SOVIET REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN 1960-69: TRENDS AND IMPLICATIONS

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
U
Document Page Count: 
47
Document Creation Date: 
December 12, 2016
Document Release Date: 
June 30, 1999
Sequence Number: 
1
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
April 1, 1972
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1.pdf1.88 MB
Body: 
' , 0` r., ()IV, , ",ekAqV59,102,404.1-1 A??,'? A . ' ) I `.,' 1.,' 1) ) o Approved For Release 2/001//06/28 (CIA=RDP85T00g75R002000040001-1 SOVIET REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN 196O69: TRENDS AND IMPLICATIONS 25X1A by If" April 1972 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 ILLEGIB ILLEGIB CENTRAL INTELLIGENCE AGENCY TO: Document Iteriplent.i; / ? ? ? ? is' ( rin tinclas.NIcle(1 rcnorl published by the ()Trice of Economic lir:Alit-eh I:; nol io bi reproduced or rutted l'In? report, will appear In It compendium of i,cholatly iirth?les on the Soviet lInlon to be later t hi year, at which I Imo the author will lie Identified a.-4 all employee of the central Intellirence ArelleY STATINTL MAURICE ERNST Director licolimnie Research Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 4 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 CONTENTS Ilighlights 1 I)iscussion :1 Intiodnetion S()vff'i PiflirY To?varfl B(1',io1131 11)I'N'cli'lm1(.111 The Soviet Minorities 5 Policy Aims 5 Regional Trends in Per (:apita National hiconii?, Industrial ()Mimi, and Agricultural Production Regional I)ifferences in 1960 Regional 1)evelopment in the 1960s Regional Trends in Population Cao?vtlf 12 Nat 'Ind Increase 12 19 Regional Investment Polit'y 21 Inconsistency liebvcrii Regional Policy and Investment Alliwations 21 Iligher Clo?vtli of Productivity in the Mote Developed Ite0ons '33 Implications for Soviet Policy 25 Investment Allocations 25 Niigration Policy 2( Plans for 1971 75 27 APPENDIXES Appendix A. Primary 1)ata Used in Calculating Regional Trends in Per Capita National Income, Indostrial and Agricultural ()input, and Facf()I. I'll)(111(?11V11%' A111)(11(11% If. DISCIINNI(//1 ol StailS1;(;;11 ;111(1 Analytical Procedures TABLES Page 31 37 I. USSR: Per Capita Regional Production in 1960 8 2. USSR: Rates of Natural Popidation Increase, by Republic and Region 18 ;5. 1.115: I hr (;ontrihution of Natural increase :Ind Migration to Popu- lation (:rowth, by !legion, 1960-70 19 4. USSR: Index of Growth of Able-Bodied Population, by Republic, 1960-70 21 5. tftiS11: (:ombined Facto! Productivity in industry 24 6. USSR: Planned Growth, by Ileptibfic 28 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 II Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 ILLUSTRATIONS Figur(' I. I /SSW l/nion Ilepublics and 11S1.'S11 Economic liegions, 1971 (Map) Figoire 2. USSR: !legion:11 Variations Average Animal GroNvIli of Pei Capita r1 ''L Invoint., 1901 09 (Map) 10 1urc 3. USS11: licgioual Gaps in It Capita National Incooic ((hart ) 11 Figure 1, USS11: Vatiations in Averagc Annual (ivJ ui Pcr Capita Industrial Pouluction, 1901-69 (1\1:1p) 1:1 Vignic 5. ()Still: licgional Gaps in Pc!. Capita industrial Production ((liar!) II Figure O. USSR: Ilegional Variations in Average Annual Growth of INT Gipita Agricultural Production, 1961-(i) (Map) 15 Figure 7. USSR: licgional Caps in Per Capita Agricultural Production ((har!) iitiir8. !legion:11 Variations in Population GroNvtli, 19131-69 (NI:if)) 17 Irigure 9. 1.1SS11: Ilanking of Union licpublics, hy Per Capita National Income and Per Capita NeNv Fixed investinen1 ((hart ) 22 Figlite 10. PIT Capita NVN,11 Investnicnt, 11cpublic ((hart) 99 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 SOVIET REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN 1960-69: TRENDS AND IMPLICATIONS HIGHLIGHTS Des;?ite the official car for economic equality among the several regions and republics of the USSR, regional disparities il) per capita income, industrial 011.,1111, (11Id ral prodnoion increased s?bstantially during the 1960s. Py the end of the decade, those regions viIii OW frVelS (If deVelOIMWIlf iii 1960?the Central Asian ' and Transcaucasian republics----had fallen even further behind the rest of the country in terms of p.?r capita income and output. The principal reasons for this situation are extremely rapid population growth il) the poorer regions, investment allocations that were not designed for re- ducing regional diffeiences, and the low productivity of labor and capital in many of the less developed regions. Population growth in the Central Asian and Transcaucasian republics has been much greater than in any other area of the country Over the past decade, primarily because of their high rates of natural increas... Interregional migration patterns, however, also contributed to regional disparities in population growth? reducing growth in areas with relatively low rates of natural increase aad aug- menting growth in areas already having relatively high rates of natural increase. Migration into the southern regions has been influenced by Soviet wage policy. it:xisting regional wage differentials are insufficient to compensate for the rigors of living in remote or climatically severe regions and make th,? southern cities far inure attractive places of residence dun) the cold uncongenial areas of -iiberin and the Urals. The slowest growing areas in the cmmtry in terms of per capita national income are Azerbaydzhae, Uzbekistan, and Turkmenia, while the fastest g Nwing are Lithuania, Belorussia, and Moldavia. In the three lagging regions, growth rates of population were among the highest in the country, ?vhereas national income growth was slower than in any other region because of the very low growth rates of industrial ontput. Conversely, the rapid growth if Lithuania, Bekinissia, and Middavia is reflected in 1(1 )OV( increases in national income, industrial output, and agricultural production together with much lower growth rates for population. Investment allocations during the 1960s have not been oriented consistently toward reducing regional differences in production and income. Iwo n the poorer republics?the Kazakh and Turkmen Republics?received more invest- ment funds per capita than wealthier republics, but much of this oapital was directed toward the exploitation of particularly rich mineral a;,(1 fuel deposits. ' Throughout this paper, the term Central Asia includes the Kvzakh Republic. 1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Oil the other hand, the Georgian, Kirgiz, and Tadzhik Republics were given ;11- VCS(111Plit allocations barely half as largo as those funneled into the Kazakh Republic. Whether actual investment policy has been to maximize national economic growth rather than to effect regional parity is uncertain. Policy state- ments are confused and the results are mixed. Although industrial investments have not favored consistently those repnblics in which the productivity of combined labor and capital inputs was highest, investment allocations have not ,ellected it planners' goal of reducing regional disparities. A serions impedimellt to narrowing the differences in regional levels of developmeiit is the relatively It growth of productivity of hal mi and capital in many of the poorer regions. Over the past decade, industrial output per unit of combined inputs has grown very little in the 1,.,ss developed republics. In some cases?Uzbekistan, Turkmenia, and Azcalraydzlian?indimITial output grew at rates 1; low the national average as a decline in productivity offset the above-average growth of combined inputs of labor and capital. The present status of regional development confronts Soviet planners and political leaders with a policy dilemma. A significant reduction of regional income differentials and maximum national economic growth cannot be adneved simultaneously through investment strategy alone. 'rhos regions that appear to have the best investment opoortunities are not the regions with the ',owes - income per capita. Moreover, the 1971-75 plan data for the republics suggest that the geographic pattern of development will not change radically o-fer the next five years. The new five-year plan gives no prospect of reducing regional income differentials by a coordinated redistribution of both capital and labor. Thus the regional disparities in development levds are likely to persit with little change during the new plan period. In fact, if planned industrial growth must depend primarily on increases in factor produet.vity, as stated by the leadership, the development gaps may continue to incr2ase, with the less developed republics falling still farther behind the rest of the country. 4proved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 DISCUSSION INTRODUCTION Although Soviet economic development has proceeded rapidly, its geographic incidence has been very uneven. The persistent large differences in per capita income and production among regions are surprising in view of the longstanding Soviet goal of providing an even distribution of productive forces (meaning industry primarily) over the entire couatry. However, the lack of progress in this regard could, until around 1960, be explained by the imperatives of the early industrialization drive, World War II, and the recovery from war. The emphasis on speedy development, ir conjunction with the shortage of capital during the 1920s and 1930s, encouraged growth at existing industrial centers, which were to a large extent tire traditional manufacturing centers in the European part of Tsarist Russia. Moreover, the massive transfer of in- dustries eastward in 1940-43 was still not sufficient to overcome the imbalance in the distribution of production. After the war, the concern with reconstruction coupled with a 1.ighly centralized branch principle of planning brought about a territorial distribution of economic activity very little different from that existing in 1945. Only after the mid 1950s, particularly with the creation of the councils of national cc momy in 1957, did attention to regional aspects of economic development increase appreciably.2 The purpose of this paper is to assess the results of Soviet regional development policy during the 190s. After the framework of this policy is set out briefly, statistics on per capita naticnal income, gross industrial output, an agricultural output ar3 examined for the 15 union republics and, where possible, the ten economic regions of the Russian Soviet Federated Socialist Republic?RSFSR 3 (sec Figure 1). National income cannot be calculated for thc regions of the RSFSR, so their relative levels of development are shown in terms of the two major contributing sectors to national income?industrial a..id agricultural out- put. Industrial output per capita is a particularly useful indicator because in- dustrial development is the leading edge of Soviet growth strategy. Therefore, the implications of that strategy foi regional development should be most visiblv in statiNtils on regional industrial output. Next, regional trends in population grot th are presented. Because the ex- amination of output, income, and popul: ,ion shows that regional differentials were greater at the end of the 1960s than at the beginning, the paper goe,' on to investigate the reasons for the failure to na:row the income gaps among regions. Finally, since some of the reasons have clear implications for current and future Soviet economic policy ar,d growth, these implications are discussed in the concluding section of the paper. ?Councils of national economy were established as a system of regional units in an abortive attempt to facilitate economic decisionmaking by docenimlizing economic management. The system was abolished in 1965. ? For primary data used in calcolating regional trends in per capita natioral income, industrial and agricultural output, and h,tor productivity, see Appendix A. 1?Hional income and indus- trial production data were derived from official Soviet statistics and reflect Soviet concep . and biases. The aft ts of such biascs ire discusvx1 in Appendix B, i,Tluding Tables B-1, B-2, and B-3. The regional values of agricultural output were estimated from price and quantity data for 17 agricultural products. Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 3 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 USSR: Union Republics cud RSFSR Economic Regions, 1971 Figure 1 I I 14 Russian Republic Minority National Republics 22 23 Republics 1. Estonia 2. Latvia 3. Lithuania 4. Belorussia 5. Ukraire 6. Moldavic 7. Georgia 8. Armenia 9. Azerbaydzhan 10. Turkmen 11. Uzbek 12. Takhik 13. Kirgiz 14. Kazakh FISFSR Economic Regions 15. Northwest 16. Center 17. Central Chernozem 10. North Caucasus 19. Volga-Vyatka 20. Volga Valley 21. Urals 22. West Siberia 23. East Siberia 24. Far East ? Kaliningrad Oblast': Included in the statistical data of the Northwest region. 4 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 SOVIET POLICY TOWARD REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT The Soviet Minorities Diversity is the most striking characteristic l the Soviet population. Nearly 170 nationalities and about as mai:), languages form the ethnic and linguistic composition of the USSR. IImvover, most of these ethnic groups are quite small relative to the total populi?tion. Only 11 constitute more than 1% of the total population and only six, more than 27(. Nevertheless, these six nationalities comprise the bulk of two ethnic groupings with vastly dillerent cultures and attitudes. The Russian, Ukrainian, and 13elorussian nationalities make up the bulk of the Slavic peoples and together account for 74%, of the total population; the Uzboks, Tatars, and Kazakhs belong to the Turkic group and accennt for 8.5% ot the population. The largest single nationality is the Russian, with 53.4% of the total population in 1970. Nearly 84% of these people live within the MESH, wher'in they comprise almost 83% of that republic's population. Russians also tiake up the largest nationality (43% ) in Kazakhstan, and in all other republics they rank either second or thud. Only in Armenia, Georgia, and Lithuania do Russians comprise less than 10% of the population. Although the Soviets officially proclaim equality among the nationalities, Russian dominance general'y pervades the political and economic life of the minority groups. Minority languages, literature, and arts are still supported and even encouraged, but the use of the Russian language increases throughout the USSR, and Russians continue to migrate to the cities of traditionally non-Russian areac, where they hold many of the key positions as managers, professionals, and technicians. The other nationality groups, particularly the nationalities of the Central Asian republics, are generally less widely distributed than the Russians. These groups are heavily concentrated in their respective republics and usually form significant minorities only in immediately adjacent non-Russian republics. The number of non-Russian people woo claim Russian as their native language has been inching upward (11.5% of the population in 1970 compared with 10.8% in 1959). Most of this increase has occurred among the Ukrainians, Jews, arid Bclontssians, and the percent of the non-Russian population speaking Russian fluently as a second knguage is generally greatest among the Slavic and other Indo-European groups. Linguistic assimilation has been more difficult to achieve among the Turkic peoples, owing partly to the more rapid rate of growth of these peoples and partly to the much stronger cultural differences between the Turkic and (i.e Russian peoples. Policy Aims Because of ideological considerations, one of the goals of Soviet economic policy has been to equalize levels of development throughout the country. Originally part of Lenin's "nationalities policy"?which considered economic equality a prerequisite to political, social, md cultural equality and the eventual creation of a Communist society?this aim was set forth specifically in terms of industrial development in the resolutions of the 10th Party Congress in 1921. Economic equality among the nationalitie.; was to be achieved by transferring industry to the areas of minority nationalities.4 kommunistieheskaya Partiya Sovetskogo Soyuza v rezolyetsiyakh i resheniyakh s''yezdov, konferentsiy i plenumov 'sentrarnogo 1-ntr'teta, Moscow, vol 1, 1954, p. 560. Although what the Soviets meant by equality is not c' , for cample, per capita industrial output, per capita real income, or some other measure), they apparently intended to equalize economic develop- ment in general and believed that industrialization was the most effective ineah..: to this and. Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 5 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Following the 15th Party Congress in 1927, which ushered in the Creat In- dustrialization Drive, the goal of equality was overshadowed by the concern for rapid industrialization and maximum productiu:. at minimum cost." Since the less developed areas wero less favorably endowed with the infrastruc- ture necessary for the rapid development of heavy industry (the primary focus of the industrialization drive 7) they received an insignificant share of the total investment." As a result, little progress was made in the pursuit of re- gional parity. Nevertheless, for political and ideological reasons, equalization of levels of development among regions and republics has remained a tenet of Soviet de- velopment policy, and the definition of "development" has been broadened to include production in sectors other than industry." In its present form, Soviet development policy incorporates the objectives of both regional parity and maxi- mum production. Current statements on development policy, although somewhat ambiguous, seem to assign equal priority to both aims, or, at least, to be founded on the belief that the objectives are consistent.'? In fact, conflicts arise in attempting to achieve both regional parity and maximum production simultaneously. Since the best investment opportunities are not necessarily in the less developed regions, heavy investment allocations to these regions could be inconsistent with the goal of maximizing overall pro- The 15th Party Congress ordered pursuit of the equalization goal to proceed within the constraints of national interests. (Ibid., vol II, p. 483.) " Pishchayev, V., "K postanovke problemy geograficheskago razmeshcheniya promyshlennosti SSSR," Problemy ekonomiki, no 6, 1931, p. 102. As Naum jasny has pointed out, For years, indeed for the whole period covered in this monograph [1928-521, almost the whole economy was geared to produce ever inure steel for the construction of ever more steel and other heavy-industry factories, as well as for the output of ever more armaments. (JnsuY, Soviet Industrialization, 1928-52, Chica:;o, 1961, p. 3.) ' Koropeckyj, I.S., "The Development of Soviet Location Theory Ilefore the Second World War," Soviet Studies, no 2, 1967, p 243. Kotoperkyj argues convincingly that the emphasis on increased development of the already established industrial centers during this period was motivated primarily by defense considerations?that is, heavy industry was considered the backbone of defense, and rapid dcvolopment of heavy industry wos considered the most expedient means to military prcparedness. ?Several Soviet specialists have indicated that the equalization of development levels includes equal:4111g the level of "well-being" of the population. However, there is little agreement as to the methodology for measuring "well-being." For example, sec Telepko, L.N., Urovni ekonomicheskogo razvitiya rayonov SSSR, Moscow, 1971, and Vedishehev, Al., "Soizmereniye urovney khozyaystvennogo razvitiya ekonomieheskikh rayonov SSSR, in Ivanehenko, A.A. (ed.) Ekonomicheskiye prohlemy razmeshcheniya proizvoditanykh sil SSSR, Moscow, 1969. " For example, in his speech to the 24th Party Congress in 1971, Kosygin stated, One of the most important conditions for increasing the efficiency of social production is the correct siting of productive forces, which ensures the further indus- trial development of all the union republics and the consistent implementation of the Leninist nationalities policy. (Fravda, 7 Apr 1971, pp. 2-7, cited in the Current Digest of Soviet Press, vol 23, no 16, p. 4.) Also, N.N. Nekrasov (Chairman of the Council for the Study of Productive Forces) recently said, The general plan for the development and distribution of productive forces for the period up to 1980 [includes] further equalization of the levels of economic develop- ment of the union republics and economic regions of the USSR, improvement in the interrepublie division of labor and prodoction relations, etc. (Planovoye kliozynystvo, no 6, Jun 1971, p. 90.) 6 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 CPYRGHT CPYRGHT Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 duct ion." Moreover, where relative retardation of economic growth in a region is the result of initial underdevelopment combioed with rapid population growth, rather than failure to ildapt to changing conditions film a previous position of equality, the movonent of capital (inchiding educational capital) into the underdeveloped region may kive iittle effect if not acconipanied by a move- ment of labor out of the region. The successful solution to the regional pit)! )lei involves, in general, the application of the principle that each resource be moved to the place where it contributes most to production. If invest ill' 'lit opportunities are greater in the well developed regions, then the primary ini?ans of ii 10V toward regional parity must be the movement of labor out of the less developed regions. This is the familiar "north-south" problem as exemplified by the American South. In practice, differences in educational levels, cultures, languages, etc., may hinder population movement; the migration north ie the United States has been going on for geir2rations. Although adjustment is slow, the migraiion process can be a powerful factor in reducing regional income differentials. A good example is Brazil during the 1950s, where, despite the flow of private capqal from the less developed Northeast to the relatively well developed Center-South, the migration of population in the same direction resulted in a narrowing of regional incomt differentials over the decade.12 A somewhat different case is that of Puerto Rico, where emigration to the United States acted as a safety valve to population growth, and an influx of US capital provided the wherewithal for per capita income growth.'" REGIONAL TRENDS IN PER CAPITA NATIONAL INCOME, INDUSTRIAL OUTPUT, AND AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION Regional Differences in 1960 In 1960, Soviet economic regions could be clas3ified into three basic cate- gories: (1) the well-populated industrially developed regions of the European USSR, containing collectively more than two-thirds of the country's population and three-fourths of the industrial employment; (2) the sparsely populated pioneer regions of Siberia and the Far East, with only one-tenth of both the total population and industrial employment; and (3) the well-populated, in- dustrially underdeveloped regions of Central Asia, Transcaucasia, and the North Caucasus, encompassing one-fifth of the population but only slightly more than one-tenth of the industrial employment. The data in Table 1 clearly show the large differences in the level of economic development among the individual regions of the USSR. " However, if investment in the less developc:1 regions, particularly those bordering on China, is motivaLid primarily by overall defense interests as suggested in a recent article by I.S. Koropecle then the regional parity aim could he consistent with national interests even if it conflicted with the goal of maximizing production. For a more complete treatme nt of the defense motivano.. 