THE OUTLOOK FOR FREE MARKET GOLD

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP85T00875R001700040008-8
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
C
Document Page Count: 
20
Document Creation Date: 
December 20, 2016
Document Release Date: 
March 28, 2006
Sequence Number: 
8
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
August 1, 1972
Content Type: 
IM
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP85T00875R001700040008-8.pdf864.25 KB
Body: 
Appr O / Jr~~ 0 4/19 :CIA-R IQ~~T RAG 70004000> _ / Confidential v DIRECTORATE OF INTELLIGENCE ~nt~lligence Memorandum International Finance Series The Outlook for Free Market Gold Confidential ER .T.M 72-125 August 1972 Approved For Release 2006/04/19 CIA-RDP85T00875RO01700449 8-> ?116 25X1 gpproved For Release 2006/04/19 :CIA-RDP85T00875R001700040008-8 Approved For Release 2006/04/19 :CIA-RDP85T00875R001700040008-8 Approved For Release.2006/?41.~~~.19~F,3~P_$~~QOI 758001700040008-8 CENTR "~L INTELLIGENCE AGENCY Directorate of Intelligence August 1972 INTELLIGENCE 11~iEMORANDUM THE OUTLOOK FOR FREE MARKET GOLD Summary 1. Free World basic (non-speculative) private demand~l ~ nor gold caught up with the supply of newly mined gold at the official price of $35 an ounce in the mid-1960s, exceeded production by 15% in 1970, and now probably is at least 30% greater. In 1970, basic gold demand totaled about 1,480 metric tons, compared with only about 1,290 tons of new gold production. This 190-ton supply shortfall -plus 245 tons added to official reserves -was met by drawing down most of the remaining portion of the speculative overhang that accu;~nulated during the 1967-68 rush on gold. About 55% of total basic demand occurred in the developed countries -nearly all for commercial purposes. The remainder was added to gold hoards in the less developed countries. 2. The gap between basic demand and supply may temporarily narrow in 1973, but will widen in the following years. Basic demand is expected to grow about 3%-4% annually in quantity terms based on estimated annual growth rates of some 5% for industrially developed countries and about 1% for the less developed countries. The annual average supply of newly mined gold, however, is not likely to expand over the coming years, although supply in 1973 probably will be somewhat higher than 1972's unusually low level. 1. The terms consumption and demand, although similar in connotation, have distinct meanings as applied in this memorandum. In all cases, consumption refers to actual tonnages of gold absorbed. ?emand, however, i~ intended to describe those tonnages of gold that potential gold consumers would wish to acquire if the price of gold remained constant. Note: This memorandum was prepared by the Office of Economic Research. Approved For Release 2006/04/1l~IOlitC=~;t~$'5700875R001700040008-8 Approved For Release 2~A~~~/~I~1~00875R001700040008-8 3. These supply and demand trends are exerting considerable upward p~~ssure on free market prices Moreover, South Africa may withhold sufficient gold from the free market this year to drive the average 1972 price up close to US $60 per troy ounce -excluding speculation -should the Soviet Union continue to sell only moderate amounts of gold on the free market. The price of gold could temporarily fall ;n 1973, speculative considerations permitting, perhaps below $SS an ounce. However, in subsequent years, the free market price probably will increase about 8%-10% a year on the average; about one-half will result from an increase in basic demand against a relatively constant supply and the balance from worldwide inflationary pressures. As a result, the annual average price of gold should be in the range of $60-$65 an ounce in the mid-1970s, even excluding speculative influences. Background 4. For centuries, gold has Y~eer. sought as a store of value against currency debasement, for display because of its aesthetic characteristics, and more recently, also for industrial applications owing to its unique physical properties. From the early 19th century until the mid-1960s, supply far exceeded private demand at a price fixe3 by international agreement - $20.67 per troy ounce prior to 1934 and $35 per troy ounce afterwards. The large residual quantities absorbed by monetary users form the foundation of the gold bullion standard that prevailed from the end of the last century until 1933 anal of the gold exchange standard that was adopted thereaf' ar. S. In the mid-1960s, non-monetary demand overtook supply for the first time at $3S an ounce. This largely reflected a sustained rise in commercial and hoarding demand in the face of constant annual production of newly mined gold, although it was abetted by such transitory events as the virtual suspension of Soviet gold sales after 1965 and speculation (see Table 1). It was a speculative rush from currencies into gold following the devaluation of sterling in November 1967 that provided the final impetus for a fundamental overhaul' of the international gold market in 1l4arch 1968. 