(UNTITLED)

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP85T00310R000200190003-2
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
S
Document Page Count: 
31
Document Creation Date: 
January 12, 2017
Document Release Date: 
September 7, 2010
Sequence Number: 
3
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
October 1, 1984
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP85T00310R000200190003-2.pdf1.45 MB
Body: 
Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Japanese Financial Liberalization: Economic and Political Dimensions EA 84-10190 October 1984 Copy 3 2 6 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Lill cuwilIIC VI v11- Intelligence Political Dimensions Japanese Financial Liberalization: Economic and Northeast Asia Division, OEA are welcome and may be directed to the Chief, Office of East Asian Analysis. Comments and queries This paper was prepared byl Secret EA 84-10190 October 1984 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Secret Overview Information available as of 2 October 1984 was used in this report. Political Dimensions Japanese Financial Liberalization: Economic and investment and economic development. Japanese financial markets have been highly regulated for most of the postwar period, with the government dictating the scope of activities for intermediaries and strongly influencing the cost of credit to borrowers and the extent of capital flows. The tightly controlled financial system was initially designed to ensure that relatively scarce personal savings were channeled to business firms at the lowest possible cost to encourage rapid prices. An increase in personal savings coupled with a decline in the need for investment following the 1973-74 oil crisis destroyed much of the system's rationale and led some Japanese-including the central bank-to press for financial deregulation. The Finance Ministry's response to these initial pressures, however, was narrowly focused and piecemeal. Progress was concentrated in short-term money markets, where interest rates were decontrolled, and in international transactions. As US financial deregula- tion picked up speed in the latter half of the 1970s, many analysts began to focus on the possible economic ramifications of Japan's less ambitious liberalization program. Some charged that Japanese companies benefited handsomely from regulations that kept the country's growing pool of savings at home, keeping interest rates-and thus production costs-low, and thereby permitting Japanese firms to undercut foreign competitors' yen transactions can be conducted freely outside of Japan. The mushrooming of Japan's current account surplus since 1981 has heightened foreign concern over Tokyo's financial regulations. Some US observers argue that these controls have kept the yen from appreciating and hindered the recycling of Japan's huge foreign trade surpluses. Pressure from Washington, which culminated in last spring's bilateral yen- dollar working group meetings, has focused Japanese attention on these problem areas. Tokyo has promised additional movement on financial market liberalization, including the removal of most restrictions on interest rates within two to three years. To promote yen internationalization, the Japanese Government has pledged to create new Euroyen markets, where We believe domestic factors, as well as international pressure, will compel Japanese authorities during the remainder of the decade to accelerate the pace at which they deregulate the financial system although bureaucratic obstacles will continue to block abrupt liberalization: ? The volume of internal government debt that is maturing will jump beginning in 1985, straining the financial system as it now exists and perhaps leading to the removal of remaining interest rate regulations. iii Secret EA 84-10190 October 1984 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T00310R000200190003-2 ? Once begun, liberalization in Japan, as in other countries, feeds upon itself. Losers from past deregulation are already demanding compensa- tion in the form of liberalization in an area of their choice. We believe US observers frequently fail to recognize the full extent of past liberalization. Hence, they tend to overstate the impact removal of remaining financial regulations will have on Japanese competitiveness. We doubt that future reform will do much to narrow Japan's global trade surplus or its surplus with the United States: ? We are skeptical that further financial liberalization will erase the alleged Japanese competitive advantage derived from low interest rates. As a result of the deregulation of money markets in 1978-79 and the lib- eralization of foreign exchange controls in 1980, Japanese real interest rates are now largely in line with those prevailing elsewhere. Moreover, we believe it unlikely that borrowing costs for companies will rise further as decontrol progresses. Future deregulation should heighten competition among Japanese banks and thus restrain them from passing along higher funding costs. Additionally, the nonbank financing options of Japanese corporations will expand. ? We believe analysis forecasting an appreciation of the yen as liberaliza- tion reaches its maximum has merit but should not be pushed too far. Fi- nancial markets are expected to deepen and accommodate a greater volume of transactions as deregulation progresses, making them more attractive to foreign institutional investors. Unless accompanied by a rise in Japanese real interest rates relative to those prevailing elsewhere, however, this development will have only a minor impact on the yen. Given the current freedom of capital flows, real interest rates in Japan do not diverge much from those prevailing elsewhere. ? Although we doubt future financial liberalization will do much to alter corporate financing costs or the value of the yen, we feel reform has many positive aspects. Chief among them is the ongoing expansion of foreign access to yen capital markets. This allows foreigners, including US corporations, to reduce risks by diversifying the currency composition of their borrowings. Although the cost of yen financing in real terms may not be especially low, in nominal terms it is. Low nominal interest rates are expected to continue, as low inflation and high savings seem entrenched in Japan. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T00310R000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T00310R000200190003-2 The Japanese Financial System 1 The Finance Ministry: Wedded to Gradual Liberalization 5 The Domestic Challenges to MOF Conservatism 7 The Dynamics of Liberalization 9 Progress and Remaining Problems 11 Short-Term Money Markets 11 Japanese Securities Markets 13 Capital Flows Into and Out of Japan 15 Implications of Financial Liberalization 19 International Economic Implications of Deregulation 21 Japan: Chronology of Financial Liberalization Measures 25 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T00310R000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 secret Japanese Financial Liberalization: Economic and Political Dimensions After World War II the Japanese Government mold- ed the country's financial system to foster a high level of investment and rapid economic growth. The Minis- try of Finance (MOF) implemented sweeping regula- tions to ensure that personal savings were channeled to business firms at the lowest possible cost. The financial authorities controlled: ? The availability of credit. The government, believ- ing indirect financing from bank loans (rather than direct financing through stocks and bonds) was the most efficient way to fund corporate investment, made sure large banks got sufficient funding. In the immediate postwar period, these institutions were in turn directed to give preference to loan requests from basic industries-such as steel-viewed as key to reconstruction efforts. The highly regulated financial system achieved its primary goal: corporate investment in plant and equipment grew an average 16 percent annually dur- ing the 1960s. The system, nonetheless, had its draw- backs. Banks tended to: ? Form such close ties to individual businesses that they lent excessive amounts to longtime clients, resulting in overinvestment in steel, petrochemicals, and textiles. ? Require borrowers to deposit over 20 percent of their loan proceeds as compensating balances, un- dermining in part the government's efforts to keep interest rates low (see figure 1) The 1973-74 oil shock, which ended double-digit GNP growth in Japan, destroyed much of the ration- ale for the highly regulated system. Many past propo- nents of the status quo became advocates of a more market-oriented system: ? The cost of credit. Financial authorities stabilized nominal interest rates on corporate borrowing from banks, at times at artificially low levels. To reduce bank funding costs, interest rates on deposits were kept below market levels, and households were offered tax incentives to save. ? The scope of operations of financial institutions. As in the United States, banks were prohibited from handling securities transactions. In Japan, more- over, bank functions were specialized. For example, regional banks looked after the financing needs of farms and small businesses, while long-term credit banks and city banks-commercial banks on a national scale-filled the needs of large businesses. ? Capital flows into and out of Japan. Such flows were generally prohibited to prevent balance-of- payments problems. This restriction also provided valuable insulation for the nonmarket aspects of the regulated financial system. ? As growth prospects dimmed for capital-intensive heavy industry, the private sector's need for low-cost investment loans declined, and its need for high- yielding financial assets in which to invest surplus funds became increasingly important. ? The Bank of Japan found its traditional monetary policy tools, which had emphasized bank access to credit, lost much of their relevance as loan demand slackened relative to the supply of savings (see figure 2). The Finance Ministry's response to initial pressures for a freeing of financial controls was narrowly fo- cused and piecemeal: ? Short-term money markets were deregulated in a step-by-step fashion, enabling the Bank of Japan to deemphasize credit availability and instead to influ- ence interest rates in the open market. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Figure 1 Japan: Nominal and Effective Interest Rates, 1970-82' Percent 12 I.. I 1LilI I ..I 4 1970 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 " Quarterly data. b Includes effect of compensating balances. Figure 2 Japan: Household Savings as a Share of Corporate Investment, 1970-81 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 secret ? Because of the concerted go-slow effort, residual restrictions remain, limiting both the access to certain markets and the rate of return available on some assets. Foreign critics claim the remaining regulations cause a variety of economic ills and therefore question the Finance Ministry's gradual approach to liberalization: ? As the size of Japan's current account surplus has grown, so have concerns about how financial regula- tions might retard or distort efforts to invest these surplus funds abroad. ? The existence of controlled interest rates on deposits raises questions about the competitive advantage Japanese firms may enjoy because of lower capital costs. ? Underdeveloped money markets are a legacy of past and present regulations and of the dominance of indirect financing during the high growth era. Crit- ics claim this underdevelopment, which reduces the attractiveness of yen assets to institutions whose large investments could swamp thin markets, is an obstacle to long-term strengthening of the Japanese currency. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Figure 3 Japan: Volume of Secondary Bond Market Transactions, 1970-82 Trillion yen 350 SUU 250 200 150 100 - - - Table I Japan: Ministry of Finance Bureaus Involved in Liberalization Debates Underwriters allowed to resell deficit bonds after holding them 100 clays Underwriters allowed to resell deficit bonds once the bonds have been listed on the stock exchange, usually seven to nine months Underwriters allowed to resell deficit bonds after holding them for one year Budget Yoshihiko Yoshino Prepares and monitors government Committed to reduction of budget deficit. Op- budget posed to measures that would raise government debt service costs, such as market-determined bond yields. Financial Yasutaka Miyamoto Administers central government Would like to improve the attractiveness of gov- borrowing ernment bonds to general public by expanding diversity and responsiveness to market forces. Banking Masateru Yoshida Regulates banks and insurance Has key say in major liberalization moves. Gener- companies ally favors gradual deregulation as long as meas- ures do not harm weaker institutions. Securities Toru Sato Regulates securities industry Probably willing to see liberalization proceed more quickly than Banking Bureau because its constituency-securities industry-likely to fare well in freer environment. International Toyoo Gyoten finance Administers financial dealings with Viewed as most pro-deregulation. Has frequently other countries liberalized Japanese banks' overseas operations when decontrol at home politically unacceptable. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 secret The Finance Ministry: Wedded to Gradual Liberalization The Ministry of Finance, which has primary responsi- bility for shaping the Japanese financial system, is becoming sensitized to foreign concerns about finan- cial regulations. We believe, nonetheless, that domes- tic pressures continue to guide MOF decisions on the pace of financial reform. In the upper echelons of the Ministry, advocates of gradual liberalization predominate, with those favor- ing faster action a vocal minority and with only a few opposed to any further financial changes: ? Press reporting indicates Finance Minister Take- shita favors gradual liberalization; so do the Minis- try's Securities and Banking Bureaus. ? Officials in the International Finance Bureau, the newest and thus the least powerful of the Ministry's in the financial arena ' but has not been able to prevent gradual erosion of its near monopoly on personal savings. The MOF has begun to approve new types of financial assets with rates of return competitive with those offered on postal savings accounts. In January 1980, for example, the Minis- try allowed securities houses to offer mutual funds that invest in medium-term government bonds. ? The Ministry's ability to keep yields on primary issues of government debt low enough to make a dent in government interest expenses has waned in recent years as the secondary bond market has grown (see figure 3). With increasing frequency, the syndicate of banks and securities houses that under- writes over one-third of the government debt has refused to sustain losses by accepting new issues at below-market rates. seven bureaus, are less conservative. MOF support for a go-slow approach stems partly from a fear that deregulation will cause a decline in Ministry prestige and power. Concerns about investor protection reinforce this preference for gradualism. Japan still lacks many of the policing agencies found in the United States, such as the Securities and Exchange Commission In defending the gradual approach, Ministry officials also point to the opposition of the politically powerful postal savings system and to the possibility that liberalization would boost the cost of servicing govern- ment debt. We believe the importance of these obsta- cles has been overstated. During the past five years, the Ministry has endorsed-or at least acquiesced in-changes that have eroded some of the traditional fundraising advantages of the postal savings system and the central government: ? The postal savings system has sufficient political backing in the Liberal Democratic Party (LDP) to stall attempts to abruptly end its privileged position We believe the most important source of Ministry conservatism is its close ties to the institutions it regulates: ? Frequent administrative contact has cemented these ties. Employees from major banks and securities houses, moreover, often serve rotational assignments at the Ministry, and retired Ministry officials fre- quently become executives at private banks. ? When combined with the MOF's internal division of responsibilities, these ties have created powerful advocates for the protection of both weak and strong institutions (see table 1). Banking Bureau loyalties, for example, are torn between institutions that are likely to fare well in a more competitive environ- ment-such as the city banks-and those that probably would not-such as mutual savings and loan banks, which are already suffering from a secular decline. ' The Ministry of Posts and Telecommunications has not made post offices curtail abuses of tax-free personal savings accounts, whereas 25X1 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Figure 4 Japan: Government Bond Redemptions, 1972-96 Trillion yen 25 1972 75 '' Assumes budget deficit will he reduced I trillion run annually beginning in AF Y 1986. Also assumes 6.6-percent yields on government bonds. Figure 5 Japan: Interest Rate Structure Interest arbitrage Linked by regulators Rigid margins CD and gettsalsi rates Long-term Average interest rate prime rate /on bank loans I~ e s %%. ft.. Official discount rate (5.0 percent since October 1983) Government bond Expected dividend yields in secondary rates on 5-year loan market trusts and bank debentures Coupon rates on l0-year +0.9 government bonds Short-term Savings deposit prime rate rates Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 secret The Domestic Challenges to MOF Conservatism Although few in Japan question the wisdom of phased deregulation, criticism of the Finance Ministry's slow pace of reform is growing. Some of the opposition has been relatively easy to defuse-such as that originat- ing in the press-but economic pressures for change are building, making it increasingly difficult for the Ministry to drag its heels on deregulation. The US-Japanese yen-dollar talks in the first half of 1984 ignited a flurry of press comment in Tokyo on liberalization issues, much of it critical of the Minis- try's go-slow strategy: ? After the April meeting of the bilateral working group, an editorial in the respected Asahi claimed that, in setting the time frame for liberalization, the Finance Ministry was placing too much emphasis on protecting banks and too little on the needs of business firms and the general public. ? We believe the Finance Ministry, as the most influential of all ministries in Japan, has sufficient clout to slough off such press criticism Strong pressure for speedier liberalization from Prime Minister Nakasone and other high-ranking LDP poli- ticians has not materialized: ? Although Nakasone cajoled the Ministry into ensur- ing progress during the yen-dollar talks, we doubt he will force the MOF to abandon its gradualism. ? Political leaders in Japan have willingly handed over responsibility for recommending deregulation strat- egy and timing to MOF advisory panels. ? If financial issues become more politically charged, we believe reform is as likely to slow as to acceler- ate. The LDP has close ties to financial institutions that cater to farmers and small businessmen; these institutions are expected to fare poorly in a market- As in the past, the Ministry of Finance has only limited latitude to ignore economic forces pushing for deregulation: ? Massive 10-year government debt issues, made fol- lowing the first oil crisis to cover revenue shortfalls and to stimulate the economy, begin maturing in fiscal year 1985 2 (see figure 4). If refinancing of these bonds is to proceed smoothly, the government must introduce new flexibility into funding methods and issue terms. ? If interest-rate ceilings on deposits are not lifted soon, the funding capacity of banks may be threat- ened. As short-term instruments with yields freely determined in the secondary market, government securities approaching maturity will be attractive alternatives to time deposits in banks. ? Wage gains have been moderate in recent years, increasing the importance of interest as a compo- nent of personal income. We expect this trend to lead individuals to demand better access to market- rate investments, especially if the government cur- tails abuses of tax-exempt small savings accounts. Members of the financial community are also chal- lenging the Ministry's slow pace of reform. According to the press, most financiers are convinced that sweep- ing liberalization is inevitable, if not imminent. To prepare for the deregulated environment of the future, bankers and brokers are urging that the Ministry permit them to expand the range of services and market-rate instruments they offer: ? In May, for example, mutual savings and loan banks requested MOF permission to become regular commercial banks. As savings and loan banks, only 20 percent of their loans can go to big companies. oriented financial system. 