'n investment decisions, see Koropeckyj, "Industrial Location Policy in the USSR During the Postwar Period," US Congress, Joint F.conoinie Committee print, Economic Performance and the Military Burden in the Soviet Union Washington, 1970, pp. 262-285. "Graham, D.II., "Divergent. and Convergent tegional Economic Growth and Internal Migration in Brazil-1946-1960," Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol 18, -Ico 3, Apr 1970, pp. 362-382. See also Baer, Werner, "Regional Inequality and Economic Growth in Brazil," Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol 13, no 3, Apr 1964, pp. 268-285. "Stahl, J.E., "An Application of a Klein Growth " Aodel to Puerto Rico, 1947-61," Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol 13, no 4, part I, Jul 1965, P. 471. 7 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Table I Per Capita Ilegio.nd Production in 1000 " 1,1t I via . . EHI.,)nia. . ..... . . ..... . 11SVS11 economie regiom. Per Capita N,.tionat Income 11uhle:; 11a nIc 11.11) I 8119 2 765 :1 ""1" H"u! .t11"I h't (0110111 (4 \) It tilde 11:oil, I:111de 1133 I 3 I1 1171 3 :178 820 ill 1 N. A . Center I , 185 1 176 111 North we + b 1,167 I 2,1 22 !Irak 930 .ri '203 Ili Val. Elva "37 '7 99 24 VoIga-Vyallut 653 8 217 13 Vidgli ValleY 64.5 9 274 11 West Siberia 621 16 288 .8 North Caneasi 600 I 1 300 7 Haat Siberia, 591 12 210 14 Central Cliernozein . 311 24 3:15 1 Lithuania 678 4 :)I 9 IS 356 2 Ukraine 675 5 775 6 285 10 Azerhayilzhan 560 6 461 16 123 23 Armenia 522 7 584 13 128 21 Moldavia 521 8 :193 119 287 9 Belorussia 517 9 451 17 323 5 Kazakh 511 10 403 18 321 6 Turkmen 509 I I 340 23 205 15 ( leorgia. 454 12 522 14 144 20 Uzbek 460 1:1 359 21 241 12 Kiru-iz 449 14 3611 20 195 17 Tadzhik 380 IS 352 22 178 IS USSR (49I 724 244 " In all regions, per capita industrial output and per capita iigricultnral (441(4)414 together exceed the value shown for per capita national income becpuse the three indicators of development are based on different prices and concepts. The nationa: income data are based on I 9513 prices and reflect the Marxist conception of net income which includts oily the 'it product of the "productive" sectors. On the other hand, the industrial output data are based on 1055 prices and r( fleet the gross output of industry, which includes doubleconnting of SOIlle products. Th, agric4.1tural data are bascd on three-year moving averages in 1968 prices and reflect production estimates net of intra-agricultural uses of farin products but not excluding doublecounting of purchases from other sectors. The derivation of these data is described in the notes to Appendix Table A-2. Including Kaliningrad Oblast'. As indicated in Table 1, the western republics, including the ESFS11, started the decade with the highest levels of per capita national income, while the republics of Central Asia and Transcaucasia had levels of national income per capita considerably below the national average. Not surprisingly, the levels of industrial output per capita in 1960 fell into the sam, general pattern. In terms of avicultural output," the picture was somewhat different. While I he Baltic repuAics and thc Ukraine were again among the led.cling regions, the Central Chernozem region, Belorussia. Kazakhstan, and Moldavia made up for part of their industrial backwardness with above-avA-age agricultural pro- duction. However, in the remaining Central Asian republics and all of Trans- 11t should be noted that while agricultural production per capita provides an indication of the relative weight of agriculture in a region's economy it may not provide a true measure of agricultural development?that is, agriculture may account for a relatively small share of national income in a region and still be highly developed in terms of output per unit of inputs. 8 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 1110.1111 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 cam .c.rt, pia f apila 1.ii iii 111111,111 11.111,11 1111111111 t111 Ihrlilliisil .1'. 1 1.1"1 I Iii ,, l?, Zi1,,, 11i1. 1.rd. III '1"ilii. 1,1 111,' iii111r?1ii.111\ 111 NI 1'111111 i1 ?'.I(111., ,?11111ii 111, 11',P111 Tri illi ,I11% Ili(' 1 ii,11... ( 'Int( I. .iIi(1 Nfiillik% 1 ',I 11 l'.inii, III 1...i..I ,,i'- i?) .w..I it Vai 1.1,I.,1. kvlicir 1,111nnw, r. 10)100.41 liv , Immlf? .1 iii Ildir?pill1.01(m Pluid,10,. tilt. If?vcr, fil imi capil.1 ;11,.1? iiiiii,?1 /mid", 11,111 \,,?ii? ,11,, hf ,IIi\ II, fmtimml Spurial 111(11111111 ',111)111(1 Iii Ithific iii lite duce ti (mown iii'i,ii,if ifthc Ilak ?Vi".1 Sihr11.1. !''Ihrl la. .11 wady \'iIt lira, ()I ;ihioVi?liii m1111)11;11 ;IVr1;tr.0 in !tam', id pia f .1116.1 1111111'111.1i 111111'11 if WI'. Ic11111)1V, iiutitiIiilv iiiIhriii :11111ii SiIitiit, ttiiif il vill11;111V 111a1111;11111cd 161114.11ii?., a', It11;11%11 11111".1Cal ;111(1 iiiuiitit tiiIitlitiitit illilitI lilt haVc ',C1111111? IIiIilfitIiiI tirVid4)11 111010 (1111MIllalll 11'1111 flitir 1(-.11111ur ha.W. 1,,icalci linancial mu reipiired i?,talikli ;old the ncre.o,aiv hicilitii"; tor ',Ode iiitutl, iii thew iireAs than it ;MN' (0111T pall id III(' (.1111101y. /\1011)111',11 111('itvjrf IlaN (11111)! III(' V:1`.1 11111114": (II Illf",r ?")11Iii 1)14)V1(11' ifill".1".` 1(".tiI "";11/1"1 (1'.".1"1) 1111111 I/1 a rurajut Illarkrt :11*Ca, this lii iii tt 1)(11111-111. Regional Development in the 1960s Irss (1"(1()P('(1 Su?'(('I "Tim" lii1".(1) l'arr Ili(' t(-4 the country is the most striking feature of regional development hi the 1960s. Contrary to ?vliat might be the expe,?led pattern for ;, nation whose poliev ostensibly is to achieve regional equality, those reg,ions with 6le !invest levels of development in 1960 did not generally grow more rapidly during, the 1960s than the areas already highly developed by 196(). In fact, percentage in(l eases ill 1)e1 capita national income (see rig,itre 2) ?vere Imvest ill Olt' I(I)11;dif'S (d tral Asia and Transcaucasia. Moreover, with the exception of Kazakhstan, re imblics that grew at rates below the national avviage during 1961-65 fell even further behind during 190(i-69. Thus the gaps bekvecii these less developed reg,ions and ill(' rest of the ("111111T havr 1".11 aS ShOW11 ill Figure 3, The range of variation in the levels of per capita national income among the union republics, which was !Wady 1?111)1(':; ill 19(3), extending limn ,15';; lwlEm lo "i6`; alnive the national average, approached 1,1(8) rubles by 1969, ranging Born Slim :n.low to 41'/e above the national average.''' Since Soviet national income data exclude any valuation for services, the differences between the two extremes probably would be even greater if national iiimine \v( Ii measured by \Vestern concepts, ?vhich include values of services. ()f titus reptiblic?s in ?vhich per capita na- tional \Vati ill'10\?' all-union avv?age hi 1960, (miy lit liniunijimill the Ukraine ?vere able to close the gaps ( svhali \yew minimal in 19(8)) between themselves and (he national average While Moldavia and Belorussia still n?- main at levels 11e105v the national average, their positions improved consider- ably relative to ti e C-ntral Asian and Transcaucasian reptiblic?s. For the remain- ing republics, the 1960 deviations from average per capita national incagne (both positive and negative) increased considerably over 0 (litadc. 'The coefficient of variation, which measnres the relative dispersion of the republican data around the melt' for the USSR, increased from 0.283 in 1960 to 0.355 in 1969. In other words. the relative stando-d deviation from the average for the USSR was greater in 1969 than if) 1960, indicating greater n4,ional disparity in development levels a: the end of the decade. 9 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 USSR: Regional Variation. in Average Annual Growth of Per Capita National Income, 1961-69' All thli011 Average !4.5",. per Year J Significantly above average (more than 6.0",, per year) [.?velisori urowth (5.0",, to 6.0"., per Ir. fir) Significantly below average (lec than 5.0"? per year) 10 IS Average Annual Rate of Growl (%) I igure 2 1. Estonia 6.3 9. Az?rbaydrhan 1.7 2. Latvia 5.9 10. Turkmen 1.7 3. Lithuania 7.9 11. Uzoek 2.5 4 941oriissia (3.9 12. Tadzhik 3.6 5. Ukraine 5.9 13. Kirgiz 4.5 G. Moldavia 6.7 14. Kazakh 4.0 7. Georgia 4.6 15. IISFSII 5.6 O. Armenia 5.3 o Ap1'c11,111 1.1blo A I Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 -49 Fiume 3 USSR: Regional Gaps in Per Capita National Income I Per cy Abov? or Below SOVESt Aver?ue) I olvia !sterile MSI SI I ilkuani? 2"" Ukraine ? 11111111111111111111111111 4' l4 NIONIMMISMEMMINIMINPMMPIM I le - 26", 1111111=11111.11.11.1. - 1 r., 1111111111111111=1111 to "..1111111111111.= 111111.1111111111111 11.111.....11111111 2O - 54 .. 411111 Neel Ambled/hen Armenia Moldavia larussis Kazakh Turkmen Georgie Uzbek Kirgiz radzhi 11 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 In hint'. 111 lir) .iiltf,l illf111.11 LI I IiHiiI,ii 1 11111. till Ill (lid I. till! lii..10 I%ii l'ii'ui ) AI 1111.1111.1. II 1111.iVki, MI( I ill( i.if ilii'. liii 111)/1111. ?,11),1 1.111 I cl11 II P., .III ill H Iii 11 1 5111 11c1(111' ,si 1,11!(' 115 ( 1', (11 1/(.1 1.11111 1111'10 111 NW, i (1 ii iii 1t I I 1,11i \ 111111 I I 1.1 I ii\ii 41 111 1.111, 1!111\lIll. 11.11.11 1(1 l'.11( ifiiifl III,' I 1..11.11 ILI I I 11 I I 1 iii I 11,1 I I\ IV 11'1 1.1 1 1 OH' I I I I \i 11 11 If 1 .1 I 11 ll',1.1 1 l'. .1 I(1 I II I I I I it (I III 1111', 1/.1111.1 11, 1 1(/\\ (-1/4( 1 ol hI 1?,, Li.1111.11 A.?1.111 And 11.111..(.111 c.c.1,111 (11115. 1(111.Ill ' iii 111,,I.'1.1 1.,11.?x 111.111 th 11,111no.11 oN (.1 1110, le.ailt III 1111,1 liii Illilti I. '11 111. 1 1?111111111'. :111(1 WIVS11 Cri 111(111114' ill 111(11 'uifttti;119)Irri;thIV ( 1{.111 11'1/1111111'. ;11111 11111%1 14.1!11111., 111 11/111! 11111111111111 (:ential and Muth \?1.. dint l'?',11;1 dippC(1 \\Aid( 11(1/1111. lilt! IlillillIell Ih'1l11!IIli', iiOW llTliiIt, Ill if(i (if. 1.111". 14 Ille 1.4'.111VC '4111(11111! (11 Ill trine, (if pet capita indte.hial 'ill!)), 11(1;11. till ii rh 'III and the It the e?pele,e of the cerinis. 'I he '4i ti inenia, ' (:'.(11g1;1. Amhavdilian, and Ow 11/11(1,, 111111 551,11? lo?IC,,t1 19(10, liii 'till 11". 1"1"" "Tinil;11 Val 11111(//1% 111 1/1'1' l'ill/11A ;W1.11'111111111 1!111 \\Al 1.1'!,(1111/11 1.1'1;11111:11 (111 11`1.111(.1": 111 1!;1111% 111 1111 111/11;1 industrial 111111111' 11111, lthinii the absolute range of variation ?va.; consideralily smaller. ?v.is ill the Center and the Celina, Cliciliozeiti Il'i'ituIl Ill Illy liSFSit, Nfoldavi 11'1oIll','il? and Lithuania. ;111'1 111 Ow VnIt&?')%ilka least (i Ill Central Asia and Transcaucasia (see ti). Of those riTioi sltil hclow-a?Traie 1(?vels of per capita larm output ill 11u.4) 1 ti t ...?? why ?le ...111,1' Urals, Volga.A'yall,a, and Ow Far Vast trp;ions of the aml the Ce()rgia and "l'orkinen Itepublies 11111511! to\vaid 111111 average in relative terms hi 55'''191 19(4) 1(1111 1)(i!) 7). illus die tremls ill i)er {?;ipita national income and imlustrial ail(1 i)r((ltiction all confirm, the in.esence of ;1 Loge and gro\viiii,, disparity in economic (1''vc1()I'1111'111 11rtw''''11 till' (11'vri()1"1 ;11.cas ((:011tral Asia, thy .1.ranN('1111511s? 111(1 the North ;Ilicasus ainl the rest of the coontry. the economies (11 lJI HTinns ha"' 1)ro'n'ssod III thr 11`,1 ducado. file rat(' Ill Pr( 1.1:1-css ill t:H' 1,?%s (levelope/1 it' tills has been too slo?v for these re,,,ions eatc.hiln; up to the rest of the conotry, REGIONAL TRENDS IN POPULATION GROWTH Natural Increase Thc \vide regional differences Ill population growth in ti0 I rSSIi (111r1111r, 1111' 19(O', (S(4' Figlin. 8) reflect patterns of erliwth that ;ire characteristic of the development process thro.eghinit much of the world. The lowest rates of !lateral increase occurred priniariiy in the European an?as of the couriry (see Table 2), ?vhere iirbanization is fairly \yell establied and ?vliere per capita 'noun is high. Conversely the highest rates are in Central Asia and the Caucasus ?vnere P'' capita income is low. The coefficient of variation iticrew.ed slightly frnin 0.383 in 1960 to 0.385 ill 1969. " The 1.01.1licivot of variation shou.rd an increase 1:om 0.34:3 in WOO to 0.300 in 1969, " natural rate of population incrt?ase is the difference bet?yeen the birth rate and the death rate and equals the numerical increase per 1,000 of the existing population. 