INDUSTRIAL COUNTRY SPREADSHEET TRADE MODELS: NEW TOOLS FOR ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
C
Document Page Count: 
31
Document Creation Date: 
December 22, 2016
Document Release Date: 
February 7, 2012
Sequence Number: 
2
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
December 1, 1986
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9.pdf1.23 MB
Body: 
Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Directorate of Intelligence For Economic Analysis teat ~~ ~CIr'~t.~D/~~ ~ et~~~l~~c4 tai? Industrial Country Spreadsheet Trade Models: New Tools EUR 86-10045 December 1986 Copy 3 7 9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 l- - _ I I..-JJ~I_..~..-- -~-~_L____ - Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Industrial Country Spreadsheet a Trade Models: New Tools Directorate of Intelligence for Economic Analysis This paper was prepared by the Office of European Analysis. European Division, EURA, Comments and requests for copies of the models are welcome and may be directed to the Chief, West Confidential EUR 86-10045 December 1986 25X1 25X1 25X1 j Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential 25X1 Preface /nJormation available as oJ' 17 October 1986 was used in this report. Industrial Country Spreadsheet Trade Models: New Tooh for Economic Analysis Econometric models for mainframe computers have become conventional tools for analyzing international trade flows. In a system of equations, a model combines a theoretical representation of the economy, a statistical analysis of the key relationships, and assumptions about external events. The solution of the system of equations produces conditional estimates of the future and can be used to estimate an economy's sensitivity to alternative sets of assumptions about future developments. The advent of economic spreadsheets, designed to operate in the personal computer (PC) environment, provides an alternative approach to quantita- tive economic analysis. Economic spreadsheets greatly reduce maintenance costs and allow for greater accessibility by analysts with a minimum of training in computer use. This project combines the standard econometric modeling approach with the spreadsheet approach through the use of simple econometric models that reside in complex PC spreadsheets. As a result, advanced econometric methods are put to work in an environment that can be maintained and used with a minimal expenditure of time and resources. The industrial country spreadsheet trade models can be used to examine the impact of price, income, and exchange-rate changes on GDP and the balance of payments. Specifically, the models are designed to gauge the effects of changes in the prices of food, energy, raw materials, and manufactured goods on import and export demand. The models are also capable of estimating income effects across trading partners through the impact on import and export demand. Because exchange rates play a prominent role in the models by converting export prices into partner import prices, the models can be used to measure the impact of exchange- rate changes on domestic and trading-partner GDP and balance of payments. The results obtained from balance-of-payments models for each of the developed countries, combined with a simple model of world trade relationships, are described in this paper. The first section gives a brief overview of the methodologies used and explains how to interpret the results. The second section examines the individual balance-of-payments model for each country. The third section demonstrates potential uses of the models, including the calculation of price and income influences on the Confidential EUR 86-10045 December 1986 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 I I _ 1 I ~ .I ___1 .LII 1 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential balance of payments. The fourth section describes the linkage model that measures the impact of changes in any particular country on the rest of the world. The final section demonstrates typical uses for the model by examining the transmission of changes in GDPs, price levels, and exchange rates between individual countries and country groups. Several appendixes describe in greater detail the methodologies used to obtain the results. Confidential iv Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Contents Page Preface iii Introduction 1 Individual Country Balance-of-Payments Models: Basic Structure 1 The Demand for Imports 1 The Demand for Exports 2 Balance-of-Payments Aggregates 3 Using the Country Models: Income and Price Effects 4 Income Effects 4 Price Effects 6 The Trade Linkage Model: Description 8 Structure of the Linkage Model 8 Import Determination 9 Import-Price Determination 9 Examples of Using the Trade Linkage Model 9 Impact of Changes in Big Seven Import Demand 9 Dependence on Exports to Communist Countries 9 The Impact of Exchange-Rate Changes 10 Appendixes A. Big Seven Exchange-Rate Effects C. Regression Results E. Trade-Share Linkage Model r Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Industrial Country Spreadsheet Trade Models: New Tools for Economic Analysis This paper examines a set of spreadsheet models of the balance of payments of OECD countries and the trade linkages between those countries and their trading partners. Each OECD member ' is modeled separately, and the rest of the world is divided into four aggregate groups: OPEC, Communist countries, newly industrialized countries (NICs), and other de- veloping countries. The methodology used here in- volves aggregate trade in goods and services broken down into five major commodity groups: agricultural products, raw materials, energy, manufactured goods, and services. The individual country models operate on semiannual data and are generally based on rela- tionships estimated over the 1970-85 period. The linkage model joins the countries through trade-share analysis: each country's exports depend on its trade partners' imports, and import prices depend on part- ner export prices. The individual balance-of-payments models and the linkage model have been designed primarily to deter- mine the degree of trade interdependence between countries and their trading