6. In less than four months after sterling's devaluation, seven major central banks of the Golc1 PooltZ> lost nearly 2,500 tons of gold (valued 2. The pool's membership included the Central banks of :he United States, the United Kingdom, West Gerr.:eny, the, Netherlands, Belgium, Italy, and Switzerland (France had withdrawn in 1967). A~Sproved For Release 2o96fe4/~sl~-C.~Af-R?~85~FO0875R001700040008-8 Approved For Release 200F~~/19~~LAEND?TIAL 758001700040008-8 Table 1 Gold: Free World Supply and Dema:~d Metric Tons Year New Production Sales by Communist Countries Additions To Monetary Stock Net PrivatE s Purchases _ 1950 19 755 -- 288 . 467 51 19 733 -- 235 498 52 1 7~5 -- 205 550 953 1 755 67 404 418 954 1 795 67 595 267 955 835 67 591 311 1956 1 8'71 133 435 569 957 1 906 231 614 523 958 1 933 196 605 524 959 1 1,000 266 671 595 960 1,049 177 262 964 1961 1 1,080 266 538 gOg 962 19 1,156 178 329 1 005 1 63 1 1,205 489 729 965 964 19 1,250 400 631 1,019 65 1,280 355 196 1,439 1966 1 1,285 -67 -40 1,258 967 1 1,250 -5 -1,404 2,649 968 1 1,262 -29 -623 1,856 969 1,262 -15 97 1,150 1970 1 1,289 -- 245 1,044 971. 1,250 50 -50 1,350 at $2.8 billion). Finally, on 17 March 1968, in conjunction with the' International Monetary Fund (IMF), these central bar..ks inaugurated a two-tier marketing arrangmant whereby monetary ,old transactions at a fixed price were segregated from private gold transactions at prices determined by market forces. As a result of this arrangment, which was supplemented by an agreement between South Africa and the IMF in December 1969, monetary gold stocks were to remain essentiali;~ unchanged and all newly mined gold was to be sold on the free .market `?~ private buyers except on certain occasions.~ I Approved For Release 2006/04/19 :CIA-RDP85T00875R001700040008-8 CONFIDENTIAL 21. Under this assumption for price elasticity, in `.he course of 1971, when the quantity supplied dropped 9% and basis demand at constant prices probably increased by about 3% to 4%, the price would have be?n expected to rise to about an average of $40 per ounce or to $43 an ounce by year's end, excluding speculative factors. Actual prices rose to just under $44 an ounce in December 1971, with the small difference easily attributable to speculative demand. 22. In January-July 1972, the free market price soared above $60 an ounce, at times nearing $70 an ounce as a result of the combined effects of the Smithsonian currency realignment of December 1971, short-curt supply restrictions, and speculative demand. During the first month of the year the price rose sharply to about $48 an ounce. This increase of $4 an ounce largely reflected the devaluation of the dollar in relation to other major currencies. On the average the gold price in terms of these currencies changed little. A drop in South African sales to' the free market has caused a further rise in prices. South Africa sold 20% less to the free market during the first half of 1972 than during the comparable period of 1971 because of lower production and increased national reserves. A considerably improved trade balance and continued capital inflows enabled Pretoria to increase its reserves by $320 million, of which $60 million was in gold. During the second quarter of 1972 the decline in sales was more than one-third, which reduced the total free market gold supply by about 25%. Basic demand continued to grow, and this would have raised the price of gold to around $60 an ounce, in the absence of speculation. In aa:iition, large increases in speculative domand have followed the current rumors that the newly established official gold price - $38 an ounce -may have to be doubled or tripled. Prospects 23. A continued upward trend in prices is inevitable through at least the mid-1970s. We project that price increases tivill average 8%-10% annually through 1971-75 on the asumptions .:f (a) a 3%?4% annual growth of basic demand, (b) a likely 4% rate of worldwide inflation, and (c) relatively constant new supplies except for a ten',porary drop this year. A little more than one-half of this projected price increase will result from increases in basic demand and the rest from inflation. Excluding speculative effects, the average free market gold price will likely be between $60 and $65 an ounce in 1975.~8> Under the same assumptions the basic price wos:id 8. This estimate incorporates the effects of the Smithsonian realignment of exchange rates on gold's dollar price. 12 ~~'01;16 1`~='RUP$" Approved For Release 4 I 5T00875R001700040008-8 . Approved For Release 2006/04/19 :CIA-RDP85T00875R001700040008-8 CON1~ IDENTIAL exceed $90 an ounce by 1980, but for t'tis longe~ period tl~e supl:~ly projection becomes much more uncertain, as there would be time for urger investments in gold mining in response to higher prices to bear fruit. 