REPORT OF THE NATIONAL COMMISSION ON SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4
Release Decision: 
RIFPUB
Original Classification: 
K
Document Page Count: 
286
Document Creation Date: 
December 21, 2016
Document Release Date: 
October 2, 2008
Sequence Number: 
1
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
January 1, 1983
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4.pdf1.08 MB
Body: 
Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 i?u?u?n?n?u?u?n?u?u?u.u?n.u?u.n?u?u.n?n?u?n?u.u?u.u.u?n.u?u?u?u?u?u?u?u?u?u?u.n?u.n?u?u?u?n?u?n.u?u.n?u?u?n?u?n?u?n?u.n.u? REPORT OF THE NATIONAL COMMISSION ON SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM JANUARY 1983 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 MEMBERS OF THE NATIONAL COMMISSION ON SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM Appointed by the President Alan Greenspan, Chairman -- Chairman and President, Townsend-Greenspan and Company, New York, NY. Robert A. Beck -- Chairman of the Board and Chief Executive Officer, Prudential Insurance Company of America, Newark, NJ. Mary Falvey Fuller -- Management Consultant, San Francisco, CA (Member of 1979 Advisory Council on Social Security). Alexander B. Trowbridge -- President, National Association of Manufacturers, Washington, DC. Joe D. Waggonner, Jr. -- Consultant, Bossier Bank and Trust Company, Bossier City, LA (Member of Congress from Louisiana in 87th to 95th Congresses). Appointed by the Majority Leader of the Senate, in consultation with Minority Leader William Armstrong -- Senator from Colorado and Chairman of Subcommittee on Social Security, Committee on Finance. Robert Dole -- Senator from Kansas and Chairman of Committee on Finance. John Heinz -- Senator from Pennsylvania and Chairman of Special Committee on Aging. Lane Kirkland -- President, American Federation of Labor-Congress of Industrial Organizations. Daniel Patrick Moynihan -- Senator from New York and Ranking Minority Member of Subcommittee on Social Security,,Committee on Finance. Appointed by the Speaker of the House of Representatives, in consultation with the Minority Leader William Archer -- Representative from Texas and Ranking Minority Member, Subcommittee on Social Security, Committee on Ways and Means. Robert M. Ball -- Visiting Scholar, Center for the Study of Social Policy, Washington, DC (Commissioner of Social Security, 1962-73). Barber Conable -- Representative from New York and Ranking Minority Member, Committee on Ways and Means. Martha E. Keys -- Director of Educational Programs, The Association of Former Members of Congress, Washington, DC (Member of Congress from Kansas, in 94th and 95th Congresses, and Assistant Secretary of Health and Human Services, 1980-81). Claude D. Pepper -- Representative from Florida and Chairman of Committee on Rules. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 NATIONAL COMMISSION ON SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM 736 JACKSON PLACE, N.W. WASHINGTON, D.C. 20503 January 20, 1983 The President The White House Washington, D.C. 20500 I hereby transmit to you the report of the bi-partisan National Commission on Social Security Reform, which has made an in-depth review of the financial condition of the Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance Trust Funds in both the short range and the long range. The results of our deliberations are contained in this report. In accordance with Executive Order No. 12335, December 16, 1981, as amended, copies of this report have been sent to the Majority Leader of the Senate, the Speaker of the House of Representatives, and the Secretary of Health and Human Services. ctful submitted, n Ure p Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table of Contents Chapter 1 Introduction Chapter 2 Findings and Recommendations Chapter 3 Financing Problems of the Medicare Program Chapter 4 Additional Statements Appendices A. Executive Order 12335 Establishing the NCSSR and Executive Orders 12397 and 12402 Modifying the Reporting Date B. President's Remarks Announcing the Establishment of the NCSSR C. Charter of the NCSSR D. President's Letter to the Chairman and the Commission Members E. List of Meetings of the NCSSR F. List of Staff Memorandums Prepared for the NCSSR G. Papers presented to the NCSSR H. Staff of NCSSR I. Glossary J. Financial Status of the Social Security Program K. "Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance and Hospital Insurance Programs -- Actuarial Cost Estimates for OASDI and HI and for Various Possible Changes in OASDI and Historical Data for OASDI and HI", Background Book, revised version, December 1982. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Chapter 1 INTRODUCTION On December 16, 1981, President Reagan promulgated Executive Order 12335, which established the National Commission on Social Security Reform. The National Commission was created as a result of the continuing deterioration of the financial position of the Old-Age and Survivors Insurance Trust Fund, the inability of the President and the Congress to agree to a solution, and the concern about eroding public confidence in the Social Security system.-l/ The National Commission is composed of fifteen members, eight Republicans and seven Democrats. Five members were selected by the President, on a bi- partisan basis; five were selected by the Senate Majority Leader, in consultation with the Senate Minority Leader, on a bi-partisan basis; and five were selected by the Speaker of the House of Representatives, in consultation with the House Minority Leader, on a bi-partisan basis. 1/ Throughout this report, the term "Social Security" will be used to denote the combination of the Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance program (OASDI) and the Medicare program, which consists of the Hospital Insurance program (HI) and the Supplementary Medical Insurance program (SMI). The National Commission decided to limit its policy recommendations to the OASDI program. The statutory Advisory Council on Social Security, appointed by the Secretary of Health and Human Services in September 1982, is charged with studying the Medicare program. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 The Executive Order provides that the National Commission should: 11 . . review relevant analyses of the current and long-term financial condition of the Social Security trust funds; identify problems that may threaten the long-term solvency of such funds; analyze potential solutions to such problems that will both assure the financial integrity of the Social Security System and the provision of appropriate benefits; and provide appropriate recommendations to the Secretary of Health and Human Services, the President, and the Congress." In carrying out its mandate, the National Commission met nine times, on approximately a monthly basis. Because of the brevity of the time in which to complete its work, the National Commission held no public hearings. However, it reviewed the results of the many hearings, studies, and reports of other public bodies, including Congress, the 1979 Advisory Council on Social Security, and the 1981 National Commission on Social Security. The National Commission on Social Security Reform sought the advice of a number of experts and thoroughly examined a wide variety of alternative approaches. Chapter 2 presents the major findings and recommendations of the National Commission. Chapter 3 deals with the financial status of the Medicare program. Additional Statements of individual members appear in Chapter 4. The appendices to this report contain the following materials: Executive Order 12335, establishing the National Commission; Executive Order 12397, modifying the original Executive Order by extending the reporting date by 15 days; Executive Order 12402, giving a further extension in the reporting date Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 (until January 20, 1983); the White House press release of December 16, 1981, announcing the membership of the National Commission; the Charter of the National Commission; the President's letter to the National Commission; a list of meetings held; a list of the technical memorandums prepared for the use of the members during their deliberations; a list of the prepared presentations made by experts who appeared before the National Commission; a roster of the staff; a detailed description of the financial status of the Social Security program; and a detailed listing of possible options and their cost effects and basic tables which served as background material for the meetings. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Chapter 2 FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS The National Commission was assigned the critical job of assessing whether the OASDI program has financing problems in the short run and over the long-range future (as represented by the 75-year valuation period) and, if so, recommending how such problems could be resolved. The National Commission has agreed that there is a financing problem for the OASDI program for both the short run, 1983-89 (as measured using pessimistic economic assumptions) and the long range, 1983-2056 (as measured by an intermediate cost estimate) and that action should be taken to strengthen the financial status of the program.!/ The National Commission recognized that, under the intermediate cost estimate, the financial status of the OASDI program in the 1990s and early 2000s will be favorable (i.e., income will significantly exceed outgo) -- see Table 7A in Appendix K. The National Commission also recognized that, under the intermediate cost estimate, the financial status of the HI program becomes increasingly unfavorable from 1990 until the end of the period for which the estimates are made -- see Table 7B in Appendix K. / The assumptions underlying these cost estimates are summarized in Tables 12 and 13 of Appendix K. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 The National Commission makes the following recommendations unanimously: (1) The members of the National Commission believe that the Congress, in its deliberations on financing proposals, should not alter the fundamental structure of the Social Security program or undermine its fundamental principles.