12 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 USSR: Regional Variations in Average Annual Growth of Per Capita Industrial Production, 1961-69' All-Ur ion Average 8.9"0 per Veer - F-1 11 Significantly above average (more than 7.4% per year) A 'rage growth (6.4% to 7.4" per yonr) ri Significantly below overage (fess than 6.4% Per year) 'Source Appendor Table Al. 14 Average Annual Rate of Growth(%) Hume 4 Republics RSFSR Economic Regions 1. EAtenli 8.1 15. Northweit 5.8 2. Latvle 8.3 IL Center 5.8 3. Lithuania 10.4 17. Central Chernozem 9.4 4. Belerustie 10.2 II. North Caucaous 8.7 5. Ukraine 7.8 19. Volga-Vyatka 8.8 8. Moldavia 9.1 20. Volga Veil,/ 8.6 7. Georgia 8.3 21. Urals 7.6 e. Armenia 6.9 22. 'Nest Siberia 7.9 a. Azerliagdzhin 3.5 23. East Siberia 8.5 10. Turkmen 3.2 24. Fr East 7.3 Uzbek 3.4 17 Tadzhik 4.9 411 7.9 14. Kazakh 6.8 13 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 40 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Figure 5 04% USSR: Regional Gaps in Per Capita Industvial Production (Porcent Ahoy? or Bolow Souks' Avorogo) - .v) Center Imiteestaavairmatosaairamsermanniai 40", Northwest Istonia WO, Urals Ukraine Tar Fest -10% Volge-Vsatke -11",, Volpe Valley -20"? -32",, -20",, NANNMAMAAAININNNMNMMIMMNOIIMOIINIMNMI 47", 341, SUMMNIIIME 40% 29' 20% BIMMIIIMI 13% 2",. -14"? Jest Siberia -17% -19% 111111.1111.1114. -10% -0?, -44"? -45% -40% -40% 44"r, -18?? 11111,11Mlin 11111111?111 -50?, -63", WillatilminP"MENIMEMOMMEINI -52", -53% cc"" raras -57% -48% 1111011?1111111111111111?11?11110111111111111MMI North Outdone East Siberia Armenia Georgia Lith aisle ezerboydzhan Belorussia Kazakh Moldevla Kirgiz Uzbek Tadzhik Is Central Chernozem 36% 45% 14 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 6 I% Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 USSR: Regional Variations in Average Annual Growth of Per Capita Agriculturril Production, 1.961-69' All-Union Average 1.6% per Year Significantly above average (rncre than 2.1? per ylnr) ri Ave ?go growth (1.1 to 2.1% per year) Signi; cantly below average (less ts,sn 1.1, per year) .SOUTCP ,)ppenrItx Table A- I . I I 23 Average Annual Rate of Growth(%) Republics I. Estonia 2. Latvia 3. Lithuania 4. Belorussia 5. Ukraine 6. Moldavia 7. Geomia 0. Arm,,ia O. Azerbaydzhan 10. Turkmen 11. Uzbek 12. Tadzhik Figure 6 IISFSR Economic Regions 1.2 15. Northwest 1.3 1.1 16. Center 2.5 2.9 17. Central Chernozem 3.0 3.1 10. North Caucasus 0.5 1.6 19. Volga-Vyatka 2.9 3.7 20. Volga Valley 2.1 2.1 21. Urals 1.0 - 1.0 22. West Siberia 0.4 -1.0 23. East Ziheria 0.7 1.8 24. Far East 1.0 --0.7 -Nag!. 13. Kirgiz 1.1 14. Kazakh 0.3 15 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 USSR: Regional Gaps in Per Capita Agricultural Production (Percent Above or Below Soviet Average) -37". -38% -48". -58% 11513MUM -49% -500. anneffaMMIIMMiNariniMiligiNEEM -50% -6O % -59% -58% Estonia I Lithuania Latvia Central Chernozem Ilelorussia Kazakh North Caucasus West Siberia Moldavia Ukroine -14% -28% -22",, ? Volga Valley -1". - Figure 7 itairemmoissmargeamaniammaraman 5 1.,,? IITTRINIZIONSKIEMEMLIIINI "? ostammenatorznistawrowa 30% 4 NM 6", --10",, 23% 12"? 18",, 18% 17% 1.11.111111M. 180 12". 1111=111111111111110?len,, Uzbek Volge-Vyatke East Siberia Turkmen Urals Kirgiz Tadzhik Center Georgia Armenia No Azerbaydzhan Far East 32",, 37% 43% 52",, 16 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 66", Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 USSR: Regional Variations in Population Growth, 1961-69* Figure 8 All-Union Average - 1.3% per Year f---1 Significantly above avenge I I (more than 1.8% per year) r 1 Average growth "" (0.8% to 1.8% per year) Significantly below average (less than 0.8% per year) 'Source: Appendix Table Al. 23 21 Avrrage Annual Rate of Growth ('/.) Repuhlics RSFSR Economic Regions 1. Estonia 1.1 15. Northwest 1.0 2. Latvia 1.1 16. Center 0.5 3. 1,thuania 1.3 17. Central Chornozom 0.2 9. Belorussia 1.0 10. North Caucasus 1.0 5. Ukraine 1.0 19. Volga-Vyatka Nog,. 3. Moldavia 1.J 20. Volga Valley 1.2 7. Georgia 1.4 21. Urals 0.6 0. Armada 3.0 22, West Siberia 0.6 9. Azorbaydzhan 3.0 23. East Siberia 1.2 10. Turkmen 3.2 29. Far East i.g 11. Uzbek 3.6 12. Tadzhik 3.6 13. Kirgiz 3.3 14. Kazakh 2.7 17 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Table USSR: Ratcs of Nab ml Population Increase, by Republic and Region " Per 1,000 1900 1970 Turkmen 35.9 28.6 Tadzhik 28.4 28.3 Uzbek 33.9 28.0 Kirgiz 30.8 23.1 Azerbayclzhan 36.0 22.5 Kazakh 30.7 17.3 Armenia 33.3 17.0 Moldavia 22.8 12.0 Georgia 18.2 11.0 Far East 18.7 10.3 b East Siberia 20.9 10.1' North Caucasus 16.8 9.1 b Lithunnii 14.7 8.7 Belorussia 17.8 8.6 Volga Valley 18.0 8.0 b West Siberia 19.8 7.6" Urals 17.8 7.313 Ukraine 13.6 6.3 Volga-Vyatka 16.6 5.8 b Northwest 13.1 4.9 b Estonia 6.1 4.7 Central Chernozem 14.1 4.1' Latvia 6.7 3.3 Center 10.7 3.1" USSR 17.8 9.2 RSFSR 8.9 5.9 ' Narodnoyc khozynystvo SSSR v 1967 godu, pp. 40-41; v 1970, pp. 50-51. "1907. These wide variations in rates of natural increase resulted primarily from large regional differences in birth rates, as death rates varied relatively Jittle among the reg:ons. In Central Asia, for example, where the urbanization process is a relatively recent phenomenon, birth ratc: were the highest in the country-more than doublp the rate in the RSFSR-while death rates were slightly lower than in the RSFSR. In addition to the usual "urban/rural" and "developed/less developed" reasons, inherent differences in the cultural outlook of different nationalities, particularly between the Slays at one extreme and the Turkic peoples at the other, have undoubtedly been a source of disparate birth rates among the regions. For ex- ample, according to a recent survey on family size conducted by the Central Statistical Administration," the number of children considered "ideal" among married women varied from two to three in the European republics and throug;, out the RSFSR, to from three to five in the republics of Central Asia and Trans- caucasia. Even more striking is the fact that the pprecntage of women who consider six cr more children "ideal" is significantly wca ter in the Central Asian and TranscLucasian republics than in any other region of the country. In all regions, the number of children actually anticipated by the families in Ih? survey was slightly 'less than the numb N considered "ideal," ranging from t. in the European areas and the RSFSR to three to four in Central Asia and Transcaucasia. These differences in attitudes regarding family size reflect, among " The survey was conducted in 1969 and the re. published in an article by Belova, V., "Obsledovaniye mnerni o nailyuchshein i ozhidayemom chisle detey v sem'ye," Vcstnik stntistiki, no 0, 1971, pp. 23-34. 18 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 other things, regional variations in the average age at marriage. The average age of newly married couples in the PSI7S14 is currently 29+ for men and 27+ for women and increasing, but in Central Asia the average age is in the low 20s and stable. It is not surprising, therefore, that the natural rate of population increase is now as much ds four times great 3. in the Central Asian republics as in the RSFSR as a whole. Every region except the Tadzhik Republic shared in the remarkable decline in rates of population growth that occurred in the 1960s. The general fall in rates of natural increase, however, did not disturb appreciably the substantial regional differences that existed in 1960. Migration Usually, migration of population acts to reduce regional disparities in popula- tion growth and income levels?that s, people move out of regions of high rates of population g?-owth and low incomes into regions of lower population growth and high incomes. This pattern was most notable in the Baltic republics of Latvia and Estonia, where in-migration was the dominant source of population growth, and in Azerbaydzhan, the only area of high population growth that experienced a net out-migration during this period (see Table 3). Table 3 USSR: The Contribution of Natural Increase and Migration to Population Growth, by Region 1960-70 Net Percentage Change in Population Percentage Change Due to Natural Inc! 'ase ? Percentage Change Due to Migration b Out-migration Central Chernozem ? ....... .. . 3 11 ?8 Volga-Vyatka .. ......... . . 1 7 ?6 West Siberia . 8 14 ?6 Urals 7 13 ?6 Belorussia 12 15 ?3 Georgia 16 18 ?2 East Siberia 15 17 ?2 Azerbayclzhan 38 39 ?1 Center 8 9 ?1 Northwest 12 12 Negi. In-migration Turkmen . .. . 42 42 Negl. Volga Valley 15 15 Negl. Ukraine 13 12 1 Lithuania 15 14 1 Moldavia 24 22 2 Far East 20 17 3 Uzbek 45 41 4 Kirgiz 42 36 6 North Caucasus 23 16 7 Latvia 13 6 1 Estonia 13 6 7 Armenia 41 33 8 Kazakh 40 32 8 Tadzhik 46 37 9 USSR 16 16 N.A. RSFSR 11 12 ?1 " Change in population that would have resulted from natural rates of increase alone. ? Derived by comparing the 1972 census results with the population that would have resulted from natural rates of increase alone. 19 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 On the other hand, migration atra,ravated regional disparities in natural population growth in most republies?rct,irding the growth of population in areas with relatively low rates of natural increase mid augmenting growth in areas already having relatively high rates of natural increase. On froin tlw regions of the 11SFS11, with the exception of the North Cancams and the Far East, tended to reinforce the effects of the already relatively low rates of natural increase. This effect was most prominent in the Volga-Vyatka, Central Chernozem, West Siberian, and Urals regions where out-migration reduced the effects of natural population increase by 86%, 73%, 43%, awl 46%, re.pectively. On the other hand, the net migration into the republics of Central Asia and Annenia, where the rate.; of natural increase were among the highest in the country, had just the opposite effect. Much of the migration over the last decade has been closely linked to the massive flow of rural residents to urban areas. Nearly one-half the growth of the country's urban population between 1959 and 1970 was due to the migration from rural to urba:i areas, although the intensity of the rural-zuban flow has not been uniform in all regions. In the IISFSR, out-migration from rural areas was approximately double the natural increase ip these areas, resulting in an absolute decline in the rural population. The decline was most prevalent in the Central, Volga-Vyatka, Central Chernozem, West Siberian, Northwest, and Urals regions. Within the RSFSR, only the North Caucasus and Far East regions incurred an increase in rural population during this period. On the other hand, in the Central Asian republics the rapidly growing rural population has tended to he considerthly less mobile. In fact, Soviet demographers have pointed out that ? :wit of the urban population growth in these repub!ies has been the result of i influx of people In. n other regions, notably from West Siberiv and the Urals, rather than from their own rural areas. In many cases this has created urban enclaves of Slavic peoples surrounded by rural areas populated by the rapidly growing indigenous ethnic groups. Thus the economic growth that has taken place in the Central Asian republics in recent years has not been accompanied by a general assimilation of the Turkic peoples into the urban-industrial economy. In the absence of an influx of workers from other regions, economic growth in these republics :.light well have been less, but a continuation of this pattern would enhance the colonial image that the central government has been trying to shed ui these regions and limit the opportunities for drawing the indigenous population into more advanced indus- trial processes. Practices followed in :ing labor, particularly