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Table 2 Japan: Domestic Funding and Clientele of Financial Institutions Individual and corporate de- Large businesses. Individuals get Highly leveraged and funding base posits, with maximum ma- about 10 percent of loans. narrowing. Underwriting of govern- turity of two years. Money ment debt squeezing profitability. markets. Loan trust certificates, with Historically heavy industry, Future rosy if they, along with life two- and five-year maturi- but more emphasis on service in- insurance companies, can retain exclu- ties. dustry. sive rights to manage pension funds. Long-term credit banks Five-year bank debentures. Capital-intensive industry. Growth prospects have dimmed as cor- Deposits from corporate cli- porate investment needs have fallen. ents and government. Regional financial institutions Deposits of up to three Cash-short city banks. Small and Ample funding but poor growth years' maturity. medium-size businesses. prospects. Securities houses Brokerage fees chief source Industry. Good growth prospects, but many of income. smaller firms troubled. Insurance companies Sales of insurance. Industry, concentrating on long- Aging of population will improve term, fixed-rate loans. growth prospects. a Approximately 80 percent of bank funding comes from deposits whose interest rates are regulated. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Secret The strength of the challenge to the existing Japanese financial system varies by issue. Like the various bureaus in the MOF, specific financial institutions may support liberalization in one area only to oppose it in another. Differences in funding bases and clien- tele account for this inconsistency (see table 2). For example, city banks would like to expand their fund- raising options, specificially by gaining permission to issue five-year bank debentures. They oppose t'he introduction of commercial paper, however, fearing it would allow securities companies to lure away their loan customers. Intraministerial and intraindustry differences fre- quently immobilize the policymaking process. When severe financial strains develop within the economy, however, the importance of these differences is re- duced, allowing liberalization to proceed: ? Rising interest rates tend to highlight strains within the financial system and to jar loose the policymak- ing process, permitting partial liberalization to occur. Once begun, liberalization in Japan, as in other countries, has fed upon itself. Losers from deregula- tion in one area have sought compensation in the form of liberalization in another area. In the United States, for instance, when the advent of money market funds threatened the funding base of savings and loan institutions, savings and loan groups lobbied for the removal of interest-rate ceilings on savings accounts. competitive rates. In October 1983 city banks got into the act by offering new high-yielding instruments, which combined a 10-year government bond fund with a 10-year time deposit. This natural unraveling process helps explain why the pace of financial liberalization in Japan is accelerat- ing despite bureaucratic obstacles: ? Feedback from past deregulation is creating pres- sure for further reform. Furthermore, the expanded freedom the MOF has given Japanese financial institutions in international dealings in recent years is now generating pressure for similar leeway at home. ? We believe the method in which the regulated system unravels will be shaped by the vested inter- ests of bureaucrats and politicians. Feedback from past liberalization will be allowed to proceed unhin- dered in areas-such as deregulation of interest rates on large deposits-that do not harm key LDP or MOF constituencies. On the other hand, we believe fundamental reform of the corporate bond market-which could lead to a large-scale shift of business from banks to securities houses-will be slow in coming. ? The MOF probably will be allowed to pursue phased deregulation in the future, but the pace at which liberalization measures are introduced no doubt will be stepped up. In Japan the events following the advent of medium- term government investment (chukoku) funds in 1980 show a similar pattern of liberalization begetting further liberalization. These chukoku funds, intro- duced to relieve some of the burden placed on finan- cial institutions underwriting government debt issues, became the highest yielding assets within reach of individual investors. The fundraising capacity of the leading securities firms, with exclusive right to handle these funds, increased as a result of their attractive- ness. On the other hand, the funding base of other syndicate members declined. To redress this situation, trust banks and long-term credit banks obtained MOF permission in 1981 to offer accounts with Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85TOO31OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Figure 6 Selected OECD Countries: Capital and Money Market Balances as a Share of GNP, Yearend 1983 Japan West Germany United United States Kingdom Table 3 Japan: Money Market Instruments Instrument Maturity Minimum Denomi- nation (million yen) Balance (as of 30 April 1984) (trillion yen) Gensaki One to 364 days 100 Certificate of deposit Three to six months 300 Half day to one month 1, by custom 5.1 One to four months (latter by custom) 10 Short-term government securities a Usually 60 days 1 a Includes treasury bills, food bills, and foreign exchange bills. Most bills are held by the Bank of Japan and various government trusts. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 ~.~t Liberalization issues vary from one type of financial market in Japan to another, as do the prospects for significant deregulation in the near future Short-term money markets in Japan, as elsewhere, allow corporations and financial institutions to dispose of-or acquire-temporary liquidity to adjust for seasonal and geographic funding needs. Instruments with competitive rates of return must be offered in a wide variety of maturities and denominations to meet participants' differing needs (see table 3). By defini- tion, money markets only handle assets with maturi- ties of less than one year. As the focus of the government's first efforts to deregulate interest rates, Japanese short-term credit markets generally offer competitive yields: ? Until the late 1970s only yields in the gensaki market-where long-term bonds with attached re- purchase agreements are traded-were freely deter- mined. Gensaki yields are still considered the most representative short-term rates in Japan. ? Rates in the call and bill discount markets, where Japanese banks receive and extend each other short- term financing, were deregulated step by step from 1977 through 1979. Central bank open-market op- erations, however, continue to influence rates avail- able in these markets. Although interest rates move flexibly in existing money markets, problems regarding terms of issue and access remain: ? Only financial institutions are allowed to participate in call and bill discount markets. Direct deals by firms and individuals would increase the market competitiveness. ? Certificates of deposit (CDs) are not considered negotiable securities in Japan, and a secondary market was not permitted to develop until April 1982. ? We believe the lack of a viable market in short-term government debt instruments (in particular, trea- sury bills) is the most serious shortcoming. Unlike their US counterparts, Japanese