* The National Commission considered, but rejected, proposals to make the Social Security program a voluntary one, or to transform it into a program under which benefits are a product exclusively of the contributions paid, or to convert it into a fully-funded program, or to change it to a program under which benefits are conditioned on the showing of financial need.** (2) The National Commission recommends that, for purposes of considering the short-range financial status of the OASDI Trust Funds, $150-200 billion in either additional income or in decreased outgo (or a combination of both) should be provided for the OASDI Trust Funds in calendar years 1983-89. (3) The National Commission finds that, for purposes of considering the long-range financial status of the OASDI Trust Funds, its actuarial See additional views of Commissioner Archer in Chapter 4. See additional views (with regard to the last point) of Commissioners Archer, Fuller, and Waggonner in Chapter 4. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 imbalance for the 75-year valuation period is an average of 1.80% of taxable payroll.?/ The National Commission was able to reach a consensus for meeting the short-range and long-range financial requirements, by a vote of 12 to 3. The 12 members voting in favor of the "consensus" package were Commissioners Ball, Beck, Conable, Dole, Fuller, Greenspan, Heinz, Keys, Kirkland, Moynihan, Pepper, and Trowbridge; the 3 members voting against the "consensus" package were Commissioners Archer, Armstrong, and Waggonner. The 12 members of the National Commission voting in favor of the "consensus" package agreed to a single set of proposals to meet the short-range deficit (with Commissioner Kirkland dissenting on the proposal to cover newly hired Federal employees). They further agreed that the long-range deficit should be reduced to approximately zero. The single set of recommendations would meet about two-thirds of the long-range financial requirements. Seven of the 12 members agreed that the remaining one-third of the long-range financial requirements should be met by a deferred, gradual increase in the normal retirement age, while the other 5 members agreed to an increase in the contribution rates in 2010 of slightly less than one-half percent (0.46%) of covered earnings on the employer and the same amount on the employee, with the This figure is the actuarial lack of balance according to the intermediate (Alternative II-B) cost estimate in the 1982 Trustees Report, after adjustment for the effects of legislation and the actual benefit increase for June 1982. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 employee's share of the increase offset by a refundable income-tax credit (see the statements in Chapter 4 for a presentation of these approaches). Various possible short-range and long-range financing options are displayed in the Commission's Background Book entitled Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance and Hospital Insurance Programs -- Actuarial Cost Estimates for OASDI and HI and for Various Possible Changes in OASDI and Historical Data for OASDI and HI, revised version, December 1982 (which is included in this report as Appendix K). The derivation and underlying basis of the additional financial resources needed in 1983-89, as stated in item (2), are described in detail on pages 16-21 of Appendix J. Provisions of "Consensus" Package Recommendations Nos. (4) to (16) describe the provisions of the "consensus" package. Table A presents the actuarial cost data for this package for both the short range (1983-89 in the aggregate) and the long range (the 75-year valuation period, ending with 2056). Table B gives the year-by-year actuarial cost data for the short-range period. The cost estimates underlying these figures are based on economic assumptions which have been developed in recent weeks and which assume significantly lower levels of both price and wage inflation than does the Alternative III estimate in the 1982 OASDI Trustees Report (and even somewhat lower than in the Alternative II-B estimate). Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Proposal Short-Term Savings, 1983-89 (billions) Long-Range Savings (percentage of payroll) Cover nonprofit and new Federal employeesc/ +$20 +.30% Prohibit withdrawal of State and local government employees +3 -- Taxation of benefits for higher-income persons +30 +.60 Shift COLAs to calendar-year basis +40 +.27 Eliminate windfall benefits for persons with pensions from noncovered employment +.2 +.01 Continue benefits on remarriage for disabled widow(er)s and for divorced widow(er)s -.1 -- Index deferred widow(er)'s benefits based on wages (instead of CPI) -.2 -.05 Permit divorced aged spouse to receive benefits when husband is eligible to receive benefits -.1 -.01 Increase benefit rate for disabled widow(er)s aged 50-59 to 713-2% of primary benefit -1 -.01 Revise tax-rate schedule +40 +.02 Revise tax basis for self-employed +18 +.19 Reallocate OASDI tax rate between OASI and DI -- -- Allow inter-fund borrowing from HI by OASDI -- -- Credit the OASDI Trust Funds, by a lump-sum payment for cost of gratuitous military service wage credits and past unnegotiated checks +18 -- Base automatic benefit increases on lower of CPI or wage increases after 1987 if fund ratio is under 20%, with catch-up if fund ratio exceeds 32% -- -- Increase delayed retirement credit from 3% per year to 8%, beginning in 1990 and reaching 8% in 2010 b/ -- -.10a1 Additional long-range changes- -- +.58 a/ This cost estimate assumes that retirement patterns would be only slightly affected by this change. If this change does result in significant changes in retirement behavior over time, the cost increase would be less (or possibly even a small savings could result). b/ Alternate methods for obtaining this long-range savings are presented in the Additional Statements of the members (in Chapter 4). c/ Includes effect of revised tax schedule. NOTE: See text for complete description of the proposals. 2-5 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 YEAR-BY-YEAR SHORT-RANGE COST ANALYSIS OF OASDI PROPOSALS (in billions) Proposal 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 Cover nonprofit and new Federal workersa/ -- +$l +$2 +$3 +$4 +$4 +$5 +$20 Prohibit withdrawal of State/local workers __ * * * +1 +1 +1 +3 Taxation of benefits for higher-income persons -- +1 +4 +5 +6 +7 +8 +30 Shift COLAs to calendar-year basis +$5 +5 +5 +6 +6 +6 +7 +40 Eliminate windfall benefits -- * * * * * * +.2 -- * * * * * * -.1 Benefits for remarried widow(er)s Index deferred widow(er)'s benefits by wages -- * * * * * * -.2 Divorced spouse's benefits when husband eligible -- * * * * * * -.1 Higher benefit rate for disabled widow(er)s -- * * * * * * -1 Revised tax schedule -- +9 * -- -- +15 +16 +40 Revised tax basis for self-employed -- +1 +3 +3 +3 +4 +5 +18 Credit trust funds for military wage credits +20 -1 -1 * * * * +18 +25 +16 +13 +17 +20 +37 +41 +168 * Less than $500 million. a/ Includes effect of revised tax schedule. NOTE: See text for complete description of the proposals. Those having no short-range cost effect are not shown here. Totals do not always equal the sum of the individual items, due to rounding. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 The "consensus" package would provide an estimated $168 billion in additional financial resources to the OASDI program in calendar years 1983-89. This amount is very close to the midpoint of the $150-200 billion range stated in Recommendation No. 2. Actually, because the economic assumptions which are used for this package involve a lower inflation rate as to both prices and wages than those which had been used earlier in the deliberations, the resulting $168 billion of additional financial resources is really relatively near the upper end of the desired range. (4).he National Commission recommends that coverage under the OASDI program should be extended on a mandatory basis, as of January 1, 1984, to 11 ewly hired civilian employees of the Federal Government.!/* The National Commission also recommends that OASDI-HI coverage should be extended on a mandatory basis, as of January 1, 1984, to all employees of nonprofit organizations. It is important to note that covering additional groups of workers such as those specified in this recommendation not only results in a favorable cash-flow situation in the short run, but also has a favorable long-range effect. The _ Under present law, temporary Federal civilian employees are covered by the OASDI-HI program, and all other Federal civilian employees are covered under the HI program, beginning January 1, 1983. All persons in the armed forces are covered by the OASDI-HI program. * See additional views of Commissioner Archer and additional views of Commissioner Kirkland in dissent, in Chapter 4. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 additional OASDI taxes paid on behalf of the newly-covered workers over the long run will exceed, on the average, the additional benefits which result from such employmen,t_ j/, assuming that the program is in long-range actuarial balance. The National Commission believes that an independent supplemental retirement plan should be developed for the Federal new hires, which would be part of the Civil Service Retirement system (just as private employers have plans supplementing the OASDI program). It is important to note that present Federal employees will not be affected by this recommendation (and that the financing of their benefits over the long run will not be adversely affected) (5) Th N ti l C i i e a ona omm ss on recommends that State and local governments which have elected coverage for their employees under the OASDI-HI program should not be permitted to terminate such coverage in the future -- specifically, termination notices now pending would be invalid if the process of termination is not completed5/ by the enactment date of the new legislation. 4/ The vast majority of the individuals involved would have qualified for sizable OASDI benefits as a result of other employment even if coverage were not extended to these two categories of workers. Also, they tend to have higher-than-average wages and, therefore, are entitled to less-heavily weighted benefits. 