highly skilled labor, do little to alleviate this Ation. Students holding post-graduate de, rees are generAy assigned to remote areas for a period of three years followirg com- pletion of their studies. Many of these specialists avoid such duty through one or another loophole in the regulati:-,ns. However, most of those who are unable to avoid a remote work assignment settle afterwards in other regions, notably in the larger urban areas such as Moscow and Leningrad, or in the southern cities where the warmer climate provides considerable incentive after three years in the harsh northern or eastern regions. This attraction of skilled labor to the southern regions is reinforced by Soviet wage policy. Regional wage differentials, designed to attract and retain labor in the more remote or clirra :c.ally severe regions ( especially Vberia and the Far East), are insufficient to counter the attraction of the southern cities. Consequently, skilled laborers are pulled into the urban areas of Central Asia, where they are warmly received by employers who would rather hire Slays than the generally less well trained Turkic people at Lie same rates of pay. 4proved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 The rapid population growth in the less developed reg,imis was accompanied by a somewhat slower growth of population of working age (see Table 4); able-bodied population in the Central /Wall republics grew about 20%-30% between 1960 and 1970 (compared with a population growth of about 40%) because of low population growth in the early 19505. However, in 1970-80 the able-bodied population will surge because of the high birlh rates of 1960-70. !knee, the problem of finding work for rural minority group labor will become CV( 'II more acute in the .1970s. Tolle 4 USSR: Index of Growth of Able-Bodied Popuhnion, by Republic '1 1960-70 1959= 100 Kazakh 131 Armenia 131 Kirgiz 129 Uzbek 124 Tadzhik 123 Turkmen 123 Moldavia 119 Azerbaydzhan 118 Estonia 111. f.atvia 109 Lithuania 109 Georgia 109 Belorussia 107 MESH 108 Ukraine 105 ' Males between 16 and 60 years of age and females between 16 and 54 years of age. Based on 1970 census data reported in the regional press. REGIOAAL INVESTMENT POLICY Ac2ording to all the measures discussed above, the differences among regions with respect to per capita income and output widened rather than narrowed during the 1960s. The other major factors determining growth of income and output, apart from population growth, are investment allocations, by region, and the return on investment, by region. Inconsistency Between Regional Policy and Investment Allocations The professed official policy of favoring the less developed regions is not borne out by the pattern of investment allocations. Per capita new fixed invest- ment in 1960-69 has not favored consistently those republics that had the lowest national income per capita in 196020 (sec Figure 9). Although some of the poorer republics?notably the Kazakh and Thrlonen Republics?received more investment funds per capita than the richer republics, " The Kendall rank order correlation coefficient relating per capita aew fixed investment in 1900-69 to per capita regional income in 1960 was 0.410. In other words, there was some positive correlation in the SCI1V3 that areas with relatively high per capita national incomes in the base year tended to be favored with relatively high per capita investments expressed in rubles. While the relationship did not indicate a strong planners bias in favor of the "rich" republics, the results certainly did not suggest that a policy of giving preference exclusive to the lagging areas was followed. The coefficient would have been ?1.00 if investment alloca- tions had been inversely related to income levels with perfect consistency. 21 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 USSR: Ranking ol Union Renublics, by Per Capita National Income and Per Capita New Fixed Investment Figu. 9 National Income Per Capita, 1960 Per Capita New Fixed Investment, 1C30-69" (1958 rubles) (1955 rubles) 940 Latvia 099 Estonia 765 IISFS11 678 Lithuania 675 Ukrelne 5R0 Azerbay6zhan 522 Armenia 521 Moldavia 517 Belorussia 511 Kazakh 509 Turkmen 484 Georgia 460 Uzbek 449 Kirgiz 380 Tadzhik 691 2i to 25i4 2265 I 1939 ; 1819 1578 1525 1568 1980 2782 ? 2336 1458 1652 1543 1532 ?Cumulative investment, 1960-69, divided by 1965 population. 2100 22 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 ihv ccorom, and T1,1,11il, \vele given lions barely hull iis 'hose funneled inn) Ntoirovei, the relaiively high invesiineni the K.1/01,11 and inikiiien \yen' used largely exploitation of iiiiiniiI iiul hiel h'eposits. Soviet polievinal,ers ill making, decisions hom the /vide! may 11;ivr emr,ideo,(11 the regional parity goal, clearly ollop factwr.. hav temper-I 11M, SI(IVIA11011 N1'11111 111111S 1111(1(.. Willtiti II"' lut?v"'cr, "Illita Ow(-1111'10 alliwatt?11s 11)1)1.a. to have favored the less developed Isastern r;.giore,, partieularlv Fast Silot ii iipii the Far Fast. Throngliont most Of the HMOs,'" per capita investment allocations iii these reg,ions appear to have liven consistently higher than in any (Wier region of the liSFSIt or in any other union republic. This may reflect, it) pit I. it planners' preference for developing the eastern regions, though perImps motivated less by equality considerations and more by a desire to exploit the vast natural resource base in these regions. The high investment alloratiiris to the eastern regions of the IISFS11 may :dm) reflect the greater cosIs moat ill tht? general development of these regions. CPYRGHT Higher Growth of Productivity in the Mor Developed Regions To narrow the dif ferences ill reg,ional !evils of development sig,nificantiy, the USSR must fly in the face of the best investment opportunities. Increases in industrial prodiiction are becoming relolively more expensive to achieve in most of the less developed areas of the USSR tlimi in the already developed western regions. One measure of this is the relinively low growtli of produclivity of inputs of labor and capital in many of the poorer regiia1s.2". ? ? " Comparable investment data for the regions of the IISVSIt were available only for 1900, 1965, 196(3, md 1967 in Narodnoye kozyaystvo StiSll v 1967 godu,p. 625. "Although it is usual to consider the incremental canital-output ratios \Olen discussing in- vestment priorities, the growth of combined factor prodlictivity is considered to be a better indicator for the allocation of investment among regions, since it is misleading to suggest that increases in output are due solely to capital accumulation. As C.M. Meier points out, Even if we accept the assumption that thew is a fixed relatioi,ship bet?vven capital and output as determined by technical factors, it does not fc.11oyv that we can infer from this relationship that only capital is needed to incre.ra, outdid. We must also consider explicitly the effect of other variables on output--for example, the supply of trained manpinver, entrepreneurship, institutional arrant...ements, attitudes, etc. (MI,' , Leading Issues in 1)evelop. tent F,co lllll nics (2nd Ed.), ()xford University Press, New York, i 970, p. 177.) Lab( r and capital inputs were combilmd in i ( obb-l)ouglas prodnetion function under the assumption that the inputs xvere paid the 011?11' marginal products in Om base year. Fcr the derivation of production finiction toeff,cients, see Appendix B. Tin, measure of combined factor productivity was derived as the residual ` ment yvhich accounts for that p?..rt of the annual pereentai,,,e increase in output in excess of increases in 4,,gregate itiptits?...iiat is, where: ---= ? +(1?a)'' - AA AV [ Al. A Q ' K ] A =Residual (combined factor productivity), Q=Industrial output, 1, = Man hours of lab" input, K=Industrial fixed capital stock, a and (1?a) -1,abor and capital coefficients. Since it is a residual, c,,inhined factor productivity covers the contribution of many factors to the growth of output such as the contribution of management improvements in resource alloca- tion, economies of scale, increases in the skill level of labor, and any other phenomena that may affect the efficiency with which industrial production is carried out. 23 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approv,ed For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 II 11,1?,1 ill/ IC1111'111, Ill 1111111'AI I;11 11111 1 IWO III 101011,, r.nikk'n ir in lin. lii.V1'111111l I Ill '.1/1111' 11;1\1'IIf 11.111V ii 1111111 (..cc lahlc !)). (m11611111 Lit too ll;11 1 II 11111ft '.uiitult ii IfIhIliiI in I Lii1%1.111, .1 III 1,1111'16;1, /\ /CI il;1? I 0011)111 Iii4s 31 ith, 101,0\ Illo 1,31 Avil,09? (Ii".101cliii thi1v!' .1v11019' gli!?vIll of(.m111'1111(1 1011111'. "I 1"'I"" "'", (.1pit.11 filIi itjitiiihti litconlia'.1. Itallic ((Tubb, loec?thci ???ith Itclo And ti hi pv6/.1111'11 CA. laiv,(",1 1111 I 1 IIIliit'li ft (1111 fill lailni IipliliutiIIVI!V In 4.i.111 if gic?t. Ilii".30,o ,r, fill. 11;11 :ivoiagy, p vc15",10?v t!,,,\v1 wind., ciirin.,1 'Fable 5 1 'ottibined Factor l'roductivity in Indust' y Alcolute Clcolge i'..ndoned Pio Ill uvit , I 1,1. Av etair.e Awn c I AnIn1:d lIt 111111,111 of if I:Imo!! ol I it Id- 11,11113,vilv, 1961 1,9 1111:11;,,, 1961 ',10i1,00,I I IIIill Percent Latvia ! 3 1 3.1 .5.!0 12 l':'11(o11111.. I .'.111 :1.:i I nod( all,:in 2.S :1 .?I 7 I II? riitii. III i 1 2.3 I; . 2 I I 1,01,,iiiiint 0. Ti 2.4 .1 !I.3 2 I leorgin 0.,41 1; 2.2 41 15 liigiz .. 0.79 7 2. 1 s 9.3 3 1111,'411 0.0? !i 2." 7 5.6 1,1 Nlohlavia !I I .2 910.0 , Al'Illl'Ilill 11.31 10 09 . III 9.1 4 titzalcli ... 0.15 11 6.0 1 1 9.1 5 Azerbityllzhan .. 0 02 12 O. 1 12 0.6 10 Tadzhik ILI) 1:1 11.1 1:1 Y.',.1 6 Uzbek .. 0.1:11 14 OA 1.1 7.6 9 Turk!, 1.... it 21 Tr, I .0 I 5 7.44 N O. GI; 2.2 li. II (, Q? ? I Ivri v1.11 ii,,. Ik.. This patter!, of productivity groxvtlt is not particidarly surprising,. ravorible factors for growth are usually available in areas of considerable urbaniriclustrial development. Therefore, given an existing spatial distribMion of urban-indus- trial development, this distribution could be expected t( exert a significant influence on the regjonal pattern of productivity groxYlb." The rcason is that l)ifferences in the industrial structures of the republic's niay aho ;lemma for some of the regional differences in productivity growth-that is, if output per unit of combined inputs grows faster in song. branches of in,1,,,;tr:.? than in othcrs, then icgions in ?vhicii the faster growiag branches predominate might show it higher rate of growth of overall factor productivity. Koropeckyj attempts to deal with this problem by analyzing the productivity of various indus- trial branches in most of the republics over 11w period 1958-65 (Koropeckyj, "Industrial Loca- tion Policy," op. cit., pp. 290-295). Although his results show r relatively higher growth of total factor productivity for some of the less developed republic's, Koropeckyls evidence is based on average annual ra? ,s of change covering a different time period than that covered in this paper. Moreover, tin.' tilne period examined by Koropcckyj was not consistent for all republics, and the data appear to require very b'oad assumptions with respect to comparability and the problem of matching the coverage of ii puts and output. 24 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 1,.iitt.,111 plug iii 111011' III ()I Ho',11 ,1111 Ad\ villi:111 1111111'.111;11 (.11114'1'.ii;11',1',11111111111111 , 1)111111111. 111.11i 111111111Ie", 111)111 (hi cow culialiou (.1 ? ..iwown. III ,1 ;lI 11 ;11c,1 ?hal iii IiAle iiiI liivial can hest'ell III OW 1?11111111111.11 1'1 11.11111111 1111 111111111 1" 111 11W 1,11 l',1".1 111111111111111,111 1111",11111' i11111?111 f1111111,1',1', (Ill 111?1 111)1111W HI, '111,1111 1 11111,111 11(-1''? "fiii 1 l',411(1111V 1"111111 II I 11111 11""1"' Ii II"1"""' 11111 "1);11H1 rX1.