partners. These models can be used to measure the quantitative impact of income, price, and exchange-rate changes in any country or group of countries on all of its trading partners. More specifically, the individual country models are used to assess the impact on a particular country of: ? Changes in world income or world prices. ? Changes in that country's income or prices. The linkage model is used (with the country models) to assess the impact on one or more countries of: ? Changes in income or prices in another country. ? Changes in exchange rates. ' The United States is included as a trade partner and for compari- son purposes. Individual Country Balance-of-Payments Models: Basic Structure Each country's balance-of-payments model is stored in a separate spreadsheet containing detailed histori- cal data, forecasts for exogenous variables, and re- gression coefficients. The various elements interact to produce conditional forecasts of key endogenous vari- ables, including the current account balance. Imports and exports of different categories of goods and services are endogenous to the model; prices, income, and transfers are all exogenous. A detailed display of key sections of the model is shown in appendix D. The Demand for Imports The demand for imports is divided into four categories of goods plus a services category: ? Food products. ? Raw materials. ? Energy. ? Manufactures. ? Services. For each of the OECD countries, regression analysis was used to relate the demand for a given category to the country's income, the price of the goods within the specific category, and a Koyck-lag term to capture long-run effects. The estimation techniques are dis- cussed in appendix B, and the estimated coefficients may be found in appendix C. The demand for a given import category is positively related to domestic in- come (that is, as a country's income rises, demand for the good also rises); it is negatively related to price (as the price rises, demand for the good falls). The relative price of imports is defined as the ratio of the import price for a particular category to its export price, which serves as a proxy for the competing domestic price. No attempt is made to estimate price elasticities for services, because reliable price data are unavailable. The demand for a given import category in any period is also positively related to the quantity Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Table 1 Imports of Goods: Income and Price Elasticities Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential imported in the previous period. This single lagged term indicates a declining, infinite lag structure; the quantity imported each period depends on income and price in all of the previous periods. The estimated income and price elasticities have the expected signs, and their summary statistics are shown in table 1. This table displays the average short-run and long-run elasticities across countries for both price and income; the largest values among the countries are also reported-the smallest value, zero, is not shown. In some cases, significant results were not obtained with the regression structure outlined above. The alternate forms used for these regressions are explained in appendix C. Our regression analysis yielded insignificant coeffi- cients for some of the countries within each category of imports. In the cases of Greece, Iceland, Portugal, Spain, and Turkey, this result is due to a lack of data prior to 1982. As more data become available, our estimation of these coefficients should improve. Insignificant elasticities of demand were estimated in some cases. Insufficient data were responsible for most of these estimation problems, as some countries only reported data from 1982. Among those countries reporting data since 1970, a few, with small domestic production in a particular import category, had inelas- tic demand functions-for example, Japan for raw materials and several other countries for energy. The Demand for Exports The demand for exports is divided into four categories of goods plus a services category: ? Food products. ? Raw materials. ? Energy. ? Manufactures. ? Services. For each of the OECD countries, regression analysis was used to relate the demand for a given category to world income and the price of the goods within the specific category, and a Koyck-lag term was used to capture long-run effects. The estimated coefficients may be found in appendix C. The demand for a given Short run -0.60 (Turkey) -0.19 Long run -1.49 (Netherlands) -0.33 Income Short run 1.77 (France) 0.69 Long run 4.18 (Belgium) 1.23 Raw materials Price Short run -1.15 (Denmark) -0.33 Long run -3.45 (Switzerland) -0.72 Income Short run 1.18 (Netherlands) 0.38 Long run 3.62 (Switzerland) 0.75 Energy _ Price Short run -0.55 (Portugal) -0.08 Long run -1.62 (France) -0.26 Income Short run 1.30 (Portugal) 0.11 Long run 2.88 (Germany) 0.31 Manufactures Price Short run -1.42 (Sweden) -0.58 Long run -4.21 (Ireland) -1.26 Income Short run 4.10 (Turkey) 1.05 Long run 4.92 (Finland) 1.91 Services export category is positively related to world income (that is, as the world's income rises, demand for the good also rises). Because it is a more reliable data series, total OECD income is used as a proxy for Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 __ i .._..~ - -- ~. l.. Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential world income. Export demand is negatively related to price (as the price rises, demand for the good falls). The relative price of exports is defined as the ratio of the export price for a particular category to its import price, which serves as a proxy for the competing world price. No attempt is made to estimate price elasticities for services, because reliable price data are unavail- able. The demand for a given export category is positively related to the quantity exported in the previous period. This lagged term indicates a declin- ing, infinite lag structure; the quantity exported each period depends on income and price in all of the previous periods. The estimated income and price elasticities have the expected signs, and their summary statistics are shown in table 2. This table displays the average short-run and long-run elasticities across countries for both price and income; the largest values among the countries are also reported. In some cases, country data do not conform to the regression structure outlined above. Details concerning the forms that were adopted in these cases and the logic underlying the adopted forms may be found in appendix C. Inelastic demand functions were estimated in several cases among countries reporting data since 1970. These results apply to countries with small domestic production of the export categories involved, particu- larly raw materials and energy. In the case of agricul- ture, the prevalence of government subsidy schemes also plays an important role in determining the esti- mated elasticities. Balance-of-Payments Aggregates The export and import volumes of total goods theoret- ically equal the sums of the component volumes of food, raw materials, energy, and manufactures. Data- reporting anomalies, however, lead to some divergence between these series. To adjust for these divergences, Table 2 Export of Goods: Income and Price Elasticities Short run -1.27 (United States) -0.29 Long run -3.07 (United States) -12.21 Income Short run 1.78 (Sweden) 0.50 Long run 3.08 (Sweden) 0.96 Raw materials Price Short run -0.84 (Canada) -0.20 Long run -1.50 (Canada) -0.31 Income Short run 1.98 (Netherlands) 0.45 Long run 2.45 (Netherlands) 0.67 Energy Price Short run -4.09 (Norway) -0.46 Long run - 24.40 (Norway) -2.69 Income Short run 5.33 (New Zealand) 0.73 Long run 25.72 (New Zealand) 3.04 Manufactures Price Short run -1.17 (United States) -0.35 Long run -5.86 (Japan) -1.01 Income Short run 1.81 (Australia) 0.63 Long run 4.52 (Netherlands) 1.46 Services bridge equations are employed for exports and im- goods export and import prices. Instead, bridge equa- ports using a simple regression of total goods volume tions are employed for exports and imports using the against the sum of the volume components. This simple regression of aggregate price against the methodology is discussed in appendix B, and the weighted average of the individual prices. The regres- regression results may be found in appendix C. Sion results may be found in appendix C. The existence of data anomalies for many countries also prevented the use of a simple weighted average of commodity prices in the derivation of the aggregate ~ Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Table 3 Domestic GDP: Impact on the Current Account Balance a Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential A similar problem arises in the conversion from total goods volumes and prices to nominal dollar values of exports and imports. Bridge equations are employed in this case to adjust for these data anomalies. The regression results may be found in appendix C. The current account balance is defined as the sum of the trade balance, exports of services, investment income credits, ofTicial transfers, and private transfers minus imports of services and investment income debits-all reported in .dollars. The merchandise trade balance is defined as the dollar value of goods exports minus goods imports. Private and official transfers along with investment income credits and debits are taken to be exogenous to the model. Using the Country Models: Income and Price Effects One of the principal assets of these models is their ability to assess the quantitative impact of economic growth and inflation on a country's exports, imports, and current account balance. Specifically, they are designed to answer questions such as: ? What is the effect of a given change in the world price of food, energy, raw materials, or manufac- tures on the current account balance of a specific country? ? What is the effect of a given change in a country's real income on the current account balance and import volume of that country? ? What is the effect of a given change in world income on the current account balance and export volume of a specified country? ? What is the impact on a country's real GDP of changes in imports or exports due to price and income changes? Income Effects Two sets of scenarios were used to examine the responsiveness of each country to domestic and world income changes. For the first scenario, domestic income is increased by 1 percent with no change in world income or prices. The resulting impact on the current account balance of each country is displayed in table 3, while table 4 shows the impact on import Australia - 87 -119 -151 Austria -747 -805 -837 Belgium -622 -803 -923 Canada -1,059 -1,578 -1,800 Denmark -231 -261 -283 Finland -224 -423 -470 France -6,285 -9,268 -10,562 Greece -39 -39 -39 Iceland NEGL NEGL NEGL Ireland -121 -209 -274 Italy -1,613 -2,066 -2,253 Japan -1,192 -1,638 -1,820 Netherlands -816 -1,181 -1,439 New Zealand -112 -136 -148 Norway -233 -288 -318 Portugal -74 -83 -84 Spain -151 -225 -274 Sweden -734 -809 -860 Switzerland -488 -676 -832 Turkey -250 -279 -270 United Kingdom - 3,264 -4,704 - 5,361 United States -6,015 -9,545 -11,309 West Germany -4,286 -6,428 -7,564 a Changes in current account balance due to a 1-percent increase in domestic GDP. volumes. In each case, import volume increases and the current account balance deteriorates by an amount that increases over time. This type of scenario can be used to estimate the impact of unexpected changes in GDP on a country's current account balance. The data in table 3 show that Japan's current account balance changes by only $2 billion after three years of a 1-percent change in Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 -- 1 .. - - - Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Table 4 Domestic GDP: Impact on Goods Import Volumes a Percentage change in import volume due to a 1-percent increase in domestic GDP. Table 5 World Income: Impact on Current Account Balances a Finland 182 273 322 France 2,285 3,101 3,480 Greece 67 81 84 Iceland 3 4 4 Ireland 64 69 70 Italy 699 788 892 Japan 1,827 3,119 4,251 Netherlands 1,674 2,522 3,018 New Zealand 52 59 68 Norway 334 482 659 Portugal 81 89 95 Spain 375 380 390 Sweden 715 933 1,033 Switzerland 524 659 709 Turkey 273 298 329 United Kingdom 1,482 2,388 2,916 United States 1,936 3,510 4,514 West Germany 2,444 3,602 4,271 a Change in