5/ Current law provides that withdrawal can occur, after advance notice of at least 2 years, at the end of the calendar year specified in the withdrawal notice. For example, a withdrawal notice filed in February 1981 would (if not withdrawn earlier by the State or local government entity) result in the process of termination being completed on January 1, 1984. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 (6) The National Commission is concerned about the relatively large OASDI benefits that can accrue to individuals who spend most of their working careers in noncovered employment from which they derive pension rights, but who also become eligible for OASDI benefits as a result of relatively short periods in covered employment with other employers. Accordingly, the National Commission recommends that the method of computing benefits should be revised for persons who first become eligible for pensions from non-covered employment, after 1983, so as to eliminate "windfall" benefits. The result of such a work history is to produce OASDI benefits that contain "windfall" elements -- the benefits payable are relatively high compared to the proportion of time spent and the OASDI taxes paid during covered employment. This results from the weighted benefit formula, which treats these individuals in the same manner as if they were long-service, low-earnings workers. Specifically, the National Commission believes that these individuals should receive benefits which are more nearly of a proportionate basis than the heavily-weighted benefits now provided. There are various methods of eliminating the "windfall" portion of benefits (while still providing equitable, proportional benefits). One method would be to modify the benefit formula for determining the Primary Insurance Amount by making the second percentage factor (32%) be applicable to the lowest band of Average Indexed Monthly Earnings (instead of the 90% factor), but the reduction Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 in benefits would not be larger than the pension from non-covered employment. Another method would be to apply the present benefit formula to an earnings record which combines both covered earnings and also non-covered earnings in the future for the purpose of determining a replacement rate (i.e., the ratio of the benefit initially payable to previous earnings); then, that replacement rate would be applied to the average earnings based solely on covered employment. The short-range cost effect of these proposals -- applied only prospectively for new eligibles -- would be relatively small. The long-range cost effect would depend on the procedure used and on whether the recommended extension of coverage is adopted. (7) The National Commission recommends that, beginning with 1984, 50% of OASDI benefits should be considered as taxable income for income-tax purposes for persons with Adjusted Gross Income (before including therein any OASDI benefits) of $20,000 if single and $25,000 if married. The proceeds from such taxation, as estimated by the Treasury Department, would be credited to the OASDI Trust Funds under a permanent appropriation.* It is estimated that about 10% of OASDI beneficiaries would be affected by this provision. The National Commission noted that a "notch" is present in this provision in that those with Adjusted Gross Income of just under the limit of * See additional views of Commissioner Archer in Chapter 4. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 $20,000/$25,000 would have a larger total income (including OASDI benefits) than those with Adjusted Gross Income just over the limit. The National Commission points out the presence of this "notch" and trusts that it will be rectified in the legislative process. (8) The National Commission recommends that the automatic cost-of-living adjustments of OASDI benefits should, beginning in 1983, be made applicable to the December benefit checks (payable early in January), rather than being first applicable to the June payments. The National Commission also recommends that the amount of the disregard of OASDI benefits for purposes of determining Supplemental Security Income payment levels should be increased from $20 a month to $50. The increase in the CPI for purposes of the automatic adjustments for any particular year is currently measured from the first quarter of the previous year to the first quarter of that particular year. This procedure should continue to apply for the adjustment in benefit amounts for 1983 (payable in early January 1984). However, for subsequent years, the comparison should be made on a "third quarter to third quarter" basis. The recommended increase in the amount of the disregard of OASDI benefits for SSI purposes is estimated to have an initial cost of about $750 million per year. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 (9) The National Commission recommends that the following changes in benefit provisions which affect mainly women should be made: (a) Present law permits the continuation of benefits for surviving spouses who remarry after age 60. This would also be done for (1) disabled surviving spouses aged 50-59, (2) disabled divorced surviving spouses aged 50-59, and (3) divorced surviving spouses aged 60 or over. (b) Spouse benefits for divorced spouses would be payable at age 62 or over (subject to the requirement that the divorce has lasted for a significant period) if the former spouse is eligible for retirement benefits, whether or not they have been claimed (or they have been suspended because of substantial employment). (c) Deferred surviving-spouse benefits would continue to be indexed as under present law, except that the indexing would be based on the increases in wages after the death of the worker (instead of by the increases in the CPI, as under present law). (d) The benefit rate for disabled widows and widowers aged 50-59 at disablement would be the same as that for non-disabled widows and widowers first claiming benefits at age 60 (i.e., 712% of the Primary Insurance Amount), instead of the lower rates under present law (gradually rising from 50% at age 50 to 712% for 2-12 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 disablement at age 60). Such change would not only be applicable to new cases, but would also be applicable to beneficiaries of this category who are on the rolls on the effective date of the provision. (10) The National Commission recommends that the OASDI tax schedule should be revised so that the 1985 rate would be moved to 1984, the 1985-87 rates would remain as scheduled under present law, part of the 1990 rate would be moved to 1988, and the rate for 1990 and after would remain unchanged. The HI tax rates for all years would remain unchanged. The resulting tax schedule would be as follows: Employer and Employee Rate (each) OASDI OASDI-HI Year Present Law Proposal Present Law Proposal 1983 5.4% 5.4% 6.7% 6.7% 1984 5.4 5.7 6.7 7.0 1985 5.7 5.7 7.05 7.05 1986 5.7 5.7 7.15 7.15 1987 5.7 5.7 7.15 7.15 1988-89 5.7 6.06 7.15 7.51 1990 and after 6.2 6.2 7.65 7.65 For 1984, a refundable income tax credit would be provided against the individual's Federal income-tax liability in the amount of the increase in the employee taxes over what would have been payable under present law.* See additional views of Commissioner Archer in Chapter 4. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 (11) The National Commission recommends that the OASDI tax rates for self- employed persons should, beginning in 1984, be equal to the combined employer-employee rates. One-half of the OASDI taxes paid by self- employed persons should then be considered as a business expense for income-tax purposes (but not for purposes of determining the OASDI-HI tax).* Under present law, self-employed persons pay an OASDI tax rate which is approximately equal to 75% of the combined employer-employee rate (exactly 75% for 1985 and after) and an HI tax rate which is 50% of the combined employer- employee rate. Also, under present law, self-employed persons cannot deduct, as business expenses, any OASDI-HI taxes paid. The reduction in income taxes payable by the self-employed during 1984-89 as a result of considering one-half of their OASDI taxes as a business expense is estimated to be about $12 billion. (12) The National Commission recommends that the proposed OASDI tax rates should be allocated between the OASI and DI Trust Funds in a manner different from present law, in order that both funds will have about the same fund ratios. (13) The National Commission recommends that the authority for inter-fund borrowing by the OASDI Trust Funds from the HI Trust Fund be authorized for 1983-87. * See additional views of Commissioner Archer in Chapter 4. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 (14) The National Commission recommends that a lump-sum payment should be made to the OASDI Trust Funds from the General Fund of the Treasury for the following items: (a) The present value of the estimated additional benefits arising from the gratuitous military service wage credits for service before 1957 (subject to subsequent adjustments if the experience deviates from the estimates). (b) The amount of the combined employer-employee OASDI taxes on the gratuitous military service wage credits for service after 1956 and before 1983 (which were granted as a recognition of non-cash remuneration, and the cost of which is met, under present law, when additional benefits derived therefrom are paid). The payment would include interest, but would be reduced for any costs therefor which were paid in the past to the OASDI Trust Funds from the General Fund of the Treasury. In the future, the OASDI Trust Funds would be reimbursed on a current basis for such employer-employee taxes on such wage credits for service after 1982. (c) The amount of uncashed OASDI checks issued in the past (which were charged against the trust funds at time of issue), estimated at about $300-400 million. (The problem of uncashed Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 checks in the future has been corrected as a result of changed procedures of the Treasury Department with regard to checks which are uncashed for a long time.) (15) The National Commission recommends that, beginning with 1988, if the fund ratio6/ of the combined OASDI Trust Funds as of the beginning of a year is less than 20.0% (except that, for 1988, the fund ratio to be considered would be that estimated for the end of that year), the automatic cost-of-living (COLA) adjustments of OASDI benefits should be based on the lower of the CPI increase or the increase in wages. If the fund ratio is 32.0% or more at the beginning of a year, payments will be made during the following year as supplements to monthly benefits otherwise payable to make up to individuals for any use of wage increases instead of CPI increases in the past, but only to the extent that sufficient funds are available over those needed to maintain a fund ratio of 32.0%.L/ 6 1 - - d ratio is the balance in the fund, exclusive of any outstanding loan from the HI Trust Fund, as a percentage of the estimated outgo from the fund in the year. 7/ When the fund ratio at the beginning of a particular year exceeds the trigger level of 32.0%, there would be a "catch-up" for those individuals on the benefit rolls at the time of the next COLA for whom some benefits in the past had been increased on the basis of wage increases instead of CPI increases. For each such person, the cumulative percentage benefit reduction up to the beginning of that particular year would be recorded. Such percentage reduction would be applicable as a percentage increase for the benefits payable for the first 12 months following the next COLA. If there were not sufficient funds available to provide a complete "catch-up", then the percentage increase in the benefits for the 12-month period would be pro-rated so that the estimated cost of this "catch-up" would equal the funds available. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 This provision will serve as a stabilizer against the possibility of exceptionally poor economic performance over a period of time. The increases in wages would be determined from the "SSA average wage index", the series used by the Social Security Administration in determining such elements of the program as the maximum taxable earnings base and the "bend points" in the formula for the Primary Insurance Amount. As an example, assuming that this new indexing method were applicable for 1995 (for the December checks), the COLA percentage would be the smaller of (1) the percentage increase in the CPI from the third quarter of 1994, to the third quarter of 1995 or (2) the percentage increase in the "SSA average wage index" from 1993 to 1994. (16) The National Commission recommends that the Delayed-Retirement Credit should be increased from the present 3% (for persons who attained age 65 after 1981) to 8%, to be phased in over the period 1990-2010. Under present law, persons who do not receive benefits after age 65 (essentially because of substantial employment of any kind) receive increases in their benefit (and in their widowed spouse's benefit, but not in any other auxiliary benefit) at the rate of 3% for each year of delay in receipt of benefits from age 65 through age 71.$/ Under the proposal, the Delayed- 8/ A technical error in the law results in age 71 being stipulated, rather than age 69; this provision should not be applicable after age 69, because the earnings test no longer applies beyond that age. This error should be corrected when the recommended change is legislated. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Retirement Credit for months in 1990 would be at the rate of 34%, those for 1991 would be at the rate of 32%, etc. until an 8% rate would be reached in 2009 and after. Coverage of Payments Under Salary-Reduction Plans (17) The National Commission recommends that, in the case of salary- reduction plans qualifying under Section 401(k) of the Internal Revenue Code, any salary reduction thereunder shall not be treated as a reduction in the wages subject to OASDI-HI taxes. Section 401(k) of the Internal Revenue Code permits employers to install "salary-reduction" plans, under which employees may elect to forego a salary increase or have part of their pay set aside in a tax-sheltered fund. Such deferred salary is neither subject to Federal income tax currently, nor is it subject to the OASDI-HI tax. The National Commission believes that, for both OASDI-HI tax and benefit credit purposes, any salary deferred under a plan meeting the requirements of Section 401(k) should be considered in exactly the same manner as cash remuneration. This proposal will not produce significant additional income to the OASDI and HI programs currently, because not many of these salary-reduction plans have Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 yet been put into effect. However, if the recommendation is not followed, it is quite probable that many such plans will be instituted and that, in the absence of the action recommended, considerable decreases in OASDI-HI tax income to the trust funds and in benefit credits would result. Fail-Safe Mechanisms (18) The National Commission believes that, in addition to the stabilizing mechanism of Recommendation (15), a fail-safe mechanism is necessary so that benefits could continue to be paid on time despite unexpectedly adverse conditions which occur with little advance notice.!/ Several types of fail-safe mechanisms are possible other than the one currently being used --inter-fund borrowing; there is strong disagreement among the members as to which type of mechanism should be used. A combination of these types of mechanisms would, of course, be possible. A number of mechanisms were considered. One would be to borrow, for a limited period, from the General Fund of the Treasury. Such limitation would prevent this procedure from being a part of the permanent method for financing 9F-ft- is most unlikely that such a situation would, with proper actuarial guidance, happen with shorter notice than a year or so. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 the program. Another possibility along this line would be to permit the trust funds to issue their own bonds for sale to the general public. A second mechanism would be to reduce, temporarily, the benefits payable. Alternatively, such a result could be accomplished indirectly, by reducing the amount of the next benefit increase which would occur as a result of the automatic-adjustment provision for benefits in eligibility status. The third mechanism would be to increase, temporarily, the OASDI tax rates and/or the maximum taxable earnings base. The National Commission makes a number of recommendations in addition to those discussed previously. Although these additional recommendations are of importance, they will not likely have any significant financial effects, on the average over the long run. Investment Procedures (19) The National Commission recommends that the investment procedures of the OASI, DI, HI, and SMI Trust Funds be revised so that (1) all future special issues would be invested on a month-to-month basis, Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 (i.e., without fixed maturity dates, as under present law), at an interest rate based on the average market rate of all public-debt obligations with a duration of four or more years until maturit : ;not including "flower bonds"10/ ); (2) all present special issues would be redeemed at their face amount; (3) all "flower bonds"10/ would be redeemed at their current market values; (4) all other current holdings would be held until maturity (unless disposed of sooner, if needed to meet outgo); and (5) only special issues would be purchased by the trust funds in the future. There has been widespread public discussion about the investment procedures of the four Social Security trust funds. The view has frequently been expressed that the investments have not been made on a proper basis and that sufficiently high rates of return have not been obtained, because the average rate of return has, in recent years, been far lower than that on newly issued Government obligations. This is not a valid comparison, because it compares the new-issues rate with the average portfolio rate, which includes the effect of the lower interest rates on long-term obligations bought some years ago (at rates which were equitable and proper at that time). The same situation as to a higher 10/ "Flower bonds" are certain series of government bonds that were issued in the past (but which are no longer issued) which contain a provision that if the purchaser holds them for a certain length of time, then for inheritance-tax purposes, they are redeemable at par (regardless of the market value). Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 interest rate on new issues than on the total portfolio, as of recent years, has also been present for private pension funds and insurance companies. The National Commission believes that the investment procedures followed by the trust funds in the past generally have been proper and appropriate. The monies available have generally been invested appropriately in Government obligations at interest rates which are equitable to both the trust funds and the General Fund of the Treasury and have not -- as is sometimes alleged -- been spent for other purposes outside of the Social Security program. Nonetheless, the National Commission makes this recommendation in order to improve the level of public understanding of the operations of the trust funds. On the whole, and over the long-range future, it is likely that such a change in investment procedure will have little (if any) effect on the financial status of the Social Security program. It will probably result in a slightly higher average rate of return in the immediate future. The long-range effects are not determinable and, in any case, are not of great significance with regard to the overall financing of the program. Although the National Commission has not considered the Medicare program in depth, it believes that the same investment procedures should apply for the HI and SMI Trust Funds as for the OASDI Trust Funds. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Public Members on Board of Trustees (20) The National Commission recommends that two public members be added to the Board of Trustees of the OASDI Trust Funds. The public members would be nominated by the President and confirmed by the Senate. No more than one public member could be from any particular political party. The National Commission believes that increasing the membership of the Board of Trustees of the OASDI Trust Funds by including two individuals from outside the Executive Branch, on a bi-partisan basis, would be desirable from the standpoint of confidence in the integrity of the trust funds. The presence of such public members would inspire more confidence in the investment procedure (even though it is recommended that the procedure should be placed on a more or less automatic basis, as under the previous recommendation) and would help to assure that the demographic and economic assumptions for the cost estimates of the future operations of the program would continue to be 'developed in an objective manner. Although the National Commission is not generally making recommendations in connection with the Medicare program, it would seem reasonable that the same procedure of having two public members on the Board of Trustees should also apply for the HI and SMI Trust Funds. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Social Security and the Unified Budget (21) A majority of the members of the National Commission recommends that the operations of the OASI, DI, HI, and SMI Trust Funds should be removed from the unified budget. Some of those who do not support this recommendation believe that the situation would be adequately handled if the operations of the Social Security program were displayed within the present unified Federal budget as a separate budget function, apart from other income security programs. Before fiscal year 1969, the operations of the Social Security trust funds were not included in the unified budget of the Federal Government, although they were made available publicly and were combined, for purposes of economic analysis, with the administrative budget in special summary tables included in the annual budget document. Beginning then, the operations of the Social Security trust funds were included in the unified budget. In 1974, Congress implicitly approved the use of a unified budget by including Social Security trust fund operations in the annual budget process. Thus, in years when trust-fund income exceeded outgo, the result was a decrease in any general budget deficit that otherwise would have been shown -- and vice versa. The National Commission believes that changes in the Social Security program should be made only for programmatic reasons, and not for purposes of balancing the budget. Those who support the removal of the operations of the Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 trust funds from the budget believe that this policy of making changes only for programmatic reasons would be more likely to be carried out if the Social Security program were not in the unified budget. Some members also believe that such a procedure will make clear the effect and presence of any payments from the General Fund of the Treasury to the Social Security program. (Under present procedures, such payments are a "wash" and do not affect the overall budget deficit or surplus). Those who oppose this recommendation believe that it is essential that the operations of the Social Security program should remain in the unified Federal budget because the program involves such a large proportion of all Federal outlays. Thus, to omit its operations would misrepresent the activities of the Federal Government and their economic impact. Furthermore, it is important to ensure that the financial condition of the Social Security program be constantly visible to the Congress and the public. Highlighting the operations of the Social Security program as a separate line function in the budget would allow its impact thereon to be seen more clearly. Social Security Administration as an Independent Agency (22) The majority of the members of the National Commission believes -- as a broad, general principle -- that it would be logical to have the Social Security Administration be a separate independent agency, Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 perhaps headed by a bi-partisan board. The National Commission recommends that a study should be made as to the feasibility of doing this.* The Social Security Administration is now part of the Department of Health and Human Services. Its fiscal operations and the size of its staff are larger than those of the remainder of the Department combined. The National Commission has not had the time to look into the various complex issues involved in such an administrative reorganization and, therefore, recommends that a study group should be formed to look into this matter. Issues involved include whether the leadership of such an independent agency should be assigned to a single individual or whether there should be a governing board of several members, selected on a bi-partisan basis, and whether the operations of the Medicare program should be included in such an independent agency, or whether they should remain as a subsidiary agency within the Department of Health and Human Sevices, as at present. * See additional views of Commissioners Ball, Keys, Kirkland, Moynihan, and Pepper in Chapter 4. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Coverage of State and Local Government Employees Although the National Commission believes that coverage of all persons who are in paid employment is desirable, some members do not favor mandatory coverage of employees of State and local governments. A majority of the members is concerned about the constitutional problem of covering State and local government employees under Social Security on a mandatory basis because the Federal Government may not have the power to compel State and local governments to pay the employer share of the OASDI-HI tax. Other members believe that, regardless of the constitutionality question, the Federal Government should not do so because the two levels of government have equal roles and status. Some members point out that many State and local governments already have adequate, well-financed retirement systems for their employees, so that they do not need OASDI-HI coveragell/; others point out that many State and local systems have serious financing problems and that protection of the benefits under such systems against inflation (and often protection against other risks) is not as adequate as under the OASDI program. 11/ A relatively small number of State and local government employees do not have either OASDI-HI coverage or public-employee retirement systems. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Benefit Provisions Primarily Affecting Women In recent years, there has been widespread discussion as to whether the basic structure of the Social Security program should be altered in view of the changes in the role of women in our society and economy.* Some members of the National Commission believe that there should be a comprehensive change in the program to reflect the changing role of women, for example, by instituting some form of earnings sharing for purposes of the Social Security earnings record. Simply stated, earnings sharing means that all covered earnings received by a couple during the period of marriage would be pooled and half would be credited to each of their earnings records. Some other members believed that such comprehensive changes were outside of the scope of the charge of the National Commission. Social Security Cards The National Commission commends a recent decision of the Social Security Administration to use banknote-quality paper for new and replacement Social Security cards. The Senate Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations estimated in June 1982 that fraud involving identification cards, of which Social Security cards are the vast majority, cost the Federal Government between $15 and $24 billion per year. * See additional views of Commissioner Fuller and additional views of Commissioners Ball, Keys, Kirkland, Moynihan, and Pepper, in Chapter 4. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Chapter 3 FINANCING PROBLEMS OF THE MEDICARE PROGRAM This chapter deals with the consideration which has been given to the financial status of the two portions of the Medicare program by the National Commission. HOSPITAL INSURANCE PROGRAM According to the 1982 HI Trustees Report, the HI Trust Fund is estimated to be depleted by the early part of the 1990s and possibly even by the end of this decade. Over the next 25 years, the program is anticipated, under the Alternative II-B assumptions of that report, to have an actuarial deficit that averages about 1/% of taxable payroll. About $12.4 billion was loaned to the OASI Trust Fund by the HI Trust Fund in December 1982, as permitted by the law then in effect. Because the HI Trust Fund will be depleted at some time within the next decade, according to current estimates, the amounts borrowed by the OASI Trust Fund in 1982 should desirably be repaid to the HI Trust Fund as soon as feasible. These future financing problems of the HI program were not addressed specifically by the National Commission, with the exception of those aspects 3-1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 that relate directly to the financial status of the OASDI program. Such action was taken both because of the more immediate financing problems of the OASDI program and because the recently-named Advisory Council on Social Security will be concerned exclusively with making recommendations on the Medicare program and its future solvency. The "consensus" package described in Chapter 2 would result in some additional financial resources for the HI program, as indicated below (see text of Chapter 2 for complete description of the proposals): Proposal Short-Term Savings, 1983-89 (billions) Long-Range Savings (percentage of payroll) Cover nonprofit employees +$1,7 +.02% Prohibit withdrawal of State/local employees + .5 Total Effect + 2.2 +.02 Although the National Commission did not specifically address the future financing problems of the HI program, some members were concerned about the estimates of large future financing short-falls. The first major concern was the possibility that any excess of income over outgo of the OASDI Trust Funds during 1990-2010 could be endangered by the extensive financing needed by the HI Trust Fund during that period. The second major concern was that, by ignoring the cost of the HI program, the potential tax burden of the entire Social Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Security program might not be properly assessed when making reforms in the OASDI portion of the program. Some members believe that the problem of financing the HI program is not simply a matter of providing the funds to meet the costs projected on the basis of past experience, but rather that first the matter of slowing the rate of increase in hospital costs generally should be addressed. According to the intermediate cost estimate, the combined OASDI-HI system will develop significant annual deficits (excesses of outgo over income) beginning shortly after 1990. These deficits will become increasingly larger as time goes by. Thus, ultimately (2030-56), the combined deficits will be somewhat more than 12% of taxable payroll.