(111,'?luililit,'11111 I l\ 11"V 111.1111'' I" "1"11 II"Il 111 11011", 11'1'11111', 111,11 111' ,11111111' 11'111 (111'111111 1 1 111.111 11 (1111", t11 11111111 114 1,1111' ( MC111111111! liii t,oiiifiij ',11(1,11 111'11111..111 )ii (Iii ii 11'1111)11111 Ic11,11111),. it i?. t?asita Iii i,uii,jLi(i n?t?Iiiittlitg,ical and nib o the iitainstosini til iiitaluction10 liii tlliiiiv highly dc\ clopcd uIilIIl lins if i.. 1011 ii 111,1111 that rot.)in.ao ire,n)ir, of the coonliv, m \dud' tuned (lcvekintictif 1.; c(oireof 1.111.41. .,ho\v flo. 11111?; of cititiltitu'il factor 1)1(1(111(1101v. .1 heir is net tituih II) stip:gest fli..1 111110 ovciii()\v(hio', awl iii Il curd.; id t)flf?vf.i);1) uiiiiiniup'r of in ho IMPIICATIONS FOR SOVIET POLICY Investment Allocationn The regional trends examined this paper conliont Soviet planners and political leaders with a policy dilemma. A signific;m1 reduution of regional in- come differentials and maximum national economic groxvtli cannot he achieved simultaneously through investment strategy alone. II maximum national economic growth is to (be chief criterion for allocating investment, then capital should he directed primarily toxvard those re0ons III svhich if is most productive. But, as die dala on factor productivity in industry sugg,est, these are not the sante regions in ?vhic?I) lie;:vy investment allocations vvotild be consistent ?vith a policy 0rien1:.(1 to\vard achieving regional parity In income. ()lily with the help of migration policy could all regions move toxvard income parity, since the most rapid popidatiou growth is occurring it) those regions with the lowest income gro?vt1). SOlificantly increa..ing the development of labor-intensive branches of industry in the less (1('VelO1)r(1 regions, to utilize their rapidly groxving supply of "warm bodies- of xvorl:ing i!; not lihrly to he a viable subAitute for out-migration of labor. Much of the growth of able-bodied population in these regions consists of unskilled rural residents whose social and cultural habits inhibit vocational transitions. Therefore, given the distribution of opportunities, it is not surprising that Soviet investmont patterns have not favored consistently those republic's with lo?v per capita ii,tional income in 1960. ()? the other hand, the evidence is not "For instance, the Lithuanian Council of Minister; reeentiv imported tho industri!!! dcvdep went continues to expand much inure rapidly in the cities of \ ;loins and Kaunas, which already accounted for over one-half of Lithuania's industry in 1960, than in the small and medium-size cities of the republic!, despite official pleadings to the contrary. (lzvestiva. 13 liii 1971. p. 3.) m As one author puts it, The continued growth of even the largest metropolitan regions in the world contra- dicts the expectation of diminishing marginal returns to scale ... there is no evidence that metropolitan areas have ceased to grow anywhere as the result of presumed social diseconotWes. (Friedman, J., Regional Development Policy: A Case Study of Venezuela, MIT, Cambridge, 196(3, pp. 19-15.) CPYRGHT Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 25 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 ..11111111. 111;11 1111111111 1 \l'41', 11Ic l'.11111111r, 1111116111r 111V1".1111,111 ;111(),';111(III..? 1 111 1111'; 111;11' 11'111'd 1111 111 I 111 iiiv 1.11.111 1111 1111.1111111111(1M' ;111(1 ;WI ri'd 1111(111 11'111111)1111' 1'1 1111 11111 1111 1111111c1111111111V, 11111111111111 Illl'1";11111.111 1111111V ( 11111 III 11011111111 11'.1111c 111 II 11;itd), palII oho I VIII' 11",111,1 111 1111111%1 1 1;11 li)(?111 ji ii / ;11 'fir' 111;111 11". 1;1'1' "I '1 1" "1 11 r?("11 1"1 r?;1111111r. "1"11111/1111', 1 11111 111r1 i"fl'"1 uii IIii lvii 'I diuf 1}1, 10,, vi, rviwatriliv Ili dud oil, ;11 11111;11 V ;11111 111(1,W.1.4(111 ililtIllIli, "1 a 1 1 iV1)1', II 1"?!1"11 (1".151("" in If 1 1Y, 11 ;11111 1111' 1 '1 11111;11111'1111 V 1'1 111'1 11 11111'1, 1141 1 111 p lii V!Mull 111.1.1!;11111,;.'"I (1Virk 1101' lo'i'n 00.11)1c 11) i1111)1"11(111 171 inv("""" 14) achievr 1)44114 lia,,4444441 4,v4441v and lowdown) prinhiclioo sitiodlaneoludy, if appcal., Itom 114c cvichatur al 1117111 1111111 W1.11k, 11111 ;11.111111 111V111111111 111111(N' liivi hiOluif 111(17.1,Iiisiiif Ili,. IA fru :is 111071):,,ts ?mid dt \VItile this ?votild be (4.1e.istent \vitt) the ptinciple of moving capital 1'1 N(1111.11S illi tIll 111.111111111 11'101/11;11 111111)1111 iticiritits In ow thry (1)10611111r imi:,11.,,11:,:ia11)::(HAhil:?1(1:1:11ti,millifl:1111)::11(i:11, Nit I( !IX:(1' region;41 parity !oust iiiiihttii 441114 capital investment (particularly iii 11w 11",s \Nadi 0111-7itigral1011 01 111101. Irmo 4.1H?se regions. llo?vever, no significant efforts have been made over the Pa`,1 10 sfiall 111(' 110\v 01 1010 Cilitral Asia 111(' Transcaneasus or to shift labor from these areas to other parts of the t1SSII. Migration Policy While more stringent control over migration into the less developed regions IS a clear possibility for the future, the problem of \vital to (II) about the rapidly increasing indigenous population remains. F'orced out-migration, though possible, cloes not seem to be a likely course of action. Aside from the fact that Turl:ic population may be un?villing to MOW` and til(' "host" Slavic popula- tion unreceptive to such movement, the educational aml language ('01. 1111)11 that prevents most of the Turkic population from entering the skilled labor force, logetker with the orientation of these people toward irrigation agriculture, warm climates, and large families, Inalws it indilaly that they c?ould readily adapt to the living conditions aml vocational demands in either tile 1,-,tfrol)ean 01' Siberian regions of the country. Moreover, the facilities to accumitmdate SPell in-migrants are sthely lacking throughout these regions. 'lousing wooiti provide a particularly Inuiblestnne prolilein as well as a r'itential source of fricti()n 1,0,.vern the Slavic popti!ation and the ne?vconteis, MIKA' it is already in Ott)rt stipply antl not generally suited to the traditionally large families of the TurIcic p(ople.s. 1)ifficult thoti,;11 it may in, out-nni.,,ration from the less clev(sloi)ed regions may have to be encouraged, aml i)roperly accommodated, if the St)victs want to " Industrial investment in 1961-69 has not favored coes4stently those republics w?14 high levels of industrial factor productivity in 1960. The Kendall rank order correlation coefficie-it relating the average annual growth of industrial new fixed investment ii) 1961-69 to the level of industrial factor productivity in 1960 was 0.048. The coefficient relating the average annual growth of innbined inputs of labor and capital in 1901-69 to the level of industrial factor productivio in 1960 was 0.162. n Defense considerations may also weigh heavily in investment decisions, although in a nuclear age it seems likely that these considerations would lu? more consistent with maximizing production than with creating region.I parity. The relatively large investment allocations to some of the less developed republics in Central Asia no doubt reflect the exploitation of natural resources at least as much as the implementation of any specific defense measures. "Vsevolod flolabnychy has prepared an excellent summary and bibliography on this point in Spatial Efficiency in the Soviet Economy, a paper delivered at the AEA-ASSTE meeting in New Orleans on 28 December 1971. 26 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 avoiI. i Ilicse iegjoils. inimaity nationalitiesif i vi Iv I income. At the veiv least Ric cawii Italy ), the movement 01 infligt11011% lah()I Ii iii 1111a1to ',1141?111 l'.1111011 1114,1' iII )EIV( to lie inereased. I \\'11111(1 1{11111.(' SLIVir iii iiii'i.iiiI Iii 11"".4' vIiii lifihhhi.,.1111 lily lInted, may pima. iIifiiiilt vith iiiil ,,imiilicant chailiran,ii (amen( y?ige Pions for 1971-75 Thi? 1971 75 plan indicatins, ilY imion suggest that past development Pattiaos iII not iliality.e lathe:111v "ver the neNt \l'arS? 11". P11111"1 gr"Wth of iiiIiiiiiaI income in each republic, shown in Till& (I heinw, is (kne piece of evidence. The most rapid growth is planned for Moldavia, Beim iissia, Armenia, and 1.iilmania, followed by the Turkic republics of llzbekistan, Kazakhstan, and Azerb.iydzhan. This gi owth, if ititained, \void(' represent a relative ill Ito' position of Uzbekistan and Azerbaydzhau---republies which grew ;it helOW- IIVCrage 11960S, ()II a per capita basis, however, ninch of this planned improvement may be offset by conlitmed high population growth. In the agricultural sector, the h! .gest percentage increase in production (hiring 1971-75 (comPared with 1900-70) is slated I ,? Moldavia. where Per ciPita production during the 1900s was already above the national average. Altliongb above-average increases are also plama?el for Azerbaydzhan, Armenia, Tadzhiki- stan, and Ceorgia, it is not likely that these increments will go far toward bringing, these republics up :o the national average, parti_ alarly if no major changes occur in the regional pattern of population grow,h. The regional pattern of growth in industry planned for 1971-75 is quiie similar to that planned kw 19136-70?that is, the most rapid growth is slated generally for the less devehiped II 'I Based on past pert ()nuance, some of these republics, particularly the Tnrkinen and Uzbek Republics. probably will fall short of the planned growth. The likelihood of snch shortfalls becomes even greater when One considers that Ow pianned growth of industrial output must be achiev.11 through significv.ot increases in prialuctivity rather thaii by large incugnents to inputs. This ind;cation of a growing pinch on available resources has been emphasized by the Soviet leadership and is mirrored in the plan data for increases in total capital investment by republics. The regional plans also suggest that investment per capita iii most of the minority national republics will probably grow somewhat slower than during 1906-70 or, at best, maintain the same rate of growth. Only in Azerbaydzhan is the 1971-75 planned increase in per capita investment significantly greater than that achieved during 1966-70. The scheduled reductions in per capita investment growth rates are especially steep in the Lithuanian, Belorussian, Ar- menian, and Uzbek Republics. Despite these changes in growth rates, the largest investment allocations per capita will continue to go to the same five republics during 1971-75 as during 1961-65 and 1966-70?Estonia, Turkmenia, Latvia, the IISFS11, and Kazakhstan (see Figure 10). Thus it appears that no major shift in the regional distribution of per capita investment is contemplated. " Although plan data for the economic regions of the RSFSII are almost nonexistent, the planned growth of industrial production in Siberia and the Far East is reported to he above the national avcrage. 27 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 , : ?-? I'D it ?i? .? 1 c. ?I/ 1 ? ?1. 0` 71 't, . 'et 11 I -P 1. I, . ? , fv1 : 1 I. 4r6 476 64-c, ,4 c:LI 47, ?-? 9-1 4,/ /C/ On/ ./., I //I 1 . -0 70 ro 07, 70 /-1 ?-1 .-1 "0 .7) 01 '0 ??1' '7 I .0 01 C, 7 1 0, r t- C't '71 01 70 ?-? 7.IC 01 CI 71 01 ?',1 CCC. f` CO ? a) ?7?1 !NI aa? ?-? 01 or ?-? r- r '4) ?() .0 ".0 "*. .0 .7' .t. t0 70 .1. n//1 nA nA .A r- (0 ,71 ? ? CD CD./-? I- ,rn ,71 .7t. "e -1' we C0 70 70 :0 co GI al -'1? 0 ..... ? .... 0 0 0 03 .S0 -la ,.1 i )0 ,T, .E E :E ?gi ?-a, ..'. 71; -2 c",'3 :%) '-'0 .'-? x --s` ;" Ts '-',,, ch .t, ol -,1 ..: :4 -e. ?.4 :34 g4 E4 (...0 CI) 44 ?1. i6,, A . al ,-.4, C11 6-; . a) " 4,_. ,,1 cl. ?-? 11, 0) ? 6 r... .,-., ;.11 ?vi ,,, 7.: &I T.) o to 0 4 ,n 'C 0 ? - - . : : h ' T '(1)1 'i'i . , - . ? ? . . . . . ,T . a N 4 0 i.t I.? 1- 0 ..., 0 i I. 4, 01 1.. I ?? TO. -111 'I; H ,--. E .F: ,;' :C.1). ? t-, -,i`:, C .11 u., - H ?:-.1 cu .?--, -0 O 0 04) f,i1 ....--.) 70 0 ? 0 1:1 ?-? al 0 EC/ 9 :I? ? .. 9 ... :g 1-i-1 '-. , ...i ,, a., ca, .r.?' . Ei) .'.1 :L_: u., al C. ,. -0 0 .. ,, - 0 01 .-4., c-: 17u E C) a , .._, :,? - .f ?2. Cl - 0 0 ,-.,i- ? c..? `' a ? E:r ? ?-? 41 1-. 70 Cl 0 43 a) ,,, 0 0 --, he0 i - . Cl - a) 4/ in 76' ill a! X 0 of :..:.: `?