 111.388 110.707 110.350 109.685 110.094 -0.409 1972 104.660' 104.986 105.826 110.766 109.962 0.804 1973 121.807 119.841 118.830 115.747 116.833 -1.086 1974 119.629 121.073 120.394 115.221 115.994 -0.773 1975 109.410 109.094 108.309 118.221 119.233 -1.012 1976 118.060 114.802 115.811 122.192 121.312 0.880 1977 122.829 123.288 123.185 120.685 120.986 -0.301 1978 126.605 125.758 125.201 124.472 125.252 -0.780 1979 118.927 120.991 126.886 116.730 117.106 -0.376 1980 113.740 113.732 125.816 114.749 114.608 0.141 1981 112.500 111.332 127.930 112.040 113.135 -1.095 1982 120.788 120.174 -138.134 114.578 115.672 -1.094 1983 128.638 130.706 136.083 126.500 127.892 -1.392 1984 128.046 129.277 129.442 133.780 133.955 -0.175 1985 125.992 127.435 129.114 132:537 131.169 1.368 1986 136.287 134.448 128.699 142.117 141.792 0.325 1987 132.032 131.575 127.060 139.566 138.048 1.518 a Final model predictions minus preliminary model predictions. A- 17 Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Appendix B Data Parameters of the model were estimated using data from 1968 through 1986. The period was not extended to 1987 because employment data for 1987 were not available at the time of the study, and only preliminary data on farm output were available. Agricultural Capital Stock The Soviet definition of fixed capital includes the undepreciated value of buildings, structures, conveying equipment, machinery and equipment (including measurement and control instruments, laboratory equipment, and computer hardware), vehicles, tools, and productive and draft livestock of basic herds (but excluding young livestock, livestock allocated for fattening, and some minor categories such as poultry, rabbits, and fur?bearing animals). Fixed capital is broken down into productive and non?productive capital. Productive capital is that used directly in the production process. Nonproductive capital includes capital in the housing and municipal services sector and in organizations and institutions of public health,-education, science, culture, art, credit institutions, and administrative organs. For use in fitting the model, nonproductive fixed capital was excluded, as was productive livestock. The data used are shown in Table Bl. B? I Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Table B1 Productive Fixed Capital Stock and Capital Investment in Soviet Agriculture Year Beginning?of?year capital stock (in comparable 1973 prices) Capital investment (in comparable 1984 prices)c Including livestock' Excluding livestockb 1965 72 49 10.600 1966 77 54 11.308 1967 82 58 12.069 1968 87 63 13.466 1969 93 69 14.029 1970 98 74 16.000 1971 106 82 18.410 1972 116 91 20.151 1973 126 101 22.249 1974 140 113 24.179 1975 154 127 26.100 1976 167 141 27.190 1977 180 153 27.910 1978 194 167 28.895 1979 209 181 29.519 1980 223 195 29.800 1981 238 210 30.500 ,1982 254 225 30.925 1983 272 242 31.978 1984 288 258 31.000 1985 303 272 31.500 1986 316 286 33.500 1987 330 300 a Narodnove khozvaystvo SSSR za 70 let., Central Statistical Administration, Moscow, 1987, p. 100, and other years. Based on indexes published in Narodnoye khozvavstvo SSSR za 70 let., Central Statistical Administration, Moscow, 1987, p. 101, and other years. c Narodnoye khozvaystvo SSSR za 70 let., Central Statistical Administration, Moscow, 1987, p. 276, and other years. Unclassified ThisThis table is Unclassified. Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Employment in Agriculture Agricultural workers fall into four basic categories--workers and employees on state farms, collective farmers, persons engaged in private farming, and temporary workers recruited from nonfarm industries, the military, and schools to help during peak agricultural periods, primarily the harvest season. The Soviets report average annual employment statistics for state and collective farms as well as the number of workers involved in temporary seasonal activity. From this information, an estimate of total work hours in socialized agriculture can be made (see table B2). The Soviets do not report statistics on average annual employment in private agriculture, but they do report data on the number of livestock on private farms and the area allocated for private plots. Using a method developed by the U.S. Department of Commerce, Center for International Research, an estimate of private employment can be derived from this information (see table B3).1 This is done using labor coefficients obtained from the Soviet literature, as follows: Activity Input required per unit (man?days) Cultivation of one sown hectare Tending one head of cattle Tending one pig Tending one sheep or goat 166.0 54.2 20.6 5.6 1. See Stephen Rapawy, Estimates and Projections of the Labor Force and Civilian Employment in the USSR 1950 to 1990, Foreign Economic Report No. 10, US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, September 1976, p. 43. B? Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified 'fable B2 Employment in Socialized Agriculture Employment (million workers) Man-days Hours worked per per ronth year per worker Total hours 'worked (millions) state collective state collective state collective state collective Year farms farms recruits total farms farms farms farms farms farms recruits total (1) (2) -(3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) 1968 8.548 15.782 0.5 1907 1580 16,299 24,934 790 42,023 1969 8.725 15.010 0.6 1890 1585 16,490 23,798 951 41,240 1970 8.833 14.667 0.6 24.1 22.8 19.2 1915 1613 16,917 23,655 968 41,540 1971 9.122 13.478 0.7 23.3 1924 1630 17,547 21,973 1141 40,661 1972 9.244 13.456 0.8 23.5 1924 1651 17,782 22,210 1320 41,313 1973 9.462 13.238 0.9 23.6 1932 1669 18,281 22,092 1502 41,874 1974 9.656 13.044 0.9 23.6 1932 1694 18,655 22,097 1525 42,277 1975 9.787 12.713 1.0 23.5 23.1 20.3 1940 1705 18,991 21,678 1705 42,374 1976 9.970 12.430 1.1 23.5 23.2 20.6 1949 1730 19,430 21,509 1903 42,842 1977 10.180 12.020 1.1 23.3 23.1 20.7 1940 1739 19,753 20,900 1913 42,566 1978 10.387 11.613 1.3 23.3 23.1 21.0 1940 1764 20,155 20,485 2293 42,933 1979 10.481 11.319 1.3 23.1 23.0 21.2 1932 1781 20,249 20,157 2315 42,721 1980 10.693 10.907 1.3 22.9 23.1 21.4 1940 1798 20,749 19,606 2337 42,692 1981 10.817 10.483 1.4 22.7 23.2 21.6 1949 1814 21,080 19,020 2540 42,641 1982 10.978 10.522 1.4 22.9 23.2 21.8 1949 1831 21,394 19,268 2564 43,225 1983 11.098 10.402 1.5 23.0 23.2 22.2 1949 1865 21,628 19,398 2797 43,823 1984 11.102 10.198 1.5 22.8 23.2 22.3 1949 1873 21,636 19,103 2810 43,548 1985 11.095 9.905 1.4 22.4 23.1 22.4 1940 1882 21,529 18,637 2634 42,800 1986 10.968 9.632 1.4 22.0 23.1 22.4 1940 1882 21,282 18,124 2634 42,040 Sources: Column Column (2): (1): Narodnove khozyaystvo SSSR za 70 let., Central Statistical Administration, Moscow, 1987, P. 86, and other years. Column (4) minus column (1) minus col?rmn (3). Values for 1968-69 were taken from Stephen Rapawy, Civilian Employment in the USSR 1950 to 1983, CIR Staff Paper No. 10, US Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, August 1985, p. 31. Columns (3) and (4): Narodnove khozyaystvo SSSR za 70 let., Central Statistical years. Administration, Moscow, 1987, p. 300, and other Column (5): Narodnove khozyaystvo SSSR za 70 let., Central Statistical years. Administration, Moscow, 1987, P. 292, and other Column (6): Narodnoye khozyaystvo SSSR za 70 let., Central Statistical years. Administration, Moscow, 1987, p. 288, and other Column (7): Column (5) multiplied by 12 months per year Values for 1968-69 and 1971-74 were derived and 7 hours per day. from data reported by Stephen Rapawy, Civilian Employment in the USSR 1950 to 1983, CIR Staff Paper No. 10, US Department of Commerce, August 1985, p. 29. Bureau of the Census, t This table is Unclassified. Draft Unclassified Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Column (8): Column (6) multiplied by 12 Months per year and 7-hours per day. Values for 1968-69 and 1971-74 were derived from data reported by Stephen Rapawy, Civilian Employment in the USSR 1950 to 1983, CIR Staff Paper No. 10, US Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, August 1985, p. 31. Column (9): Column (1) multiplied by column (7). Column (10): Column (2) multiplied by column (8). Column (11): Column (3) multiplied by column (8). Column (12): Column (9) plus column (10) plus column (11). This table is Unclassified. - Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Table B3 Employment in Private Agriculture and Total Employment Private agriculture Unclassified Number of productive livestock (end of year, millions) year cattle swine (1) (2) 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975' 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 '1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 sheep and goats (3) Sown area (million hectares) (4) Total hours worked (millions) (5) Total hours worked in agriculture (millions) (6) 27.3 12.8 34.4 25.0 13.8 31.7 25.0 16.6 33.2 24.9 15.9 32.7 24.7 13.3 32.3 24.6 13.6 32.1 24.5 13.7 32.0 23.5 12.2 29.4 22.8 11.8 28.8 23.3 14.8 29.4 23.1 14.8 29.2 23.1 14.8 25.3 23.0 14.0 30.2 23.4 14.2 30.7 24.2 15.8 31.9 24.6 15.6 33.2 24.0 14.1 32.5 24.1 13.9 33.1 23.7 13.6 33.4 6.77 6.78 6.73 6.68 6.67 6.64 6.64 6.64 5.93 5.93 6.05 6.05 6.16 6.15 6.16 6.16 6.17 5.70 5.72 22,771 21,868 22,292 22,089 21,551 21,525 21,489 20,716 19,519 20,212 20,277 20,109 20,280 20,488 21,139 21,331 20,824 20,313 20,135 64,794 63,108 63,832 62,750 62,864 63,399 63,766 63,090 62,361 62,779 63,211 62,830 62,972 63,129 64,365 65,153 64,372 63,114 62,175 Sources: Columns Column Column Column (1), (2), and (3): Narodnove khozyaystvo SSSR za 70 let., Central Statistical Administration, Moscow, 1987, P. 253, and other years. Narodnove khozvavstvo SSSR za 70 let., Central Statistical Administration, Moscow, 1987, p. 225, and other years. Derived from columns (1), (2), and (3); see text. Column (5) plus column (12) from table B2. (4): (5): (6): '3-.' This table is Unclassified. Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified The total man?days for animal husbandry are increased by 10 percent to allow for labor involved in tending poultry, horses, and rabbits, which otherwise would not be included. Man?days are converted to total hours by multiplying by 7 hours per day, the same daily work rate assigned to state and collective farms. Weather Detailed meteorological data from the USSR are available through the World Meteorological Organization. As a member, the USSR shares such information with foreign countries. These data are part of a worldwide standardized system that attempts to insure consistent measures of weather parameters from year to year. Precipitation and temperature data are available for approximately 1,000 stations located throughout the grain?growing portion of the USSR.2 The US Air Force processes the data and applies corrective measures to overcome reporting errors and omissions. Although the original dataset extends to the mid-1940s, the 'correcteddataset begins in 1969. It was possible to use the 'uncorrected' weather data for 1968 and thus extend the dataset an additional year, but attempts to include years before 1968 in the model were unsuccessful.3 2. Summaries of the data for 27 crop regions are reported in Climate Impact Assessment, Foreign Countries, published by the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA). For the present study, eight additional crop regions were created, predominately in Siberia and Kazakhstan. 3. The two weather datasets also had different area definitions, and so it was necessary to link the two series. This was done for 1968 data as follows: B-7 Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified These data were used to calculate monthly precipitation and average monthly temperature for the agricultural area of the USSR. Two weighting schemes were used to aggregate the data. Precipitation and temperature for the variable HOTNDRY were weighted according to the area sown to all crops, whereas temperature data for WINTEMP were weighted according to area sown to winter wheat.4 HOTNDRY is the ratio of average temperature to cumulative precipitation for April through July. WINTEMP is the average temperature for October through March. The data and summary statistics for HOTNDRY and WINTEMP are shown in Table B4 (also see figure B1). The mean and standard deviation were used to generate a probability distribution for each variable in order to conduct the stochastic simulation exercise. HOTNDRY and WINTEMP are positively correlated; the Pearson correlation coefficient measured 0.595 (with a standard error of 0.139). That is, when WINTEMP is high, HOTNDRY is often--but not always--high 'corrected' value for 1969 Value for 1968 ? x 'uncorrected' value for 1968 'uncorrected' value for 1969 4. The calculation was made as follows: 35 I Share of total L area in area i Is i=1 Weather data for area i = Weighted weather data B? % Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Table B4 Weather Data HOTNDRY WINTEKP Data 1968 0.065680 -0.03 1969 0.052343 -2.60 1970 0.059621 0.15 1971 0.062416 -0.10 1972 0.066987 -1.50 1973 0.059346 0.60 1974 0.052102 0.00 1975 0.085941 2.10 1976 0.058007 -1.90 1977 0.056889 -0.50 1978 0.046413 -0.10 1979 0.059482 -0.30 1980 0.049892 -1.20 1981 0.073477 1.40 1982 0.058703 0.60 1983 0.072209 1.50 1984 0.074187 0.20 1985 0.053265 -2.50 1986 0.069834 -0.60 1987 0.059304 -2.40 Percentilesa 99% 0.085942 2.1 90% 0.074187 1.5 75% 0.069834 0.6 50% (median) 0.059483 -0.1 25% 0.053266 -1.5 10% 0.049892 -2.5 1% 0.046414 -2.6 Mean Standard deviation 0.061613 -0.376 0.0099342 1.36426 NOTE: Neither of these distributions were significantly different from the normal distribution. Data for 1968 were excluded from calculations of summary statistics. a A percentile represents the probability that a value equal to or less than the tabled value would be expected to occur, based on the 19 observations in the original frequency distribution. For example, a value of HOTNDRY equal to or less than 0.053266 (the value for the 25th percentile) would be expected to occur about one-in-four years, on average. Unclassified This table is Unclassified. Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 0.09- 0.08- 0.07 - 0 ? 0.06- ? 0.05- 0.04 ' Degrees Centigrade 1967 3., Figure B1 Roo of Temperature to Preciptation, April?July (HOTNDRY) ? 0 ? ? ? ? ? ? ? ? ? ? May 2. 1968 Averooe ? 1969 1971 1973 1975 1977. 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 Average Winter Temperature October?March (WINTEMP) 3 ? ? ' 19 67 1969 1971 197 3 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 NEWAC137-BENN:Th. Average Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified as well. Consequently, simulated values for HOTNDRY and WINTEMP were created such that this correlation was preserved; the Pearson correlation coefficient of simulated values was 0.585. Farm Output The Soviet measure of gross agricultural output is inadequate for modeling purposes because no adjustment is made for intra?agricultural use of farm products (such as seed and animal feed) and because Soviet gross output statistics include a large element of waste. The measure of farm output used in this study--net farm output--is the sum of livestock production and crop production, less seed, feed and waste, valued in average 1982 realized prices. Derivation of the series has previously been described in detail.5 Net farm output is based on a sample of 28 individual crops, 10 livestock products, and four items of livestock inventory change. These 42 products account for .nearly 95 percent of total farm output net of intrafarm use of crops. Value?Added Farm Output Total factor productivity was calculated usilig value?added farm output. Value?added farm output excludes not only production for intrafarm use, but it also excludes the value of materials and services purchased by agriculture on current account from nonagricultural sectors (current purchases). The time 5. See Barabara Severin and Margaret Hughes, Part III. An Index of Agricultural Production in the USSR, in 'USSR: Measures of Economic Growth and Development, 1950-80,' Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, December 1982, pp. 245-316. B? H Unclassified Draft Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified series for current purchases is based on 10 indexes of material inputs.6 Weather-adjusted farm output is converted to a value-added measure according to the method presented in table BS. 6. See John Pitzer, Part I. Gross National Product of the USSR, 1950-80, in 'USSR: Measures of Economic Growth and Development, 1950-80,' Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, December 1982, pp. 88-91. B- Unclassified Draft L, Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4 Unclassified Table B5 Derivation of Value-Added, Weather-Adjusted Farm Output Year Weather-adjusted farm output Gross weather-adjusted output including current purchases (billion rubles) (3) Current purchases (billion rubles) (4) Value-added weather- adjusted output billion rubles index (1) (2) billion rubles index (5) (6) 1968 105.757 0.923 120.361 20.1494 100.211 1.000 1969 105.939 0.924 120.568 20.9693 99.599 0.993 1970 108.749 0.949 123.766 21.6942 102.072 1.018 1971 109.685 0.957 124.831 22.7634 102.068 1.018 1972 110.766 0.966 126.062 24.2611 101.801 1.015 1973 115.747 1.010 131.730 25.9391 105.791 1.055 1974 115.221 1.005 131.132 27.5947 103.537 1.033 1975 118.221 1.031 134.546 29.2831 105.262 1.050 1976 122.192 1.066 139.066 28.3749 110.691 1.104 1977 120.685 1.053 137.350 31.1685 106.182 1.059 1978 124.472 1.086 141.661 31.6678 109.993 1.097 1979 116.730 1.018 132.850 32.1303 100.719 1.005 1980 114.749 1.001 130.595 33.1553 97.440 0.972 1981 112.040 0.977 127.511 34.0618 93.450 0.932 1.982 114.578 1.000 130.400 35.2400 95.160 0.949 4983 126.500 1.104 143.968 37.8364 106.132 1.059 1984 133.780 1.167 152.254 39.1360 113.118 1.128 1985 132.537 1.156 150.839 41.0018 109.838 1.096 1986 142.117 1.240 161.742 42.7994 118.943 1.186 1987 139.566 1.218 158.839 43.6574 115.182 1.149 Sources: Column (1): Weather-adjusted output series from table 3. Column (2): Column (1) divided by 114.578, the value of weather-adjusted output for 1982. Column (3): Column (2) multiplied by 130.4 billion rubles, which is the 1982 gross value of farm output estimated by extending the 1972 .input-output table forward to 1982. It represents complete coverage of gross output less interfarm use, as opposed to the net farm output measure used in this study which is based on a sample. Column (4): Current purchases. Column (5): Column (3) minus column (4). Column (6): Column (5) divided by 100.211, the value of value-added weather-adjusted output for 1968. This table is Unclassified. Unclassified Draft L.. Declassified in Part - Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2013/09/30: CIA-RDP90G01353R001800180004-4