* About 65% of such deficits will be caused by the HI program. In considering these estimates, it should be recognized that the underlying assumption is that hospital costs will continue to rise more rapidly than the general wage level for the next 25 years and at the same rate thereafter. In other words, they assume that mandatory or voluntary actions to control hospital costs undertaken in the next 25 years will be effective only to the extent that the growth in hospital costs as compared with the general level of wages will not be reduced below what is assumed in the actuarial cost estimates for the HI program.!! 1/ These assumptions are summarized in Table Al of the 1982 HI Trustees Report. * See views of Commissioners Ball, Keys, Kirkland, Moynihan, and the undesirability of cost estimates for the HI program going 25 years into the future, in Chapter 4. Pepper further as to than Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUPPLEMENTARY MEDICAL INSURANCE PROGRAM The National Commission did not believe that it was necessary to make any recommendations with regard to the SMI portion of the Medicare program. Its financing is -- as discussed in Appendix J -- entirely on a year-by-year basis, rather than on a long-range basis, as are the three payroll-tax-supported programs (OASI, DI, and HI). For calendar year 1982, the payments from the General Fund of the Treasury to the SMI Trust Fund are estimated to represent 77% of the total of the premium income and such payments. The financial status of the SMI Trust Fund is currently excellent. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Chapter 4 ADDITIONAL STATEMENTS This chapter consists of additional statements of individual members of the National Commission. These statements are presented alphabetically by name of member; those which are signed onto by several members appear first. The statements appear in the following order: (1) Commissioners Archer, Beck, Conable, Dole, Fuller, Greenspan, Heinz, and Trowbridge (2) Commissioners Ball, Keys, Kirkland, Moynihan, and Pepper (long- range financing and issues of special concern to women) (3) Commissioners Ball, Keys, Kirkland, Moynihan, and Pepper (independent agency) (4) Commissioners Ball, Keys, Kirkland, Moynihan, and Pepper (HI cost estimates) (5) Commissioners Dole and Conable (6) Commissioner Archer (7) Commissioner Armstrong (8) Commissioner Fuller (long-range financing) (9) Commissioner Fuller (issues of special concern to women) (10) Commissioner Kirkland (11) Commissioner Waggonner Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUPPLEMENTARY STATEMENT ON MEETING THE LONG-RANGE FINANCING REQUIREMENTS BY COMMISSIONERS ARCHER, BECK, CONABLE, DOLE, FULLER, GREENSPAN, HEINZ, AND TROWBRIDGE The recommendations made in the "consensus" package fail to meet the long- range goal of providing additional financing equivalent to 1.8% of taxable payroll. The shortfall is an estimated .58% of taxable payroll. We believe that this should be derived by a delayed, slowly phased-in increase in the "normal" retirement age (the age at which unreduced retirement benefits are available to insured workers, spouses, and widow(er)s -- which is age 65 under present law). The major reasons for this proposal are: (1) Americans are living longer. (2) Older workers will be in a greater demand in future years. (3) The disability benefits program can be improved to provide cash benefits and Medicare to those between age 62 and the higher normal retirement age who, for reasons of health, are unable to continue working. (4) Because the ratio of workers to beneficiaries is projected to decline after the turn of the century, younger generations are expected to pay significantly increased taxes to support the system in the 21st century. An increase in the normal retirement age will lessen the increase. (5) Given sufficient notice, coming generations of beneficiaries can adjust to a later retirement age just as earlier generations adjusted to age 65. Statement (1), page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Although we believe that greater action in this direction may be desirable, we are suggesting only enough change to produce approximately the needed .58% of taxable payroll. The recommended change would apply only to the normal retirement age. Early-retirement benefits would continue to be available beginning at age 62 for insured workers and spouses and at age 60 for widows and widowers, but the actuarial reduction factors would be larger. The minimum age for eligibility for Medicare benefits would continue to be the "normal" retirement age for OASDI benefits. Disability benefits are now available under somewhat less stringent definitions for those aged 60-64. However, because some workers, particularily those in physically demanding employment, may not benefit from improvements in mortality and be able to work longer, we asume that the diability benefits program will be improved prior to th implementation of this recommendation to take into account the special problems of those between age 62 and the normal retirement age who are unable to extend their working careers for health reasons. Under our proposal, the normal retirement age would be gradually increased --one month each year -- to age 66 in 2015, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 2000. Beginning with those who attain age 62 in 2012, the normal retirement age would be automatically adjusted (on a phased-in basis) so that the ratio of the retirement-life expectancy to the potential working-lifetime (from age 20 to the "normal" retirement age) remains the same over the years as it was in 1990. The estimated long-range savings of this proposal is 0.65% of taxable payroll. Statement (1), page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUPPLEMENTARY STATEMENT Commissioners Robert M. Ball, Martha Keys, Lane Kirkland, Daniel Patrick Moynihan and Claude Pepper (members selected by the Democratic leadership of the Congress) Long-Term Financing and Issues of Special Concern to Women Meeting the Remaining Long-Term Deficit All of us supported the compromise agreement which is being recommended by a vote of 12 to 3 of the full Commission.!/ The agreement provides for fully meeting the Commission's short-term financing goal and also for meeting about two-thirds of the Commission's long-term goal--1.22% of payroll out of the 1.8% projected need. We recommend that the remaining 0.58% of payroll deficit be met by providing additional revenues starting in the year 2010, in advance of the period when the bulk of the deficit is projected to occur. Sufficient additional revenues would be provided by an increase of less than one-half of 1% (0.46%) in deductions from workers' earnings beginning in 2010 and a like amount in employer payroll taxes (with an equal combined rate for the self-employed) or the revenue could be supplied by an equivalent general revenue contribution, or some combination of the two. For purposes of present legislation we would support putting in the law now an increase in the contribution rate beginning in _1% Mr. Kirkland is not joining in the recommendation to extend coverage to Federal employees and has filed a supplemental statement on the issue. Statement (2), page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 2010 of 0.46% of payroll (with the employee contribution offset by a refundable income tax credit) recognizing, of course, that in the next century the Congress may prefer to raise the money in some other way and that, in fact, such a rate increase would not be allowed to go into effect unless estimates at the time of the scheduled increase showed that it would be needed. An increase of less than one-half of 1% in the contribution rates in all probability would not mean an increase in the burden of supporting OASDI because: (1) By 2010 real wages are likely to be substantially higher than they are now; and, (2) although levied at a higher rate, the rate will apply to a smaller portion of total compensation than today if the expansion of non-taxable fringe benefits projected in the estimates actually occurs. (If such expansion fails to materialize the contribution rate increase would be unnecessary.) In contrast to our plan for meeting the part of the long-range deficit not addressed by the compromise agreement, some members of the Commission seek to meet the remaining deficit by raising the age at which full benefits are first payable and then continuing to raise the age automatically in relation to improvements in longevity. This proposal is a benefit cut. If the age is raised to 68, benefits would be reduced by 20% relative to those received at age 65; if it is raised to age 67, the cut is 13%; and if set at age 66, the cut is 7%. Statement (2), page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 The cut would be concentrated on those unable to work up to the newly set higher age and on those unable to find jobs. It would cut protection for those now young, the very group being asked to pay in more and for a longer period of time. And an automatic provision changing the age of first eligibility for full benefits would make it very difficult for people to plan for retirement. It would also greatly complicate private pension