-? > 4) 28 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 USSR: Per Capita New Fixed Investment, by RepubEc ( 1955 rti Wen) 1001-05 Kazakh ['Ionia MIIIIIIIMMOIMMINIIIIIIMmonsilesmissated I 206 u rk m en 11111111111111111111111111111111MWMINIIMmomesall 1140 11 STSR 11111=11111111111111111111MMALIMMilikilm 10/3 Lily's NIMMINNIIIIIMININIMINIINEM11030 Armenia mum Now 080 Ukraine NIMPIMIMIllailMmilimmea 062 Lithuania 111111111111111.1111111111111111.11M1040 Azerha shim ammimarammoimr 035 Walk INIIINIMINIIIIIIM11111111111111001 622 Uzbek 705 hirelz 111111MIMIIIIMIIIMINIMMIN 7115 Moldavia 11,111111.1111M1111111M11111 700 tholorilssia 576 Georgia 1111111111 573 1000-70 Kozekh Estonia Turkmen RSFSR Lctviu Armenia Ukraine Lithuania Azerbeydzhan Tadzhik Uzbek Kirgiz Moldavia Belorussia Georoi. 1971-75 Kazakh Estonia lurkmen RUSH Leiria Armenia Ukraine Lithuania Azerbaydzhan Tadzhik Uzbek Kirgiz UMW, Relerusela 1114 061 078 1157 1027 1033 1005 040 r:!.,:f.7.4.:n1177:7_7r-t7=7::.7.7-7: ? J4,;?..,:r.,.?::7,-V,s1,71,=.77: 7.; i',VT-'277.4a,TfOV.7...1:-.7.1,,?!..,'.., ? 1514 1602 1629 1360 1413 1426 1340 1362 1050 2198 2054 1938 1030 1540 1455 1813 1297 1222 - 1417 1348 ' 1533 ' 1592 1205 Figure 10 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 29 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Similarly, Ito IlukV Willi le!.prel 1.0 itlICIn?f!IU11111 .111)(1' 1)14'11 1111111111111111. 1.:1111111:P;k 101114111V; I 1161111 UI l kV.Ige 101 11111111' I() wig) ;de int() 111(. (1,,i( )(IN. I IU'(' I, Ibis policy bas enjoyed only mini?. 101' OW 11:1!il. Iii fall, sultirien1 tegional wage differenlials,v); distlissed lias dairwn labor ink) the sondiein legions. Allbmigh Iltere bas been MIMI' ICI 4.1g1III 11/11 Of OW 111411 (1) W111,4' intliftely Ilial any immediate \VIII 1)11)111011' 111111,4(T Ill 1111(11' to ibell!I !Ind 11111' (1111.1111.: III1' 1110 live years. Since Iliv iirtv live year plait give!. no plospecl of redwing regional income differenlial); by It roiardinaled redisbilmlion of boll) capital and labor, tegional dispatilies in development levels are likely It) persist ?vik a 11111e change during Ilit) new/ plan period. In fact, if industrial glowIli mnsl depend primarily on in- creases in Inch?. p:mlueliyity, the development gal)); may co,..mtie It) increase, tvith die IS developed republics faIIiii ill Further behind the rest of the country. 30 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 APPC.NDIX A PRIMARY DATA USED IN CALCULATING REGIONAL TRENDS IN PER CAPITA NATIONAL INCOME, INDUSTRIAL AND AGRICULTURAL OUTPUT, AND FACTOR PRODUCTWITY Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 31 Table A-I USSR: Indexes of Regional Growth 1960=-100 Northwest ? Center Central Chernozem Volga-Vyatka Volga Vallt4 North Caucasus Urals West Siberia East Siberia Far FAO Estonia. Latvia Lithuania Belorussia Ukraine Moldavia Georgia Armenia Azerbaydzhan Kazakh Kirgiz Uzbek Tad_hi:: Turkmen USSR Mid-Year Population ? National Income h Industrial Output !-gricultural Production d 1965 1969 1965 1969 1965 1969 Total Per Capita Total Per Capita Total Capita 1965 1969 106.0 102.5 Iri 7. 10..i.0 107.5 110.4 103.6 105.0 108.3 111.7 105.3 195.7 106.7 104.9 105.9 111.2 108.5 116.3 117.6 119.0 119.4 120.9 121.9 118.1 107.6 109.21 105.01 101.51 100.31 111.5 117.3 [ 105.1j 105.51 111.21 11S.3j 110.0 110.0 112.e 109.4 109.7 118.4 112.9 130.5 130.0 127.6 134.1 138.0 138.1 132.8 112.1 135 143 141 132 141 140 161 137 148 125 131 150 145 156 131 137 181 191 1S6 223 200 184 212 173 208 152 193 200 172 189 153 183 168 174 16, 199 183 168 179 153 159 117 151 149 125 137 117 163 )161 (161 1.116509 1138 131 163 145 154 148 150 158 174 164 153 177 141 157 141 164 167 150 154 134 149' 182 174 227 213 233 210 203 209 232 222 222 226 273 263 211 261 196 237 178 231 267 186 211 177 205' 167 166 224 219 209 179 193 1988. 209 188 202 205 244 240 192 220 174 182 137 181 199 135 153 133 183 112.7122.4 113.5 123.7 106.6 115.7 124.5 101.1 1912.99 116.1 112.4 108.2 3. 11226.4 6 115.3126.2 135.5 117.7 108.0 108.8 119.1130.4 136.1 119.2 128.5 132.6 115.5 130.6 112491.'5? 133.6 199.4 123.9 11?18 9. .03 139.0 122.9 121.9 144.6 143.9 164.7 136.0 119.6 119.8 147.8 129.4 137.4 156.2 128.9 112 194 139 129 120 104 118 104 106 117 112 111 199 132 115 139 120 92 92 102 110 94 99 118 115 ? Indexes of mid-year population were derived front data in Table A-3. b Indexes of national income were taken from Narodnoye khorya:stvo SSSR v 1969 goda, p. 558. ? In '^..:ef inaustrial output were taken from Nar-dnoye khozysystvo SSSR v 1969 godu, p. 149. 4 of agricultural production and the per capita ruble data (shown in Table A 2) were derived from three-year mo-.-ng averages, representing an Lstimated net value of per capita agricultural production in thc various regions. The 7..1.1ue of agricultural output was derived for each region and for the USSR on the Ws:3 of price (1968 prices) and quantity data for the following 17 agricultural products: grain, potatoes, other vegetables, fruits and berries, cotton, sugar beets, mr.flower seeds, fiber flax, tea, meat, milk, wool, eggs, cattle, hogs, sheep, and goats. An adjustmept was made for grain and potatoes used for feAing purposes. ? Including Kaliningrad Oblast'. The index of industrial prodr.ction for the USSR is based on the sum of the regional values of industrial output in 1965 and 1969. Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Table A-2 USSR: Regional Per Capita Values of National Income, Industrial 01 tput, and Agricultural Production 11 Miles National Income ^ Industrial 1960 11169 Output, 1960 1969 Agrbniltural Proo?o1 ion 1910 1960 Northwest. d 1,167 1,915 124 139 Center 1,185 1,961 176 219 (1entral (1liernozeni.. 311 695 335 465 Volga-NlyatIca 653 1,387 217 280 Volga Valley ..... 765 1,282 645 1,347 274 329 North (aticastis 600 1,074 300 313 1Jrals 930 1,797 203 239 West Siberbt. 621 1,230 288 298 East Siberia 594 1,239 210 223 Far East 737 1,383 99 117 Estimia 899 1,561 971 1,961 378 423 Latvia 940 1,590 933 1,915 34% 386 Lithuania 678 1,350 519 1,264 356 459 Belorussia 517 945 451 1,085 323 425 Ukraine 675 1,131 775 1,492 285 327 Moldavia 521 933 393 867 287 400 Georgia 484 741 522 906 144 174 Armenia 522 831 584 1,060 128 118 Azerbayilzhan 560 655 461 631 123 113 Iazalch 51.1 773 403 730 321 328 Xi rgiz 449 670 369 735 195 215 I.Jzbelc 460 574 354 484 241 226 l'adzhik 380 520 332 537 178 177 Turkmen 509 594 340 453 205 241 USSR 691 1,127 724 1,325 244 280 " Prices in 1958. The per capita data for national income shown here and in Table 1 of the text were derived as follows. First, national income per capita for the USSR was derived for 1965 by moving the 1958 value of national income forward by the appropriate growth indexes and dividing by mid-year 1965 population (Narodnoye khozyitystvo SSSR v 1960 godu, p. 152 and Narodnoye khozyaystvo SSSR v 1969 godu p. 55%). Republican data on national income per capita as a percent of the USSR in 1965 (at 1958 prices) contained in Vedisheliev, op. cit., p. 82, were then applied to the USSR figure. From these results, national income was dlrived for each republic in 1965, and the latter was moved back to 1960 and forward to 1969 by the appropriate growth indexes (Narodnoye khozyaystvo SSSR v 1969 godu, p. 55%). Finally, using mid-year population data (Table A-3), per capita national income was calculated for each republic in 196)) and 1969. b Prices in 1955. The per capita data for industrial output, shown here and in Table 1 of the text, were derived from the gr,)ss value of industrial output for the USSR in 1960 at. 1955 prices (PromyshiennosP SSSR, Moscow, 1964, p. 3);), and the regional percentage shares of this total figure (originally derived in Cook, P. K., "The Administration anti Distribu- tion of Soviet Iadustry," in US Congress, Joint Economic Connnittee, Dimensions of Soviet Econom1c ir'ower, Washington, 1962, pp. 704-732, and later adjusted for boundary changes in Koropeckyj, "In(1ustrial Location Policy," op. cit., pp. 286-287). n Prices in 1968. Data for agricultural production were derived as explained in footnote d for Table A-1. d Including Kaliningrad Oblast'. 34 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Table A-3 USSR: Mid-Year Population" 'Thousand Persons 196() 1965 Northwest ' 11,676 12,371 Center 25,936 26,584 Central Chernozein 7,848 7,968 Volga-Vyatka 8,290 8,290 Volga Valley 16,371 17,592 North Caucasus 12,080 13,340 Urals . . .. ........... 14,498 15,206 West Siberia 11,526 12,108 Elst Siberia 6,966 7,220 Far East 4,907 5,482 Estonia 1,215 1,279 Latvia 2,130 2,252 Lithuania 2,781 2,968 Belorussia 8,184 8,583 Ukraine 42,786 45,308 Moldavia 3.001 3,336 Georgia 4,161 4,515 Armenia 1,860 2,164 Azerbaydzhi .1 3,904 4,591 Kazekh 10,078 11,988 Kirgi,,. 2,185 2,610 Uzbek 8,564 10,350 Tadzhik 2,073 0.,528 Turkmen 1,598 1,888 USSR 214,318 230,521 ? Derived from data reported in Narodnoye khozyaystvo godu, p. 8; v 1964, p. 12; v 1968, P. 12; v 1969, p. 12; a khozyoystvo RSFS11 v 1960 godu, pp. 34-37. "Including Kaliningrad Oblast'. 1969 12,752 27,234 7,964 8.118 18,260 14,172 15,232 12,158 7,412 5,806 1,336 2,344 3,119 8,950 46,944 3,F.552 4,699 2,428 5,076 12,864 2,930 11,816 2,862 2,122 240,347 SSSR v 1960 ncl Narodnoye Table A-4 USSR: Indexes of Growth of Man-Hours Worked per Year in Industry a 1960 = 100 1965 RSFSR 117.5 Estonia 126.5 Latvia 125.9 Lithuania 146.9 Belorussia 137.2 Ukraine 124.3 Moldavia 150.5 Georgia 121.6 Anei -lin 138.4 Azerbaydzhan 127.6 Kazakh 137.5 Kirgiz 138.1 Uzbek 132.3 Tadzhik 140.3 Turkmen 117.7 USSR 121.2 1969 140.0 146.6 153.7 203.1 189.9 155.6 216.0 149.7 195.3 146.4 192.8 192.9 164.2 181.7 140.6 147.9 ' Based on employment data, days worked per man-year, and hours worked per inan-day. These data were extracted from Trud v SSSR, pp. 40-70, 81, and 173, and Narodnoye khozynystvo SSSR v 1960 godu, p. 645. 35 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 36 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Table A-5 USSR: Indexes of Growth f Industrial Fixed Crpital Stock (End of Year)" 1960=100 " 1065 1969 USSR 169 234 IISFS11 167 229 Ukraine 164 225 Beloressia 210 (313) ' hiloldavitt 213 (317) Lithuania 104 (308) Latvia 177 (229) Estonia 185 ( 230) Georgia (143) (195) Azerbaydzhan (168) (242) Armenia 185 (390) Kazakh (182) (260) Uzbek 186 (287) Kirgiz 1C..7 (320) Tadzhik 193 (385) Turkmen (178) (284) ' Sources: USSR: Narodnoye khozyaystvo SSSI1 v 1969 godu, p. 45. RSFSR: Narodnoye khozyaystvo RSFSR v 1969 godu, p. 32. Ukraine: Narodnoye khozynystvo Ukrainskoy SSR v 1969 godu, p. 48. b.lorussia: NarocInoye khozynystvo BSSR v 1968 godu, p. 27. Moldavia: Narodnoye khozynystvo Moldr vskoy SSR v 1968 godu, p. 17; Sovetskaya Moldnviya k 50 letiyu Velikogo Oktynbrya, 1967, P. 23. Lithuania: Ekonomika i katura Litovskoy SSR, 1967, p. 80; 1068, p. 35; 1969, p. 117. Latvia: Ekonomika i kurtura Sovetskoy Latvii, 1966, p. 35; Narodnoye khozyaystvo Sovetskoy Latvii v 1968 godu, p. 46. Estonia: Nnrodnoye khozyaystvo Estonsko: 6SR v 1969 godu, p. 44. Armenia: Isnakyan, C.D., Osnovne fondy promyshlennosti Armyarskoy SSR, 1970, p. 387. Uzbekistan: Narodnoye khozynystvo Uzbekskoy SSR v 1967 godu, p. 26. Kirgizia: Narodnoye khozynystvo Kirgizskoy SSR v 1967 godu, p. 11. Tadzhik: Nnrodnoye khozynystvo Tatlzhikskoy SSR v 1.905 godu, p. 28. b All indexes based on 1955 rubles. All indexes in parentheses are estimated values derived by the perpetuat inventory method as explained in the text of Appendix B. Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 APPENDIX B DISCUSSION OF STATISTICAL AND ANALYTICAL PROCEDURES The Effect of Soviet Statisticrd Biascs on Interregional Comparisons The statistical data on national income and indusHal output employed through- out this paper h.. vi' been drawn exclusively from official Soviet sources and are subject to the biases inherent in Soviet concepts and statistical practices. Although the regional biases do not differ sufficiently to cause a significant change in the relative po0.:on of the regions, some regional differences in statistical bias sti'l exist. These differences and their probable effect On thc results of this paper are discussed below. National Income Data In Soviet practice, national income reflects the total net product of the "pro- ductive!" sectors of the economy. This differs from the Western concept of net national product primarily in the exclusion of the service and government sectors from the Soviet data. The exclusion of services very likely has resulted in the underestimation of regional variations in per capita national income, since the value of services per capita is considerably greater in the European areas of the country than in the Central Asian and Transcaucasian republics." Probably the greatest degree of regional variation in the bias of national irCOMC data is due to the inclusion of turnover tax in the net product of indotry."' This introduces different c:egrees of bias among the regions according to the branch structure of industry ii each region, due to variations in the einount of turnove, tax [..pplicd to differei.' products. For instance, in 1969 the turnover tax com- ponent of wholesale prices averaged 4.2% in the branches of heavy industry and 22.1% in t;:,! branches of the light and food industri...-.."2 Thus, national income could be subject to more ,Ipward bias in regions with a greater share of light and food industries in their industrial structures. Neverthele.-, a comparison of the relative positions of the union republics in terms of )er capita national income in 1965, inclusive and exclusive of turnover tax,"" reveals that regional variations in the bias resulting from inclusion of the turnover tax lo not sig- nificantly change the ranking of the republics (see Table B-1), and have virtually no effect on the findings of this pader, with respect to r!gional variations in the level of per capita national income. For example, the data given for personal services in SSSR v tsifrakli v 1970 godu, p. 227, Indicates that the value of such services per cadita ranges from 11 rubles in Azerbaydzhan and Uzbekistan to 27 rubles in Estonia. " The turnover tax incidence is a result of budget practice rather than production relations, and distribution of net products, by sector, including turnover tax distorts the actual situation. Narodnoye khozvaystvo SSSR v 1969 godu, p. 191. "Per capita national income data exclusiv2 of turnover tqx in 1965 were obtained from Vedislichev, op. cit., p. 82. 37 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Table 11-1 ItSSR: Ranking of Republics, by Per C111)i11 National Income, Inclusive and Exclusive ol Turnover 'Fax /.965 1111.111!thrr (11 .1.11111()%'(.1 It \ IiIii,jv,nor, 1 I ,:iIi ia Est og Hslonia La I v ia ItsP'Sii I I ,ithitallia likraine ISS II ilveragr t !Stilt Average Moldm,fit oldav fit Ilil ,russia Aril vflin ( .1?09,;(11 Kazakh Azerbilydzkoi :eorgia Turkmen Kirgiz Kirgiz Kitzaldi Azerhay(lzhan 1171)1.1; Tirlourn Tadzhik Regional indexes of national income growth are also affected differently, depending On the branch structure of industry in each region. Since the light and food industries generally experience slower growth than heavy industry, regions with a greater share of the former in their industrial structures will naturally display slower growth rates of national income. The turnover tax element in the net product of the light and food industries exaggerates the weight of these branches and therefore causes an understatement of economic growth. Nevertheless, the relative rates 01 industrial growth, by region, should not be affected appreciably by the inclusion of the turnover tax. In& alai Output Data The sector defined as industry includes manufacturing (inclu(ling munitions), mining, e'lectric power generation, lumbering, and fishing. The official production indexes extracted from the statistical handbooks of the USSII and die are indexes of gross indostr:al production ( valovaya prothild promyshlennose ). These indexes represent the sum of the gross production of ill industrial enter- prises, where the gross production of each enterprise is calculate by multiplying the output of each product by its price (exchi(ling turnover taxes) as of a base year. Only those product, produced by an enterprise solely for internal use in the production of its primary products are excluded from the gross production of an enterprise.'1 These indexes are subject to several defects when used to estimate growth. Multiple weights will be assigihd to some industrial activities due to interindustry transactions, and if those activities are growing faster than others that are les heavily weighted, the index will be overestimated. To the extent that this occurs, regions NVith relatively greater concentrations of technically related industries (that is, the Europetu regions) may incur a relatively greater inflationary bias in growth. Another defect is that the indexes are sensitive to changes in the organizational structure of industry. As the degree of specialization increases, " Narodnoye khozyaystvo SSSR v 1967 godu, p. C21. 38 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Illy number of independent esiterprEe:; and accounting units, and with them the gross value of industrial proilliction, x'ill increase. Thus, increases in the gross value of industrial production alter f9() may II) 5(1110 IxtIrIt III' lin' 111111III011 III I hr (1)11111.11N OF national economy and the relarn to die branch system of administration. The greatest inflationary defect of these indexes is probably the million by which II('W 1)11011(.1S 11111ThIllred Plt() the ill(11ACS. New products and modified or improved old ones are assigned prices ostensibly equivalent to prices that would (Aisle(' in the base year. In practice this has usually meant the initial wait cost of production, which is generally %,ery high and includes Thiti prar:Ire, C011pird WWI the tendency Of low products to glOW 11101` rapidly in output than 01(1V1 011eti, may CIIIISC greater inflation of the growth rates of industrial production in I: European regions of the country where conditions are ininv condtic.,;! to the introduction of ne?v products. There is little doubt that some of the regional variations in both the level and growth of per capita industrial output are attributable to (lie problems discussed above. However, the regional variations ill industrial production seen) far too grelit to be explained predominantly by variations in statistical bias. Derivation of Industrial Inputs and Combined Factor Productivity The Input Series Perhaps the most seri( 015 ch,ficiency in the analysis is the lack of adequate regional data on factor inputs other than labor awl capital. There does not ar;war to be any tractable method of imputing inputs from other sectors, par- ticularly agriculture, to the industrial sector on a regional basis. Although a fairly detailed input-m(1,91: table exists for the country as a w hole, there is no reason to expect that the coefficients would realistically represent the techniques of individual regions, and use of these coerficients would probably comimund the existing margin of error. Indexes of labor services The indexes of labor inputs are based on published Soviet data: the average annual number of wage earners and ,ilaried personnel in industry, the average number of days worked per man-year in industry, and the average number of hours worked pVI' man-day. Data on hours worked per man-day 111(1 days worked per man-year are available only for the USSR as a whole and had to be assumed relevant for each region. To the extent that this assumption is violated, the indexes of labor inputs are not fully comparable with those of output. Another problem of matching the coverage of inputs and outputs occurs in the labor series because of the exclusion of industrial workers participating in minor industrial production activities on collective farms whose output is included in the indexes of industrial production. Indexes of industrial gross fixed capital stock Data on the growth of imlustrial gross fixed capital stock, by union republic, were obtained both directly from Soviet statistical sources and ind;rectly from Trud v SSS11, Moscow, 1968, p. 81, 39 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 esliniatcs 1111 nible value of industrial gross fixed eapitpl sto-1; derived by the perpetual inventory melhod.3" Conceptually, those indexes are less desirable as stirrogates tor the growth Of capital services Orni indexes of average annual gross fixed capital stock would be, since the irdexes presented here represent stock as of the end of the year. However, ill Oil IlbSOICV finll data on the annual ruble value of industrial gross fixed capital, by republic, Ii iii \Ville)) ill(IPX('S Of aVrragr Minna, I.VOSS fixed ShWk C0111(1 la, derived, the end-of- year indexes represent a feasible alternative for indicating the relative order of magnitude in the growth of capital services among the union republics. The growth indexes of industrial gross fixed capital stock for 1965 and 1069 (with 1960 as the base year) are presented in Table A-5. Those in parenthe,ws represent values estimated by the perpt tual inventory method. Four basic steps were followed in obtaining the estimated indexes. First, estimates of the ruble value of industrial gross fixer' capital stock at the end nf 19t20 were ch,rived as slg)wn in Table 11-2. For cacti republic except Georgia, An,rbaydzlian, Kazakhstan, and TurklIWIlia this value was moved forward by the reported growth index to the most recent year for which the index was given. The perpetual in nwthod was then appli(,d for the remaining years to obtain a ruble value of industrial gross fixed capital stock at the end of 1969. No growth indexes were available for Georgia, Azerbaydzhan, Kazakhstan, and Turkmenia, so the perpetual inveAtory method had to be used for all years. Because republic data on the changes in unfinished construction were not available, the perpi tual inventory method tends to overstate somewhat the growth of industrial fixed capital stock e1l:.1) year. The stock of unfinished con- struction typically grows faster than total investment. Thus, when the values of industrial fixed cPpital stock were sumrded for all republics at the end of 1965, they totaled 152.24 binion rubles, or 2.24 billion rubles more than the reported total for the USSR. On the assumption that the reported growtl: indexes for the other 11 republics were accurate, this error was attributed selely to the estimating procedure, and the four estimated values for 1965 were adju.:ted proportionally to add to the difference between the sum of the 11 republics for which data were reported and the total for the USSR. Starting from :hose adjusted values, the porpetual inventory method was again applied through 1969. The sum of all republic values at the end of 1069 was 211.33 billion rubles,--_)r 3.33 billion rubles over the reported total for the USSR. Therefore, the esthr ated values were ad- justed as before, md indexes of growth were then calculated from ratios of the adjusted values t ) the 1960 values. In addition to the lack of data on changes in tinfini.iied construction men- tioned above, two other factors associated with the perpetual inventory method may have affected the accuracy of the estimates. Since retirement rates for industrial fixed capital stock, by republic, were not available, the all-union retire- ment rates were applied to the values of industrial gross fixed capital stock of each repnblic. Second, :ndustrial investment data for some republics (and The perpetual inventory method can be expressed as follows: S1?[(S1) . (R,)]+I=Sw where St=Gross fixed capital stock at the beginning of the year t. Rt= Bate of retirements in the year t. Investment during the year t. St.i_i=Gross fixed capital stock at the beginning of the year t+1. 40 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 Approved For Release 2001/09/28 : CIA-RDP85T00875R002000040001-1 T J:1 Jo, H N 0 .0 - r,1 ?-? ri; 01 ? !). O a3 OA A cO .0 I : .0 10 C 1 CO C? I 1':1 cr:1 EL. .0 IL") CO r fli NP Cl CD 00 .0 1- .0 10 .0 40