24. In 1972 the basic price will deviate substantially from the estimated longer run trend bccause we expect South Africa to sell about 300 fewer tons of gold to the free market this year than last. Excluding speculation, this she~~ld yield an average price of about $60 an ounce. Free market price rises in subsequent years should be substantially more gradual as the flow of newly mined gold to the free market from South Africa is restored to more normal levels and with the expected resumption of Soviet gold sales on a larger scale. In fact, the price of gold could temporarily decline over the next year, speculative considerations aside. Demand 2S. Basic demand for gold in non-Communist countries is expected to rise during 1971-75 at an average annual rate of 3% to 4% based on a projected annual growth rate of about S% or slightly more for the advanced countries and only about 1% for developing countries. Because the price elasticity of demand for gold is slightly less than unity, the value of gold demand increases at about the same rate. Consequently real demand should increase from 1,480 tons in 1970 to 1,750 tons in 19'5 if the gold price is constant. With a price elasticity of unity, the value of sales in current prices will increase to the same extent -from $1.7 billion in 1970 to $2.1 billion in 1975. 26. The basic demand for the developed countries is based heavily on past trends that have been modified slightly in some instances to reflect changing conditions (see the Appendix). In accordance with past trends, a projected S% a,~nuzl average increase for national income should yield a 5% to 6% annual growth rate for gold in jewelry. Demand in dentistry, because it is more closely related to population -which is expected to increase 1% annually in the developed countries -than to income, probably will rise at the average annual rate of 3%. Finally, industrial applications of gold, which have risen at least SO% more rapidly than industrial production in the developed countries over the past 1 S years, are likely to be somewhat less sensitive to increases in industrial production in coming years becaus~;: of new techniques which will lower the gold content per unit of output in the electronics industries. Consequently, an expected 6% growth rate of industrial production may yield only an 8% rate of increase for industrial demand for gold. 27. Consumption in less developed countries is more difficult to forecast because it largely depends on prevailing political and military Approved For Release 2006~~~~~=RdP85T`00875R0017000400081~ Approved For Release 200 1~~?,R~.~,5TQ.0875R001700040008-8 conditions. Estimates range frc m a 2% annual decline to about a 2% ann.~al increase, with the most likely increase approximat;ly 1%. Our overall projection is a c~mpesite of ^Aparate estimates for each region. Consumption in the Near East is expected to continue to decline as : apiii economic development in that area provides more attractive forms of investment and as investor sophistication grows. South Asian consumption sh~~uld increase by only 1% to 3% a year as the growth of rural incomes gi;nerated by the "green revolution" of recent years decelerates. Far Eastern a~nsumption, dominated by South Vietnam and Indonesia, is likely 'to be much more volatile. Vietnam's consumption might increase to perhaps 70 tons a year, if a high level of uncertainty continues. On the other hand, should stable conditions be restored to Viet~iam, consumption in 1975 could be on the order of 20 tons - a normal level for a country with its population and level of development. In Indonesia, economic conditions are likel;~ to continue improving, bringing a drop in politically motivated gold purchases. 5'uPP1Y ' 28. World gold production is not likely to expand over the next several years, regardless of free market price behavior. Because a long lead time is necessary to open a new mine -about three years for a deep level shaft -South Africa's output through 1975 will be determined by mines already in operation or under construction. Ry this time, four mines are expected ~,;ii:?er to be opened or substantially expanded, providing additional capacity of about 75 tons. At free market prices substantially above the official price, some older mines scheduled for closure will remain open. But, although gold mining capacity will increase and the lifespan of existing mines will be lengthened, their production during this period will be reduced because the richness of the ores extracted and, consequently, output in terms of metallic content varies inversely with price.~9~ This decline in output from existing mines will approximatelS? offset increased output from new mines. South African production in 1972 is expected to be 8% (about 9. All but one of the seven goldfields are in one geological basin -- the other field is in a subsidiary basin -- that is characterized by the occurrence of gold in thin reefs at extremely deep levels -- down to depths in excess of 10,000 feet. The gold is found in the form of a fine dust intermixed in a conglomerate, and for each metric ton of conglomerate mined an average of about one-third ounce of gold is obtained. Remo gal and processing of the conglomerate is the gold industry's bottleneck. The total volume produced can be varied somewhat, however, by extracting ores with different gold content. The richness of the ores extracted varies inversely with the price of go13. Working a given volume of lower grade ores means that in any one year less gold is produced and profitable reserves are increased. In the long run, therefore, less gold is left in the ground by the time the mine is closed and thus the mine's lifespan is considerably lengthened. 