current account balance due to a 1-percent increase in world income. GDP, demonstrating a low level of sensitivity to domestic changes. France's current account balance is much more sensitive to changes in domestic GDP, however, shifting by nearly $11 billion after three years in response to a 1-percent change in GDP. The second scenario measures the effect on each country of a 1-percent increase in world income assuming no change in domestic income or prices. The resulting changes in current account balances and export volumes are displayed in tables 5 and 6. As expected, export volume and the current account balance increases over time for each country. This type of scenario can be used to measure the sensitivity of individual countries to changes in the world economy. In this case, the current account balance in Japan is more sensitive to income changes than in France. Japan would suffer a deterioration of over $4 billion after three years of a 1-percent reduction in world income, while France's current account balance would be reduced by only $3.5 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 1. __ __ L I I I I I I. I I I I I _ 1 _ L____.-_ I __ L .I III Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Table 6 World Income: Impact on Goods Export Volumes a Percent First Year Se cond Year Th ird Year Australia 1.0 1.2 1.2 Austria 1.7 2.2 2.2 Belgium 0.6 0.8 0.9 Canada 0.9 1.5 1.7 Denmark 1.2 2.0 2.2 Finland 0.9 1.5 1.8 France 1.4 2.1 2.3 Greece 0.9 1.3 1.4 Iceland NE GL NE GL NE GL Ireland NE GL NE GL NE GL Italy 0.2 0.3 0.4 Japan 0.6 1.3 1.8 Netherlands 1.9 3.1 3.7 New Zealand 0.3 0.7 1.2 Norway 2.2 5.2 8.4 Portugal 0.1 0.1 0.1 Spain 0.2 0.2 0.2 Sweden 1.6 2.1 2.2 Switzerland 1.1 1.4 1.5 Turkey 0.1 0.1 0.1 United Kingdom 1.1 2.0 2.4 United States 0.8 1.3 ].6 West Germany 0.7 1.2 1.4 Percentage change in export volume due to a 1-percent increase in world income. billion. Although its economy is much smaller, Cana- da would suffer a disproportionate deterioration in its current account balance of over $2 billion because of its heavy reliance on foreign trade. Price Effects Four scenarios were examined for each country to analyze the impact of changes in the world price of each of the goods categories. For each scenario, one country was examined independently and faced a 10-percent increase in both the export and import Table 7 Food Prices: Impact on Current Account Balances a a Change in current account balance due to a 10-percent increase in world food prices. price of a particular commodity. Countries that ex- port more of the product than they import will generally register improvements in their current ac- count balances, and the reverse is true for countries that import more than they export. The relative price elasticities of import and export demand also play an important role in this analysis, leading to unexpected results for some countries. The results are summa- rized in tables 7-10. 25X1 25X1 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Table 8 Energy Prices: Impact on Current Account Balances a Million US $ Table 9 Raw Materials Prices: Impact on Current Account Balances a Change in current account balance due to a 10-percent increase in world energy prices. Ireland 20 17 16 Italy -845 -921 -984 Japan -1,677 -1,902 -2,085 Netherlands -25 -47 -41 New Zealand 98 100 104 Norway -35 -38 -39 Portugal 4 3 4 Spain -324 -333 -339 Sweden 210 223 234 Switzerland -85 -97 -100 Turkey -188 -230 -230 United Kingdom -372 -416 -450 United States 980 1,319 1,536 West Germany -509 -578 -632 a Change in current account balance due to a 10-percent increas25X1 world raw material prices. This type of scenario would prove very helpful in measuring the impact of the large energy price in- creases and decreases that have occurred over the past several years and are expected to recur in the future. The results in table 8 clearly show the gainers and losers-with respect to the current account bal- ances-of an increase in energy prices. Norway, the United Kingdom, Australia, and the Netherlands are identified as enjoying improved current account bal- ances as a result of increases in the price of energy. Japan and the United States suffer the largest deteri- oration in current account balance in this scenario. In some cases the impact on the current account balance reverses over time, indicating differing short- run and long-run elasticities. In table 7, for example, the current account balance of the United States worsens in the first year following an increase in food prices, but improves in later years. This outcome is a direct result of the estimated coefficients; these show j Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Table 10 Manufacturing Export Prices: Impact on Current Account Balances a Austria -2,210 -6,580 -6,750 Belgium -41 -2,453 -2,959 Canada -2,456 -8,014 -10,577 Denmark 1,944 2,011 2,137 Finland 422 376 317 France 351 -5,882 -7,593 Greece -16 -60 -58 Iceland 39 43 47 Ireland -546 -2,194 -3,610 Italy -2769 -2,083 -2,160 Japan -167 -22,498 -38,064 Netherlands 3,804 2,223 1,453 New Zealand -622 -874 -972 Norway 974 412 210 Portugal 478 321 329 Spain 2,690 1,953 1,363 Sweden -926 -1,620 -1,763 Switzerland -1,365 -5,029 -7,590 Turkey 158 -26 -3 United Kingdom -387 -7,992 -11,575 United States -38,430 -82,576 -107,050 West Germany -8,793 -29,616 -39,555 a Change in current account balance due to a 10-percent increase in manufacturing export prices. that the long-run elasticity of demand for food im- ports is high relative to both the short-run elasticity of demand for food imports and the long-run elasticity of demand for food exports. The Trade Linkage Model: Description A simplified model linking all of the countries, but without commodity detail, is stored in a separate spreadsheet containing historical data on export and import volumes, price indexes, and bilateral trade flows. Trade shares and the effects of trade interde- pendence are estimated by the interaction of these different elements. The model performs all of the necessary conversions between dollars and other cur- rencies and between real and nominal values. Key sections of the model are displayed in appendix E. Specifically, the model is designed