planning. In our opinion it is unwise to try to index Social Security for all possible future changes in society. Social Security has enough indexing. Congress can act to make future changes in the long-run future as needed. We favor the maintenance of the full range of retirement options in present law so that the program will be responsive to the great variety of occupations in the American economy and to the great variety of individual circumstances. It is one thing for example, to consider a higher age of first eligibility for full benefits for white collar workers; something else again for those required to do heavy work. The system today has the required flexibility. It provides: (1) full benefits at any age for qualified workers who have long continued total disability, (2) actuarially reduced benefits for those who apply between ages 62 and 65, (3) higher benefits for those who postpone retirement and continue to work between 65 and 70 (3% a year additional benefits under present law, to be raised to 8% during the 1990's under the Commission recommendations). Some have argued for raising the age at which full benefits are first payable on the ground that as life expectancy increases, so will the ability to Statement (2), page 3 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 work. However two leading government authorities on health and the aging testified before the Commission that data on increased longevity carry no evidence that health improved commensurately. If anything, they said, what evidence there is indicates the contrary; more people living longer, but with more chronic illness and impairments. Moreover, recent increases in longevity may be related to retirement at earlier ages. It is, of course, highly uncertain what the economy and the labor market will look like in the next century. Two major possibilities exist. A labor shortage may result from projected shrinkage of the proportion of persons in the 20-64 age group?/. In that event, greater market demand for the services of older people would produce greater paid-work opportunities for them. Employers would be seeking older people and the benefit increase for work after 65 recommended by the Commission would encourage older people to work. If, on the other hand, a labor shortage does not materialize, raising the age of first eligibility for full Social Security benefits would force a large number of elderly persons into early retirement with lower benefits than current law provides. We should not cut benefits in an attempt to keep older persons at work. Instead we should recognize and remove the impediments that stand between older workers and employment. Most important of all, economic arrangements should 2% A labor shortage would result only if the relative reduction in the working age population were not offset by productivity improvements. Statement (2), page 4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 favor full employment and, then, the voluntary approach -- the incentives prepared by the Commission -- will have a chance to work. Social Security benefits are not so large as to cancel the lure of good wages. The best medicine for Social Security is full employment and economic growth, not benefit cuts. Meeting Problems of Special Concern to Women Since enactment of the Civil Rights Act of 1964, Federal law has sought to prevent and redress unequal treatment of women. Despite those efforts, substantial inequalities persist and much remains to be done. In general, gender-based discrimination has been eliminated from the OASDI program through legislative change and court decisions, but in recent years there has been a growing concern regarding the extent to which the Social Security system has adapted to the changed roles of women in society and the economy. The labor force participation rate for married women has almost doubled in the last 25 years. Over 65% of all women aged 20 to 54 are now in the labor force. In addition, the divorce rate has increased significantly. Two decades ago, there was one divorce for every four marriages; in 1976 that rate had risen to one divorce for every two marriages. Although the scope and urgency of economic considerations appropriately consumed most of the time of the Commission, it did give attention to some of Statement (2), page 5 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 the problems that currently exist for women in Social Security coverage. Four specific recommendations were made for important changes affecting certain groups of widows, divorced women and disabled women. Social Security has indeed given extensive protection to women and men. It provides benefits for 91% of women over 65 today (compared to 10% of women who received benefits from a private pension system in 1980). Nevertheless, the significant changes in women's roles in society and the economy have caused many inequities and unintended results for women beneficiaries. Today, the majority (65%) of working age women are in the labor force; yet their benefits may be greatly reduced if they leave the labor force for a period of time for homemaking or child-caring. Also lower family retirement and survivor benefits exist for 2 wage-earner couples than for 1 wage-earner couples with the same family earnings history (although there are some advantages to having benefits based on one's own earnings that are partly offsetting). Homemakers have no individual coverage or eligibility to Social Security and no credits of their own on which to build with later employment because of early widowhood or any other reason. Divorced women may be severely affected by the arbitrary 10-year duration-of-marriage requirement and the inadequacy of the 50% dependent benefit for their independent economic needs. Currently, the benefit for the divorced woman depends upon the actual retirement of the former spouse; however, the Commission has recommended a change which will correct this Statement (2), page 6 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 problem. Disability protection exists only for women who remain quite continuously in the labor force and not at all for homemakers. It is often lost to working women during a period of time spent in the home. Since the introduction in 1976 by Representative Martha Keys and Representative Don Fraser of legislation to implement the concept of earnings sharing, many have believed this to be the best solution to these anomalies. Earnings sharing is a recognition of marriage as an economic partnership with equal respect given to the division of labor chosen by each couple. It accords the right of each individual to a retirement income based on half of the total retirement credits earned by the couple during their marriage. This is similar in concept to the sharing of income in the joint tax return of a married couple. Working women would have a continuous record of Social Security credits when they retire instead of zero credits for years spent in the home. It would respond to, and recognize, the economic value to the couple of full-time work in the home by either spouse. Earnings sharing has been proposed in many forms and was recommended for consideration by both the 1979 Advisory Council on Social Security and the 1980 President's Commission on Pension Policy. Obviously, such a comprehensive change in structure requires careful development of a detailed proposal and thorough analysis of its impact. There are many technical and administrative questions to be worked out and special consideration must be given to continued strong protection for the family against death or disablement of its primary Statement (2), page 7 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 wage-earner. These are not insurmountable problems, however. We believe that earnings sharing is the most promising approach to the solution of Social Security problems of special concern to women and we urge renewed efforts to develop a comprehensive proposal based on this concept. Statement (2), page 8 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUPPLEMENTARY STATEMENT BY Commissioners Robert M. Ball, Martha Keys, Lane Kirkland, Daniel Patrick Moynihan and Claude Pepper (members selected by the Democratic leadership of the Congress) Social Security as an Independent Agency We believe that it would improve the operation of the Social Security system and strengthen public confidence in the integrity of the program if it were administered as an independent agency under a bi-partisan 3oard as it was in the early days of the program. We do not believe that an in-depth study is necessary, but rather any study should be confined to the details of implementation. Statement (3) Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUPPLEMENTARY STATEMENT Commissioners Robert M. Ball, Martha Keys, Lane Kirkland, Daniel Patrick Moynihan and Claude Pepper (members selected by the Democratic leadership of the Congress) HI Cost Estimates We do not believe that the work of the Commission provided any basis for overturning the long-term position of the Board of Trustees that the HI estimates should be limited to 25 years, and we object to the use of a 75-year valuation period for HI cost estimates. The Trustees consider that the degree of uncertainty concerning future hospital costs, relative to the remainder of the economy, is so great as to make projections beyond 25 years thoroughly misleading. Since official projections for the Hospital Insurance (Medicare) program are made for only 25 years, tax rates are formulated based on expected income and outgo only during that period. It is misleading to extend a fixed tax rate into the distant future while assuming that costs continue to accelerate. This procedure (1) exaggerates program costs and (2) assumes that unlimited growth in health care costs would be permitted without intervention. Statement (4) Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 ADDITIONAL VIEWS OF SENATOR ROBERT J. DOLE AND CONGRESSMAN BARBER B. CO?]ABLE, JR. When the National Commission. on Social Security Reform was created on December 16, 1981, few people had real confidence in what the commission could accomplish. And little wonder. For the better part of a year, social security had been embroiled in political