treasury bills are sold only for stopgap funding. The Finance Minis- try, moreover, fixes yields on these securities below market levels. The Bank of Japan thus incurs a loss when it sells them to call market brokers. ? Business firms in Japan are not permitted to issue commercial paper. As short-term unsecured promis- sory notes, commercial paper is considered incom- patible with traditional Japanese reliance on collat- eralized financing. ? Japan also lacks yen-denominated bankers accept- ances, which are negotiable instruments involving bank drafts to pay trade-related financing at matu- rity. However, Japan's bill discount market is a close substitute, with tacit bank guarantees on payment replacing the formal ones involved in bank- er acceptances. We believe the prospects for filling the gaps in Japan's money markets are good: ? In the final report of the US-Japanese yen-dollar working group in mid-1984, the MOF pledged to inaugurate a yen-denominated bankers acceptance market by 1985. Although many Japanese were initially skeptical that the new market would prove an attractive way to finance foreign trade, by early October almost all financiers there were enthusias- tic about its potential, according to US Embassy reporting. ? To enhance monetary policy effectiveness, the cen- tral bank is pushing for a US-style treasury bill market where securities can be freely traded. The Finance Ministry is cool to the idea, claiming the present system is more appropriate. As soaring refinancing needs force the government to diversify its fundraising methods, many Japanese believe 25X1 MOF opposition will subside 25X1 The major defect of Japanese money markets, accord- ing to most experts, is the narrow range of instru- ments available, which has kept the market small by international standards (see figure 6): Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Figure 7 Selected OECD Countries: Share of Funds That Nonfinancial Sectors Raise Directly in Capital Markets Percent 55 Japan United States Figure 8 Japan: Comparison of Government Bond Yields in Primary and Secondary Markets, 1973-84a Percentage points 2.0 I-J -1.0 1973 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 Yields on secondary market of bonds with longest maturity minus yields on new 10-year bond issues. Quarterly data. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 secret The government's postwar decision to encourage firms to rely on indirect financing dealt Japanese bond and equity markets a heavy blow. Leery of antagonizing their bankers, companies shied away from investigat- ing nonbank funding sources. As economic momen- tum slowed in the mid-1970s, the power balance between banks and companies became more equal. Firms felt freer to explore direct financing options namely, stock and bond issues. What potential borrowers in Japan's equity and cor- porate bond market found in the mid-1970s, however, was not particularly appealing (see figure 7): ? Industrial bonds had to be secured by collateral, an especially onerous requirement for leasing and trad- ing companies that possessed only limited amounts of land, factories, and machinery. Japanese compa- nies that floated unsecured bonds overseas, more- over, had difficulty issuing secured bonds domesti- cally without violating provisions of agreements with overseas trustee companies. ? The tradition of giving existing stockholders the right to buy new issues at par value raised the cost of raising funds via equity markets for established companies. For investors, flaws in Japanese securities markets were equally obvious: ? Yields on primary issues of bonds, especially gov- ernment ones, frequently carried below-market cou- pon rates. ? Primary and secondary bond markets were small until the mid-1970s, when the government began using deficit financing. As a result, investors' choices were limited. ? Over two-thirds of the stock listed on the Tokyo Stock Exchange were and still are held by institu- tional investors, including companies in industrial groups such as Mitsui; these stocks were rarely traded. The shares held elsewhere were viewed as fair game for speculators, and price movements were quite volatile, discouraging individuals from entering the market. In the past decade, some of these defects have been rectified: ? As indicated earlier, the underwriting syndicate for central government bonds is forcing the Finance Ministry to set yields on new issues close to those prevailing on the secondary market (see figure 8). This development has ripple effects throughout the financial system, as regulators tend to link interest rates. ? In 1979 Sears Roebuck became the first private company to issue totally unsecured bonds in Japan. The eligibility requirements drafted at that time were so stiff, however, that only I 1 Japanese compa- nies qualified. ? In FY 1980 par issues accounted for only 8 percent of the new domestic equity issues. We believe the power balance between banks and securities companies will determine if remaining defi- ciencies-particularly those in the corporate bond market-are corrected: ? Banks, especially long-term credit banks, oppose further erosion of the principle of collateralization. Eligibility requirements for unsecured corporate bond issues have been relaxed twice in the 1980s, but banks have used their clout to ensure conces- sions were minor. ? Securities houses are growing faster than other types of financial institutions in Japan. We believe at least a decade will pass, however, before this trend erodes the banks' political and economic supremacy. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Figure 9 Japan: International Capital Flows, 1972-83 Figure 10 Japan: Yen Bond Issues by Nonresidents, 1970-83a Billion veil 1,000 400 200 800 600 " 1970 71 72 73" 74b 75" 76 77 78 79" 80' 81 82 83 Includes private placements as well as public offerings. b Years when Japan's current account was in deficit. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 secret Capital Flows Into and Out of Japan In its 1949 foreign exchange law, Japan forbade all capital transactions between residents and foreigners without Cabinet approval. The prohibition on capital flows was intended to help control balance-of-pay- ments problems but also provided valuable insulation for the highly regulated financial system. As the economy matured and other industrialized nations began to open their capital markets, Tokyo gradually softened this stricture: ? As a condition for entry into the OECD in 1964, Japan removed bars that had limited the free exchange of yen for other currencies and gold. ? In the 1970s, balance-of-payments considerations periodically inspired the Finance Ministry to liber- alize foreign exchange transactions. For example, to attract overseas funds to cover a $9 billion current account deficit, Tokyo in 1979 allowed nonresidents to participate in the gensaki market and in the newly created CD market. In 1980 Tokyo formalized its more progressive atti- tude toward capital movements by enacting a new foreign exchange law. It made restrictions on external transactions the exception rather than the rule. As a result, capital flows in both directions