to answer ques- tions such as: ? What is the effect of a change in the domestic demand of a particular country on the GDPs and balances of payments of its trade partners? ? What is the effect of a change in the price of a country's exports on the import price faced by its trade partners? ? What are the impacts of particular exchange-rate changes on other countries? Structure of the Linkage Model The linkage model consists of selected trade, income, and price data for each of the OECD countries and aggregates for the Communist countries, OPEC, the NICs, and the rest of the world. Real GDP for each reporter is broken down into domestic demand, ex- ports, and imports. Domestic demand is considered exogenous to the model; exports of goods and services are a function of partner imports of goods and services and bilateral trade shares; and imports are a function of relative prices and domestic income. Price indexes for both imports and exports are included, with export prices exogenous and import prices a function of partner export prices. Dollar exchange rates and bilateral trade-flow data are included as exogenous to the model. The key element of the model is the trade-share. matrix, which measures the bilateral trade flows between each pair of reporters. Through this matrix, an increase in any country's export price will feed into its partners' import price, thus affecting the partner country's import demand. Similarly, changes in im- port demand will affect partner countries' exports. Because exchange rates play a role in the conversion of export prices into import prices, they also contrib- ute to the interactions. Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 _ - -. _- _ _ ......._ ... __._.. . L..__ Jd.~ i _ . ,L l _ _ 1 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential The spreadsheet produces summary tables that pro- vide results for key variables, including GDP growth rates, current account balances in dollars, and real effective exchange rates. These figures are calculated using all of the simultaneous interactions present in the model. Import Determination Real imports of goods and services are estimated as a function of domestic demand and the relative price of imports, using a geometrically declining infinite lag structure. The values of the coefficients are calculated using simulations of the individual country models, in order to reflect most accurately the actual elasticities. Each country has a different lag structure, which is consistent with the implicit values determined using its individual model. The level of import demand calculated by the model for each country is used in the determination of partner countries' exports. A country with 25 percent of the market in a country that increases its imports would receive a boost to its exports equal to 25 percent of the import increase. Because the model contains all countries of the world, any change in total imports will be met by an equal change in total exports throughout the rest of the world. Imports and exports are then combined with domestic demand to deter- mine real GDP for each country. Only domestic demand is determined exogenously in this model, using OECD forecasts in most cases. Import-Price Determination Each country's exogenously determined export price level feeds into its trading partners' import price levels. These prices feed through all of the relevant exchange rates in order to determine the actual relative prices. The weights applied to each export price in order to determine import prices are based on bilateral trade shares. Countries with very close trade relations will have closely interdependent prices. The determination of import and export prices, com- bined with the determination of import and export volumes, leads directly to the calculation of the current account balance for each country. Export prices, exchange rates, and trade shares also combine to determine real effective exchange rates for each country. Examples of Using the Trade Linkage Model The linkage model can be used (with the country models) to assess the impact on partner countries of changes in economic growth, inflation, and import demand in a particular country. Alternatively, it can be used to estimate the impact of exchange-rate changes. The model also offers a convenient way of calculating various economic data, such as real effec- tive exchange rates or imports as a share of GDP. Impacts of Changes in Big Seven Import Demand The trade linkage model can be used to estimate the impact of changes in import demand in particular countries on the GDP growth rates and the current account balances of their trade partners. For example, the scenarios displayed in table 11 show the effects of a 10-percent increase in the level of import demand by each of the Big Seven. The effects range from negligi- ble amounts for countries with little bilateral trade to a 3.3-percent increase in Irish GDP as a result of increased British imports. This type of scenario can be used to compare the effects of applying the same policy in different coun- tries. For example, the results in table 11 have implications for the encouragement of "locomotive" policies z in Japan and West Germany. According to model results, increases in West German import demand have a much larger impact on world GDP than increases in Japanese imports. Policymakers can compare the relative benefits of each country pursu- ing this type of policy. Dependence on Exports to Communist Countries Another example of the model's use is the estimation of the share of a country's GDP attributable directly or indirectly to exports to the Communist countries. This is done by comparing the baseline case to the case where exports to Communist countries are cut to zero. The calculated shares range from negligible for several countries to 0.5 percent of GDP for Finland ' Expansionary policies in key countries designed to increase world GDP through increased import demand. Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 i~ ~ I l i i i I I 1__ I 1 .I II I Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Table 11 Big Seven Import Demand: Impact on World GDP a Impact on real GDP growth of a 10-percent real increase in import demand. and are shown in table 12. Such calculations are very country's GDP, current account balance, and import straightforward in the linkage model because GDP price index. The direct effect will result from a and bilateral trade data are available in an easily change in the price of imports from the country whose accessible spreadsheet. exchange rate has changed. Indirect effects result from the impacts on the import prices of other The Impact of Exchange-Rate Changes The trade linkage model can estimate the impact of a change in a given exchange rate on any particular Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Table 12 Communist Import Demand: Contribution to Industrialized Country GDP a Table 13 Real Effective Exchange Rates: Movement Between March 1985 and September 1986 0.1 0.1 a DifTerence in GDP between the baseline case and the case where exports to Communist countries are cut to zero. 2.6 6.4 8.3 8.4 - 0.8 - 5.4 16.6 - 38.3 United States -22.1 25X1 West Germany 14.7 countries, which affect exports from the country in question. Appendix A displays the results of apprecia- tions of each of the Big Seven currencies. Other Uses The model's large data base can be used to easily make calculations that might otherwise be very time consuming. For example, the linkage model uses its trade-share, exchange-rate, and price data to calcu- late real effective exchange rates. Dollar exchange rates are deflated by unit labor costs for each country and then converted to implicit bilateral rates for every pair of countries. For a given reporter, weights are applied to each of its bilateral exchange rates on the basis of the importance of trade with the correspond- ing partner. Both imports and exports are included in the weighting, but less-developed and Communist countries are excluded. Table 13 shows the changes in real effective exchange rates since the dollar's peak early in 1985. Another example of using the model's data base is the calculation as a share of GDP of a country's exports to or imports from another geographic area. As an i Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Table 14 Imports From NICs a as a Share of GDP 3.0 4.2 3.6 1.7 2.4 0.7 Brazil, Mexico, Taiwan, South Korea, Singapore, and Hong Kong. illustration, table 14 shows, for each industrial coun- try, imports from the NICs as a share of GDP. Shares range from 0.7 percent in the United States to 6.6 percent in Canada. Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 _ L _ ---.----- _ . _ .. ._ .1_ Y_____.____`l~.-._LI , I I I Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Appendix A Big Seven Exchange-Rate Effects Table 15a Table 15b The US Dollar's Impact on The Japanese Yen's Impact on Industrialized Countries Industrialized Countries Real GDP Growth e (percentage points) Current Account Balance a (billion US $J First Year Second Year First Year Second Year Australia 0.2 0.3 -0.2 0.1 Austria 0.7 1.3 0.3 1.3 Belgium 0.3 0.6 -0.5 NEGL Canada 3.1 4.7 2.9 19.4 Denmark 0.3 0.6 NEGL 0.3 Finland 0.3 0.4 -0.1 0.2 France 0.3 0.6 0.1 2.8 Greece 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.3 Iceland I.0 1.7 0.1 0.1 Ireland 2.0 3.7 NEGL 0.6 Italy 0.4 0.7 1.1 4.1 Japan 1.1 1.7 -1.9 22.9 Netherlands 0.4 3.7 -1.0 -0.1 New Zealand 1.2 1.6 0.1 0.4 Norway 0.3 0.5 0.1 0.5 Portugal 0.4 0.7 0.1 0.2 Spain 0.4 0.6 0.1 1.5 Sweden 0.7 0.9 -0.1 1.1 Switzerland 0.6 1.0 NEGL 1.0 Turkey 0.3 0.6 0.1 0.5 United Kingdom 0.4 0.8 NEGL 3.9 United States -1.3 -2.1 3.4 -65.0 Real GDP Growth a (percentage points) Current Account Balance a (billion US $J First Year Second Year First Year Second Year Australia 0.1 0.1 -1.1 -0.8 Austria 0.5 I.0 0.2 1.0 Belgium -0.3 -0.4 -0.5 -0.9 Canada -0.7 -1.0 -3.2 -6.7 Denmark -0.2 -0.2 -0.3 -0.5 Finland NEGL NEGL -O.2 -O.2 France -0.1 -0.1 -1.4 -2.4 Greece NEGL NEGL -O.1 -O.2 Iceland -0.4 -0.7 NEGL -O.l Ireland O.1 O.3 NEGL NEGL Italy -0.2 -0.3 -1.1 -2.3 Japan -0.7 -1.2 20.3 2.7 Netherlands -0.2 -0.2 -0.6 -1.0 New Zealand 1.4 2.5 NEGL 0.4 Norway NEGL NEGL -O.3 -O.2 Portugal -0.1 -0.2 -0.1 -0.2 Spain -0.1 -0.2 -0.6 -0.8 Sweden NEGL -0.1 -0.3 -0.4 Switzerland NEGL NEGL -O.4 -O.3 Turkey -0.2 -0.2 -0.2 -0.4 United Kingdom -0.2 -0.3 -2.0 -3.5 United States 0.4 0.6 - 3.2 20.6 Changes resulting from a l0-percent appreciation of the US dollar. Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 I I ., .I J I 1 1 I_ ... ~. ,. I I. I I I .. I I I I _. _ I_ I .11L 1 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Table 15c Table 15d The West German Deutsche Mark's The French Franc's Impact Impact on Industrialized Countries on Industrialized Countries Real GDP Growth a (percentage points) Current Account Balance a (billion US $J First Sec Year Ye ond ar First Year Second Year Australia -0.1 -0 .1 -0.5 -0.6 Austria 7.4 10 .7 4.0 13.7 Belgium -0.1 NEG L -2.3 -2.5 Canada -0.2 -0 .3 -I.1 -2.2 Denmark NEGL 0 .1 -0.9 -0.8 Finland 0.3 0 .2 -0.4 -0.2 France 0.2 0 .4 - 3.4 - 1.7 Greece 0.3 0 .3 -0.2 -0.1 Iceland -0.2 -0 .3 NEGL -O.1 Ireland 0.7 1 .4 NEGL 0.2 Italy 0.2 0 .2 - 2.7 - 1.6 Japan -0.1 -0 .1 -3.2 -5.6 Netherlands 0.6 1 .3 -2.1 -0.2 New Zealand 0.2 5 .7 NEGL NEGL Norway 0.3 0 .6 -0.4 NEGL Portugal NEGL 0 .1 -0.2 -0.2 Spain NEGL NEG L - 1.O -O.8 Sweden 0.7 0 .6 -0.2 0.6 Switzerland 1.1 2 .1 - 1.0 0.8 Turkey -0.1 0 .1 -0.4 -0.5 United Kingdom NEGL NEG L -3.2 -3.3 United States 0.1 0 .1 - 2.2 2.6 West Germany -1.5 -2 .5 20.4 -0.3 Real GDP Growth a (percentage points) Current Account Balance a (billion US $J First Seco Year Year nd First Year Second Year Australia NEGL -0.1 -0.2 -0.1 Austria 0.5 1.2 0.3 1.2 Belgium 0.2 0.6 -1.3 -0.7 Canada -0.1 -0.2 -0.5 -1.0 Denmark -0.1 NEGL -0.2 -0.3 Finland 0.1 0.1 -0.1 NEGL France -0.9 -1.8 12.1 2.1 Greece 0.1 0.1 -0.1 -0.1 Iceland -0.1 -0.2 NEGL NEGL Ireland 0.5 1.1 NEGL 0.2 Italy 0.3 0.4 - 1.2 0.9 Japan NEGL -0.1 -1.4 -2.4 Netherlands 0.1 0.4 -0.7 -0.3 New Zealand 0.1 0.1 NEGL NEGL Norway 0.1 0.2 -0.1 0.1 Portugal 0.2 0.4 -0.1 NEGL Spain 0.2 0.4 -0.5 0.4 Sweden 0.2 0.1 -0.1 0.2 Switzerland 0.4 0.8 -0.4 0.4 Turkey -0.1 NEGL -0.1 -0.2 United Kingdom NEGL 0.1 -1.3 -0.9 United States NEGL 0.1 -0.7 2.2 West Germany 0.1 0.2 -3.5 -2.1 Changes resulting from a 10-percent appreciation of the deutsche a Changes