14 CONFLDENT'l.AL Approved For Release 2006/04/19 :CIA-RDP85T00875R001700040008-8 Approved For Release 2006/04/19 :CIA-RDP85T00875R001700040008-8 CONFIDE~T~IAL 75 tons) less than in 1971. Moreover, production from existing mines should continue at that level until the mid-197Gs. 29. The condition of South Africa's balance of payments and the marketing policies of th.e Swiss "Big Three" banks which market most of South Africa's output~l~~ will continue to yfr,;ct supply conditions. South Africa, because of potential balance-of-payments surpluses, may withhold upward of 200 tons of newly mined gold in 1972 and additional amounts in subsequent years to build up its own gold reserves. Pretoria expects a balance-of-rayments surplus of about $500 million in 1972 compared with a $340 million deficit in 1971, mainly as a result of a vastly improved trade balance. 30. Production by other non-C'ommuni ;t countries will probably decline or at best remain constant because a substantial share of this output is a byproduct of other metals production, which is little affected by changing gold prices. Moreover, gold mine operations everywhere are Beverly pressed by rising costs. Although rising receipts have somewhat alleviated th4is squeeze, the basic price trend is probably still tao low to influence production significantly. 31. Finally, it seems likely that the Soviet Union will resume large-scale sales. Planned imports of capital equipment and grain are expected to greatly increase Moscow's hard-currency requirements. With nearly 1,750 tons of gold reserves, Moscow may now be willing to sell enough gold at least to offset the expected decline in non-Communist supplies (150-200 tens annually through the mid-1970s). During the decade, moreover, the potential for Soviet sales will increase. Preliminary estimates suggest that annual production should rise from the 1971 lever ~f about 225 tons to 350-400 tons by the mid-1970s. 32. The gold supply in the late 1970s is less predictable. The problem is not so much a lack of gold deposits but rather whether these deposits can be profitably mined. Although the prospects that prices will increase at least as rapidly as costs could lead to a substantial increase in production, this is by no means certain. An increase in production would have the effect of dampening price increases. Practically all producers outside South 10. The Big Three Swiss banks -- (1) Union Banks of Switzerland, (2) Swiss Banking Corporation, and (3) Swiss Credit Bank -- gained the ability to manipulate the gold market after 1968 when South Africa shifted the bulk of its gold sales from the London market 4o this consortium. Approved For Release 2U6'G/0`41t9i:`Ct# R~~6~F00875R001700040008~ Approved For Release 2006/04/19 :CIA-RDP85T00875R001700040008-8 CONFIDENTIAL Africa depend on government subsidies, and higher prices might result in lower subsidies. Moreover, the South African government largely determines the profitability of .its manes through tax policy, and, if dependence on gold to finance balance-of-payments deficits declines, Pretoria may not encourage an expansion of its gold industry. Implications 33. A price increase on the order of that envisioned through the mid-1970s could threaten an end to the two-tier gold market,, depending on the shape international monetary reform assumes. If Special Drawing Rights, or some other new form of international reserve ass;,t, were to gain sufficient favor among central banks, then part of the nearly 36,000 ions ($44 billion at $38 an ounce) of gold in official coffers could be sold on the free market. Large-scale sales of gold stock, however, would depress the free market price and reduce the advantages of further sales. 34. Conversely, rising prices may increase gold's attractiveness as a reserve asset and encourage same gov~;rnments to purchase free market gold. This would be the most likely outcome in the absence of restored confidence in the international monetary system and the viability of alternative reserve forms. Steadily rising prices could dispel a principal argument against gold as a reserve asset. If the free gold market price rose steadily, a country's gold reserves -far from being sterile assets -would indeed increase in market value. Moreover, a combination of sustained dollar inconvertibility and a rising gold price would tempt some central banks to dispose of excess dollar holdings by using them to purchase free market gold. ~~proved For Release 29~0~1~~[~T00875R001700040008-8 25X1 gpproved For Release 2006/04/19 :CIA-RDP85T00875R001700040008-8 Next 10 Page(s) In Document Exempt Approved For Release 2006/04/19 :CIA-RDP85T00875R001700040008-8