mounted rapid- ly (see figure 9): ? Capital inflows quadrupled and outflows doubled from 1979 to 1983. Because outflows started from a much larger base, however, they still exceeded inflows by $18 billion last year. ? Much of the increase in outflows reflects the desire of institutional investors in Japan to reduce risks by diversifying the currency denomination of their portfolios. ? The growth in the external bond issues of Japanese firms, predominantly in the form of low-interest Swiss franc paper, accounts for much of the rise in inflows. Even after the promulgation of the 1980 law, the Ministry of Finance continued to restrain many types of capital flows through administrative guidance: ? During April-September 1983 the MOF set a $11 billion cap on medium- and long-term lending by private Japanese banks to overseas borrowers. We believe this inhibited the efficiency with which the Japanese current account surplus was recycled. ? Japan's current account balance weighs heavily in MOF decisions on the permissible volume of yen- denominated bond issues by foreigners (see figure 10). Although freedom of capital movements is incom- plete, we believe the liberalization that has taken place has effectively integrated Japanese money mar- kets with those abroad. Tokyo, moreover, has shown a willingness to remove some of the remaining barriers to the free flow of funds into and out of Japan: ? Euroyen and gensaki interest rates usually move in tandem, indicative of the integration that now exists. ? In March 1984, the Finance Ministry ended its case-by-case screening of banks' offshore medium- and long-term yen loans. Some Japanese journalists doubt this will boost offshore yen lending because they consider the new requirements that the MOF imposed at that time as equally restrictive; these requirements were designed to prevent banks from extending excessive amounts to troubled LDC debt- ors. In our view, this is a valid concern, but the ease with which Indonesia and New Zealand borrowed record sums of yen over the summer provides some evidence of a genuine liberalization. ? In our judgment, the principle of free capital flows is well enough entrenched that backsliding will be minimal when Japan encounters balance-of-pay- 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Figure 11 Use of Mark, Pound, and Yen as Official Foreign Exchange Reserves, 1975-82 Table 4 Situation in Euroyen Markets Euroyen bond issues by nonresi- Only supranational agencies or Aaa-rated dents of Japan governments that have previously floated three samurai bonds are eligible to float bonds. were given permission to issue convertible Euroyen bonds; 30 became eligible to issue straight Euroyen bonds. Euroyen certificates of deposit Currently prohibited because financial au- (CDs) thorities fear Euroyen CDs will compete head-on with domestic CDs in Japan and proceeds might be used to fund long-term Euroyen lending. Short-term Euroyen lending to nonresidents liberalized in June 1983 and to residents in June 1984. Medium- and long-term lending still prohibited. The MOF is expected to allow governments with lower credit ratings and fewer samurai issues to tap the Euroyen bond market later this year. Foreign companies with similar qualifications-a pool of four at present- are also likely to gain access. Future relaxation probably will be tied to improve- ments in the domestic corporate bond market, such as an easing of heavy collateral requirements and enhanced rewards for being a good credit risk. This prohibition is slated to be lifted by I December 1984. Unlike domestic CDs, ceilings on issues will not be imposed. Proceeds, however, will not be allowed to flow back into Japan. This restriction is designed to minimize negative fallout on the domes- tic market. The Ministry of Finance is unlikely to grant banks permission to make medium- and long-term Euroyen loans this year, according to press reports. MOF officials fear decontrol would undermine the regulat- ed interest-rate system in Japan. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 secret As Tokyo has become more openminded about capital flows, prospects for yen internationalization have brightened. Even so, the potential for wide interna- tional use of the yen as a currency for trade transac- tions and as a medium for investment remains largely unrealized. Some US observers view internationaliza- tion as key to sustained strengthening of the yen. The share of Japanese trade denominated in yen is rising, although still below the corresponding ratio in other industrial powers: ? Currently 40 percent of Japanese exports are in- voiced in yen, up from 33 percent in 1981; this is less than half as high as the share of West German exports priced in marks. The import side of the picture is even more striking: only 3 percent of Japanese imports are yen denominated. ? Financial analysts frequently cite the lack of yen- denominated bankers' acceptances as the cause of the low level of trade conducted in yen. In our view, this argument should not be pushed too far given the existence of a close substitute, namely, the bill discount market. ? We believe the biggest obstacle to enlarging the volume of yen-based trade is the international tradi- tion of pricing raw materials in dollars. These items accounted for over two-thirds of Japanese imports in 1983. In our opinion, use of yen as a reserve currency is also limited, reflecting in part past Japanese attempts to discourage this form of internationalization: ? Tokyo reversed that policy in 1978, however, and in March 1980 exempted yen deposits of foreign gov- ernments from interest-rate ceilings. The Japanese hoped that, by making such deposits more attrac- tive, they would be able to attract the funds of oil exporters to cover the $11 billion current account deficit (see figure 11). We believe relaxation of capital controls has had its most profound effect on the yen's use as an investment medium: ? In 1983 the yen replaced the British pound as the second most popular currency in international lend- ing. The yen's 6-percent share paled, however, next to the dollar's 74-percent share. Five percent of foreign bond and Eurobond issues were denominat- ed in yen last year, putting the yen in fourth place- behind the dollar, the deutsche mark, and the pound. Further expansion of the yen's role in international finance hinges partly on the creation of free Euroyen markets, where yen transactions can be conducted outside of Japan. Financial authorities in Tokyo so far have been reluctant to allow these markets to develop. They fear uncontrolled growth of Euroyen markets may erode monetary policy control and lead to unreg- ulated risk taking by banks: ? Despite their apprehension, Japanese officials agreed at the yen-dollar talks to improve residents' and nonresidents' access to Euroyen markets (see table 4). In July the Japanese press speculated that some of these measures would be implemented ahead of schedule to reduce economic tensions with West European countries and the United States. ? The rules governing Euroyen markets have been carefully crafted, however, to limit the markets' attractiveness. For example, Tokyo will not let proceeds from Euroyen CD issues flow back into Japan. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85TOO31OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Figure 12 Selected OECD Countries: Short-Term Interest Rates, 1975-84a , L Iw, ii L_L_,_i i_wi_I Li Figure 13 Selected OECD Countries: Short-Term Interest Rates Adjusted for Inflation, 1975-83a -4 6 I i L I l L -t iL w LPL I IL-w-LI I 1975 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 Quarterly data. Adjusted using a nine-month moving average of the consumer price index. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85TOO31OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Secret Analysts differ over how much future deregulation will impinge on Japanese interest rates and competitiveness: ? We disagree with this scenario, however, because most of the postulated increase in credit demand involves the refinancing of government debt that begins to mature next year. Tokyo's requirements for new money are actually declining. ? Some observers believe existing regulations insulate the Japanese financial system from international economic forces, permitting authorities to keep in- terest rates at artificially low levels. These analysts believe future deregulation will wipe out this artifi- ciality, reducing Japanese competitiveness in the process. ? In our view, these arguments underestimate the effectiveness of past liberalization measures, partic- ularly the deregulation of money market interest rates and the freeing of capital flows, at integrating Japanese financial markets with those abroad. Yen interest rates now generally move in tandem with those in other countries, especially during periods when Tokyo is trying to stabilize the value of the yen see figures 12 and 13). We believe future increases in arbitrage involving Japan will be mar- ginal compared with that which has already taken place. Others point to increased funding costs for banks, resulting from deregulation of deposit rates, as anoth- er potential route to higher Japanese interest rates: ? Although we believe this argument has some merit, we also feel banks will be unable to pass along all their higher funding costs to corporate borrowers as deregulation spurs financial competition. Bank prof- itability is as likely to decline as corporate borrow- ing costs are to rise. Data Resources, Incorporated (DRI) analysts contend a credit crunch is likely to strike Japan in 1985, magnifying the significance of any liberalization- induced rise in interest rates: ? These analysts see the combination of freer capital flows and a projected doubling of government bond issues beginning next year as leading to a 3-percent- age-point rise in government yields between 1984 and 1987. Even if liberalization raises the cost of capital to some extent, we believe this development will alter Japa- 25X1 nese competitiveness only slightly: ? As the share of Japanese corporate investment financed out of retained earnings has grown from 63 percent in 1968-73 to 75 percent in 1980-83, the potential competitive advantage conferred by low nominal interest rates has declined. Moreover, in real terms, interest rates in Japan are at unprece- dentedly high levels and yet export competitiveness remains strong. ? The yen's current weakness against the dollar 3 along with the country's skilled and diligent labor force are, in our view, more important than capital costs in explaining Japanese export competitiveness. ? If the analysts who believe a major interest-rate increase is in the offing are correct, the loss of Japanese export competitiveness would result main- ly from the associated upward pressure on the value of the yen rather than from the increased financing costs of firms. The pressure on the currency, howev- er, would have to be great enough to counteract the short-run negative effects past liberalization is ex- erting on the yen; these effects are described in the next section. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Figure 14 Japan: Medium- and Long-Term Loan Commitments to Offshore Borrowers, 1982' International organizations Indonesia)- Asia----- Latin America - a Yen and foreign currency lending by private financial institutions totaled $22.4 billion. Figure 15 Japan: Basic Balance and the Exchange Rate, 1972-83 Billion US $ 15 1972 Yen/dollar exchange rate Yuen appreciating 200 re atinn to the dollar 1"cn depreciating 305 relative to tilt dollar Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T00310R000200190003-2 secret International Economic Implications of Deregulation Financial liberalization in Japan has proved a boon to some foreigners and a headache to others. On the positive side, foreign access to Japanese capital mar- kets-and thus to plentiful savings-has improved during the last five years, at least for many official borrowers: ? Eligibility requirements for foreign yen bond issues and loans have been eased repeatedly since 1981, when Japan's current account surplus began to mushroom. ? Yen markets in Japan cater primarily to sovereign borrowers. Not all foreign governments, however, enjoy equal access. We believe MOF decisions on which countries get priority in tapping yen markets are shaped largely by foreign policy concerns. At present, international organizations and ASEAN and West European countries appear the most welcome; troubled LDC debtors and Soviet Bloc countries appear the least welcome (see figure 14). ? Interest-rate differentials between yen and dollar assets play a much more important role in the size of capital flows, in our view, than specific liberaliza- tion measures do. These differentials stem primarily from dissimilarities between Japanese and US mac- roeconomic policy mixes and from dissimilarities in savings rates. Additionally, swings in the current account balance can swamp changes in the capital account balance. ? Over the longer term, liberalization is likely to help deepen Japanese financial markets; this should make them more attractive to foreign institutional investors, boost capital inflows, and perhaps raise the value of the yen. Continued liberalization of Japanese markets poses a potential challenge for Asian countries now serving as international financial centers, namely, Singapore and Hong Kong. Japan, with its high-savings rate and large economy, is in many ways a natural location for an international financial center: ? Sovereign borrowers also obtain a large share of the syndicated offshore foreign currency lending done by the Japanese. The downward pressure long-term outflows put on the yen is the negative side of the enhanced openness of the Japanese financial system. We do not, however, see a 1-to-1 correlation between liberalization and yen depreciation: ? Admittedly, annual changes in Japan's basic bal- ance-the sum of the current account balance and the long-term capital account balance-and the yen-dollar exchange rate appear connected (see fig- ure 15). ? We believe that much of the recent outflow facili- tated by liberalization-and traceable to Japanese institutional investors-is a transitory phenomenon. Once the desired currency diversification of portfo- lios is attained, outflows should abate, reducing the downward pressure on the yen. ? Although Japan has natural advantages, the limited English-speaking skills of its middle managers is a 25X1 distinct handicap. ? Tokyo has not yet embraced the idea of becoming an international financial center, although Prime Minister Nakasone has voiced support for such a move. Concerns about the potentially harmful ef- fects on neighboring financial centers partly explain the lack of enthusiasm among many government officials. Fears about the impact on domestic mone- tary policy formulation also play a role. ? Some Western analysts argue that the development of a successful Tokyo financial center would create more financial business for all of Asia rather than merely divert existing business to Japan. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T00310R000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Figure 16 Japan: Corporate Financial Assets, 1975 and 1982 Assets with regulated interest rates Table 5 Japan: Banks Among Top 50 Syndicated Loan Managers, Globally Assets with regulated interest rates Bank of Tokyo 14 Bank of Tokyo 4 Bank of Tokyo 6 Industrial Bank of Japan 19 Industrial Bank of Japan 13 Industrial Bank of Japan 12 Sumitomo Bank a 27 Fuji a 16 Fuji a 14 Fuji a 34 Sumitomo Bank a 20 Mitsubishi Bank a 17 Long-Term Credit Bank 39 Dai-ichi Kangyo a 25 Long-Term Credit Bank 24 Sanwa a 45 Mitsubishi Bank a 26 Sumitomo Bank a 25 Dai-ichi Kangyo a 49 Long-Term Credit Bank 27 Dai-ichi Kangyo a 26 Nippon Credit Bank 45 Nippon Credit Bank 37 Sumitomo Trust 40 Mitsubishi Trust 47 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Appendix Japan: Chronology of Financial Liberalization Measures January December April Underwriters allowed to sell government bonds after one year. Eurobond flotation by Japanese companies decontrolled. Medium-term government bonds issued on auction basis. Increased link between interest rates in primary and secondary markets. Added to pressures on banks to look overseas for growth. Heightened market influence on terms of bond issues. Nonresidents allowed to participate in gensaki Effectively linked Japanese money market with market. foreign money markets. Rates on two-month bills allowed to move freely. Investment trust funds in medium-term gov- ernment bonds introduced. New Foreign Exchange and Trade Control Law implemented. Tokyo Stock Exchange amends charter to permit foreign security companies to become members. Annual queuing system for issuance of yen bonds by foreigners replaced by quarterly system. Banks allowed to sell newly issued long-term government bonds to public. Minimum-size CD reduced to 300 million yen. Spurred growth of underdeveloped money market. Ostensibly completed deregulation of money market. Formalized new policy of permitting international capital flows. Of limited practical significance since there are only 83 seats on exchange. Embodied principle that foreign banks are to be accorded like treatment with domestic banks. Facilitated recycling of growing current account surpluses. Heightened link between primary and secondary government bond markets. Boosted growth potential of money market by putting CDs within reach of more investors. Select Japanese companies allowed to issue Euroyen bonds. Ended case-by-case screening of medium- and long-term yen lending abroad. Select banks allowed to deal in government bonds with maturity of less than two years. Ceiling for conversion of foreign currency into yen by banks abolished. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Expected to increase volume of such loans, even though prudential net worth ratios imposed. Further blurred lines between securities and banking activities. Simplified operations and widened financial base of banks, especially foreign ones. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Secret The Political Dimensions of Liberalization We believe the political fallout from the liberalization of Japanese financial controls is likely to be as important as the economic fallout. Existing power relationships between the government and financial institutions, between financial and nonfinancial insti- tutions, and among financial institutions are all likely to change. Although we expect the Finance Ministry to retain greater control of financial transactions than its coun- terparts in other countries-if only by monitoring activities closely-the MOF's leverage over financial institutions will decline: ? Financial institutions still have an incentive to heed Ministry guidance, namely, to ensure themselves a voice in decisions concerning specific liberalization measures. ? As liberalization approaches its maximum level, however, we believe the Finance Ministry will find itself in the same position with respect to relatively sound financial institutions that the Ministry of International Trade and Industry finds itself in with respect to healthy nonfinancial corporations. Minis- try advice will be respected only when it appeals to the self-interest of the institutions. The supremacy of financial institutions over corpora- tions is also likely to continue weakening, although less dramatically, in our view: ? A 1974 law, which prohibited banks from lending more than 20 percent of their capital and reserves to a single client, has already reduced the role played by main banks. These banks, usually city banks, act as advisers as well as bankers and spearhead finan- cial rescue packages when necessary. ? Subsequently, Japanese companies made use of their new freedom in financial dealings to decrease further dependence on their main banks. Many firms now regularly tap nonbank and overseas fund- ing sources and participate actively in Japanese money markets. ? The emphasis on trust and personal ties in business dealings in Japan has muted the impact of past liberalization measures. We suspect it will continue to do so in the future, preventing foreign financial intermediaries and the most competitive Japanese ones from quickly expanding their market shares. The power balance among financial institutions is also likely to shift, although the bottom line will depend heavily on the scope of liberalization: ? If product deregulation occurs in tandem with inter- est-rate deregulation, those institutions that now enjoy monopoly privileges in growth areas will be the losers. Examples are trust banks and insurance companies, which have exclusive rights to manage pension funds. ? On the other hand, if a high degree of specialization is maintained in the financial arena, the profitabili- ty and soundness of individual institutions will probably be jeopardized. Smaller banks are most vulnerable, and mergers may prove imperative. ? We believe the current heavyweights in Japanese finance (the large city banks and the four big securities houses) will fare well, regardless of the type of liberalization embraced. These institutions have aggressively internationalized their operations in the last five years and by so doing have learned how to compete in a market environment (see table 5). Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2 Secret Secret Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/05/12 : CIA-RDP85T0031OR000200190003-2