resulting from a 10-percent appreciation of the franc. mark. 25X1 X1 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Table 15e Table 15f The British Pound's Impact The Italian Lira's Impact on Industralized Countries on Industralized Countries Real GDP Growth a (percentage points) Current Account Balance a (billion US $f First Year Second Year First Year Second Year Australia NEGL -0.1 -0.4 -0.4 Austria 0.3 0.6 0.1 0.5 Belgium -0.1 NEGL -0.8 -0.9 Canada -0.1 -0.2 -0.7 -1.2 Denmark NEGL 0.1 -0.3 -0.3 Finland 0.2 0.2 -0.2 NEGL France 0.1 0.2 -1.3 -0.8 Greece O.l NEGL NEGL -O.1 Iceland NEGL NEGL NEGL NEGL Ireland 4.9 7.8 0.2 1.7 Italy NEGL NEGL -O.7 -O.S Japan NEGL -0.1 -1.7 3.0 Netherlands 0.2 0.4 -0.8 -0.4 New Zealand 0.6 0.7 NEGL 0.2 Norway 0.4 0.6 -0.1 0.3 Portugal 0.1 0.2 -0.1 -0.1 Spain NEGL NEGL -O.4 -O.2 Sweden O.S O.S NEGL 0.7 Switzerland 0.3 0.4 -0.2 0.2 Turkey NEGL 0.1 -0.1 -0.1 United Kingdom -0.8 -1.2 12.4 6.4 United States 0.1 0.1 - 1.0 2.3 West Germany NEGL NEGL -2.S -2.S Real GDP Growth a (percentage points) Current Account Balance a (billion US $J First Year Second Year First Year Second Year Australia NEGL -0.1 -0.2 -0.1 Austria 1.7 4.0 0.9 2.8 Belgium NEGL NEGL -O.3 -O.4 Canada -0.1 -0.2 -O.S -1.0 Denmark NEGL NEGL -O.2 -O.2 Finland 0.1 0.1 -0.1 NEGL France 0.3 0.4 - I.0 1.0 Greece 0.3 0.3 NEGL 0.1 Iceland -0.1 -0.2 NEGL NEGL Ireland 0.2 0.4 NEGL 0.1 Italy - 1.4 - 2.0 6.7 - 2.1 Japan NEGL -0.1 -1.3 -2.5 Netherlands 0.1 0.2 -0.2 -0.1 New Zealand 0.1 0.1 NEGL NEGL Norway NEGL NEGL -O.1 -O.1 Portugal 0.1 0.1 -0.1 -0.1 Spain 0.1 0.1 -0.3 NEGL Sweden 0.1 NEGL -O.1 0.1 Switzerland 0.6 0.9 -0.1 0.7 Turkey NEGL 0.1 -0.1 -0.1 United Kingdom NEGL NEGL -O.8 -O.9 United States NEGL 0.1 -O.S 2.3 West Germany 0.1 NEGL -2.3 -1.7 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Table 15g The Canadian Dollar's Impact on Industrialized Countries . Real GDP Growth a (percentage points) Current Account Balance a (billion US $J First Year Second Year First Year Second Year Australia -0.1 -0.2 -0.2 -0.4 Austria NEGL NEGL NEGL NEGL Belgium -0.2 -0.1 -0.1 -0.4 Canada -2.2 -3.3 4.1 -7.8 Denmark -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.2 Finland NEGL NEGL -O.1 NEGL France NEGL NEGL -O.S -1.1 Greece NEGL -O.l NEGL -O.1 Iceland -0.3 -O.S NEGL -O.1 Ireland -0.1 -0.1 NEGL NEGL Italy -0.1 -0.2 -O.S -1.1 Japan -0.2 -0.3 -4.9 -9.3 Netherlands -0.1 -0.1 -0.2 -0.4 New Zealand NEGL NEGL -O.I -O.1 NOiWay NEGL NEGL -O.l NEGL Portugal -0.1 -0.1 NEGL -O.1 Spain -0.1 -0.1 -0.2 -0.4 Sweden -0.1 -0.2 -0.2 -0.3 Switzerland -0.1 -0.2 -0.2 -0.3 Turkey -0.1 -0.1 NEGL -O.2 United Kingdom -0.1 -0.1 -0.7 -1.3 United States O.S 0.8 4.S 33.8 West Germany -0.1 -0.2 -1.1 -2.4 Changes resulting from a 10-percent appreciation of the Canadian dollar. Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Appendix B Data and Methodology The data for this project are all obtained on floppy disk from the OECD, Paris. The series are reported on a semiannual basis, generally beginning with the first half of 1970. New diskettes become available each June and December, and the balance-of-payments spreadsheets are designed to incorporate revised and updated data by using the Lotus 1-2-3 File/Combine command. No labor-intensive data maintenance or update procedure is required. Koyck Lags Econometric relationships often assume that the dependent variable depends not only on the current values of the independent variables but also on their values in earlier periods. Direct estimation of the coefficients of these lagged variables is usually impossible, however, as a result of multicollinearity and degrees-of- freedom problems. The Koyck-lag approach gets around this difficulty by including the dependent variable, lagged one period, among the independent variables. This is functionally equivalent to expressing the dependent variable as a function of the values of the independent variables in the current and all preceding periods. This relationship can be illustrated by the estimation of imports (m) in period t as a function of prices (p) in period t, income (y) in period t, and imports in period t-1; that is: M~=aXP~+bXY~+cX,_, Similarly for period t-1 M,_,=aXP,_,+bXY,_,+cXM,_Z Substituting the second equation into the first yields M~=aXP,+bXY,+cXaXP,_,+cXbXY,_,+c2XM,_Z The substitution process can then be successively repeated to eliminate M,_Z, Mt_3, and so on, leaving only current and lagged values of prices and income on the right-hand side of the equation. The principal drawbacks of the Koyck method are that it imposes a geometrically declining lag structure and-more important-that it imposes the same lag structure on all of the independent variables. We believe that these shortcomings are outweighed by the Koyck method's ease of use and by the fact that it has won widespread acceptance in econometric model building. s Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Bridge Equations Because aggregate and component data series are generally created through the use of different methodologies, a lack of consistency exists in the OECD balance- of-payments data bank. To correct for these anomalies, bridge equations are employed in the individual country balance-of-payments models. Bridge equations are created by regressing one serfs against another in cases where the two series should theoretically be equivalent For example one source may provide data on total exports while another provides data on exports by category. If the value for total exports created by adding together the components does not match the reported aggregate value, the following equation will be estimated, where X 1 and X2 are two series that should be equivalent but are calculated in different ways: If the data sources are consistent, the estimated value for a will be close to zero and the value for b will be close to one. Coefficients that diverge significantly from these values identify data with a high degree of inconsistency. The econometrically estimated coefficients allow us to create a historically consistent aggregate series from its components. Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 -~- - ---_ ... _~ _ ~ ~~ I . I i I I Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Appendix C Regression Results The general form of the regressions uses a price and income term, combined with a Koyck lag. In some cases-primarily because of insufficient data-unacceptable results were obtained when using the form based on price, income, and lagged quantity. In these cases, acceptable results were obtained by employing one of four alternate forms: ? Income and lagged price. ? Income, price, and lagged price. ? Price, income, and lagged income. ? Price and lagged income. In all cases, the usual infinite lag was replaced by cone-period lag. For services, attempts to incorporate lag terms were unsuccessful. The specific results are identifiable, by heading, in this appendix. 1 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02!07:CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Australia Austria Belgium/ Canada Denmark Finland France Greece Iceland Ireland Italy Japan Netherlands New Norway Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland Turkey United United West Luxembourg Zealand Kingdom States Germany Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02!07:CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 -L- _~ ~ ~ I ..J ----- -~~i-1----- - 1 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Appendix D Individual Balance-of-Payments Models Models for individual countries were created in the environment of the Lotus 1-2-3 spreadsheet package. The regressions were estimated using the Lotus 1-2-3 regression facility, and the spreadsheet format is used to combine historical data and regression results for forecasting and scenario analysis. This appendix consists of the econometric representation of the typical country model. The coefficient values for each country are listed in Appendix B. Copies of the models on floppy disk are available on request from the West European Division, EURA. MAG Agricultural products: import volume MAGPI Agricultural products: import price index MEN Energy products: import volume MENPI Energy products: import price index MG Total goods: import volume MGPI Total goods: import price index MMG Manufactured goods: import volume MMGPI Manufactured goods: import price index MRM Raw materials: import volume MRMPI Raw materials: import price index NCABD Current account balance: current dollars NIICD Investment income: credits in current dollars NIIDD Investment income: debits in current dollars NMGD Total goods: imports in current dollars NMSD Nonfactor services: imports in current dollars NOTD Net official transfers: current dollars NPTD Net private transfers: current dollars NTBD Trade balance: current dollars NXGD Total goods: exports in current dollars NXSD Nonfactor services: exports in current dollars XAG Agricultural products: export volume XAGPI Agricultural products: export price index XEN Energy products: export volume XENPI Energy products: export price index XG Total goods: export volume XGPI Total goods: export price index XMG Manufactured goods: export volume XMGPI Manufactured goods: export price index XR Exchange rate: domestic currency units per dollar XRM Raw materials: export volume XRMPI Raw materials: export price index YD Domestic income: volume YW World income: real dollars Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 ii ~ ~ I I l .III I Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Import Demand (1) log(MAG) = al + a2 X log(MAGPI/XAGPI) + a3 X log(YD) + a4 X log(MAG(-1)) (2) log(MEN) = al + a2 X log(MENPI/XENPI) + a3 X log(YD) + a4 X log(MEN(-1)) (3) log(MRM) = al + a2 X log(MRMPI/XRMPI) + a3 X log(YD) + a4 X log(MRM(-1)) (4) log(MMG) = al + a2 X log(MMGPI/XMGPI) + a3 X log(YD) + a4 X log(MMG(-1)) Export Demand (5) log(XAG) = al + a2 X log(XAGPI/MAGPI) + a3 X log(YW) + a4 X log(XAG(-1)) (6) log(XEN) = al + a2 X log(XENPI/MENPI) + a3 X log(YW) + a4 X log(XEN(-1)) (7) log(XRM) = al + a2 X log(XRMPI/MRMPI) + a3 X log(YW) + a4 X log(XRM(-1)) (8) log(XMG) = al + a2 X log(XMGPI/MMGPI) + a3 X log(YW) + a4 X log(XMG(-1)) Total Goods Bridge Equations (9) MG = al + a2 X (MAG + MEN +MRM +MMG) (10) XG = a 1 + a2 X (XAG +XEN +XRM +XMG) (11) MGPI = a 1 + a2 X MAG X MAGPI + MEN X MENPI + MRM X MRMPI + MMG X MMGPD MAG + MEN +MRM +MMG (12) XGPI = a 1 + a2 X XAG X XAGPI + XEN X XENPI + XRM X XRMPI + XMG X XMGPD XAG +XEN +XRM +XMG (13) NMGD = al + a2 X (MG X MGPD / XR) (14) NXGD = al + a2 X (XG X XGPD / XR) Current Account Balance Aggregates (15) NTBD =NXGD -NMGD (16) NCABD =NTBD + NXSD - NMSD + NIICD - NIIDD + NPTD + NOTD 25X1 Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 i ... .I . J1 _. ... I I I Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Appendix E Trade-Share Linkage Model This model was created in the environment of the Lotus 1-2-3 spreadsheet package. The regression results were obtained from the individual country models and are combined in this spreadsheet in order to examine interactions between trade partners. These results can help with both forecasting and scenario analysis. This appendix consists of the econometric representation of key parts of the trade linkage model. Copies of this model are available on request from EURA/WE. DD; Real domestic demand: country ; EX; Real exports: country ; EXPI; Export price index: country ; GDP; Real GDP: country ; IM; Real imports: country; IMPI; Import price index: country ; REXR; Real effective exchange rate: country ; SH; ~ Country ;imports: share coming from country ~ ULC; Unit labor cost: country ; XR; Exchange rate: units of country ;currency per dollar Real GDP (1)GDP;=DD;+EX;-IM; Import Demand (2) log(IM;) = al + a2 X log(DD;) + a3 X log(IMPI;/EXPI;) + a4 X log(DD;(-1)) + a5 X log(IMPI;(-1)/EXPI;(-1)) and so on Export Demand (3) EX; = IMI X SH,; + IM2 X SHZ; + IM3 X SH,; and so on Import Price Index (4) IMPI; = EXPI1 X SH;, + EXPI2 X SHi2 and so on Real ERective Exchange Rate (5) REXR; =ULC; / XR; X ((SH,; + SH;,) / 2 X XR1 / ULC1 + (SHZ; + SHjz) / 2 X XR2 / ULC2 and so on) Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 I! . I I I I 11 I _. II_ ... ; I ,I I I I _.. I I I I I I III I Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9 Confidential Confidential Declassified in Part -Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2012/02/07 :CIA-RDP89T00295R000400420002-9