controversy. The system moved closer to insolvency as proposals for financial reform were subjected to partisan political attack. The 15 selected as commission-members; moreover, embodied widely divergent views At-least-to outsiders, these members probably seemed incapable of reaching any true bi-partisan consensus. In the last several days, the commission accomplished what some said was impossible. With the cooperation and approval of President Reagan and House Speaker O'Neill, the commission forged a consensus reform package with broad bipartisan support. As detailed earlier in this report, the package is designed td close the short-term deficit identified by the commission, and-go a long way toward closing the long-range deficit. It requires concessions from all of the parties who have a stake in social security--current and future beneficiaries, taxpayers, and government employees who do not now contribute to the system. while no one member is happy with every specific recommendation, the important fact is that a consensus was reached on how to save Statement (5), Page 1' Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 the system. The bipartisan reform package, which we plan to introduce into the Senate with Senators Heinz, Moynihan, and others, and into the House, merits speedy Congressional action. Agreeing on the essential provisions of a social security solution was by no means the only accomplishment of the commission. It should be noted that the commission reached unanimous agreement on the size of the short- and long-term deficits in the social security cash benefit programs (old-age and survivors insurance and dis.abili.ty insurance). That is, in concrete dollar terms, the. -commission. quanti.f i-ed the seriousness and the urgency of the financing problem. In our judgment, S150- $200 billion is the amount required to keep the system (excluding medicare) solvent through 1990. Over the very long term, the next 75 years, the needs of the system amount to about S25 billion a year (in 1983 dollar terms) over and above currently scheduled tax income. Only a year ago, partisan lines were drawn between those who did and- and did not believe there was any financing problem at all before the year 2000. In addition, the National. Commission provided a valuable forum for the diverse views on social security. With the able -leadership of Chairman Alan Greenspan and with the expert assistance of Executive Director Robert Myers, members of both political parties were able to work together in studying the social security financing problem and options for financial Statement (5), Page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 reform. The interests of the elderly, organized labor and business, and the general taxpayer were all well represented. In recent weeks, we engaged in intensive negotiations which were, to a large extent, absent of the political partisanship that so seriously damaged efforts for responsible -reform in 1981. Finally, we believe the commission's recommendations are: significant in that they narrowed the range of realistic. options for closing the deficits. Realistic options were not judged to include, nor was there any support for, proposals to reduce or eliminate benefits for people now on the rolls. Options under consideration involved restraining the growth-of benefits in future years and providing additional financing through some form of revenue increase. Current and future beneficiaries-should be reassu.r.ed by the unanimously held view that social security is an important and vital program that must be preserved. With these accomplishments under our belts, we in Congress are- in a strong position to hammer out the details of legislation in the early months of the 98th Congress. The expiration of interfund borrowing and the likely inability of the retirement program to pay full benefits in July make prompt action essential. Statement (5), Page 3 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 The Financing Problem While the commission report accurately reflects the size of the social security financing problem, perspective may be provided by some additional facts. Most importantly, without prompt Congressional action, the social security retirement program will not be able to pay benefits on time beginning in July. In fact, were it not for "interfund borrowing," authorized by Congress in 1981 to permit the reserves of each social security trust fund (old age and survivors insurance, disability insurance, and hospital insurance) to be used to help pay benefits from another, the retirement program would have stopped meeting its monthly payments on time two months ago. With the authority for interfund borrowing now expired (as of December 31, 1982), July is when all of the money borrowed from the other two trust funds--$17.5 billion in total--fina4lly runs out. Reauthorizing interfund borrowing can not-help the retirement program for long. The retirement program is so large-- accounting for 73 percent of all social security spending--and its borrowing demands are so heavy, the rest of the system could be insolvent before the year is out. The Social Security Board of Trustees, the Congressional Budget office, and a wide variety of private actuaries and economists all agree that additional trust fund revenues must be provided or savings must be achieved if the social security system is to remain solvent through the remainder of this decade. Statement (5), Page 4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 While it is the short-term financing problem that is immediately pressing, the long-term financing problem is equally serious, if not more so. The Social Security Board of Trustees reports that the combination of the baby-boom generation retiring and gradually lengthening lifespans will lead to a dramatic increase in the cost of social security--about 55 percent between 2005 and 2035 alone. In the year 2035, when the young people of today are beginning to retire, the actuaries expect that the elderly population will account for 21 percent of the overall population (as compared to 11 percent today), and the typical 65 year old will have a life expectancy of 17 years (as compared to 14.5 years today). The effect will be to decrease the ratio of taxpayers to beneficiaries from just over 3:1 today to 2:1,. helping to generate the enormous.long-term deficits we now forsee. According to the social security actuaries, the long-term deficit in the non-medicare social security programs is 1.8 percent of taxable payroll. This is the figure adopted by the National Commission. To translate, it means that over the next 75 years, the actuaries project that benefits will outstrip payroll tax income, in dollar terms, by about S25 billion per year, or $2 trillion in total (expressed in 1983 dollar terms). Including medicare, the long-term deficit has been estimated at 7.01 percent of taxable payroll, or nearly $8 trillion in total. Statement (5), Page 5 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 How Much Does the,System Need? How much the system needs in additional financing depends on how we expect the economy to perform in the years ahead and how much of'a "safety margin" is accumulated in reserves. Each set of forecasts provides a.different view of the needs of the* system, as illustrated in the table below. TABLE -- ADDIMNAL RESOURCES REQUIRED IN THE NEAR-TERM TO. BRINGQSDI RESERVES UP TO CERTAIN LEVEL (ti tiioas) Percent of 1 year's expenddures desired at beginning of 1990: 9 perced (1-im) 13 percent 15 t 20 ~t P 30 pawl (6 mo) C80 1992 trustees' intermed+ate (C-8) 19t2 ttastees' pesiaiatie tsssnaptioas 6856.6 .7 62 70 187, 195 743 74 2 16 89J 88 2 .- 120.1 113 246 180.7 M 163 303 -' ioble ncNades the dies of the iu Equity aid acal AMMOO Ad if 1952. Target reserve kvdi are attained in even NOW increments a ceo esiawtes aid irate s' estimates are not &edly rumparable bemuse C80 numbers include added interest on.larter trust fund "m m wbk irostees riuabers do ail The commission settled on $150-$200 billion as the amount required in the years 1983-89 to ensure the solvency of the system through 1990. This is roughly consistent with achieving a reserve ratio (reserves relative to annual outgo) of 15 percent by 1990, under the 1982 Board of Trustees' pessimistic assumptions. Statement (5), page 6 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Several points, are worth noting in this regard. First, planning for a low growth decade is prudent in light of the experience during the 1970s. (The pessimistic assumptions in the 1982 Board of Trustees Report project the economy will perform much like in the past 5 years.) The failure to anticipate, both in 1972 and 1977, that prices would grow more rapidly than wages, and therefore benefits wquld grow more rapidly than tax income, is why we are%in the situation we are in today. Second, a reserve ratio of 15 percent is not, in and of itself, a "goal". At this level, reserves would be lower than at any point in history. Accumulating considerably larger reserves is desirable, although this would be difficult to do very quickly. We believe we express the views of-all members of the commission when we say that it is our hope that the economy will perform better than we assumed when we made our estimates and that a larger reserve cushion will accumulate. Finally, if the medicare program-were under consideration as well, the reserve needs of the system would be considerably higher. Not a New Problem Given the partisan debate that raged over social :.ecurity in 1981, some people may have lost sight of the fact that the financing crisis is- not a new problem. Trust fund reserves have been on a down-hill course for years. As the table below indicates, prior to 1970, there were always reserves on hand Statement (5), Page 7 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 capable of financing a year's worth of benefits or more--that is, reserves equal to 100 percent or more of annual outgo. By 1,976, reserves had fallen to 57,percent of outgo, and today, the combined reserves of the system stand at about 15 percent of annual outgo, only 8-weeks worth of benefits. The situation is even worse, at least today-, when medicare is excluded. TABLE -HISTORICAL OASDHI RESERVE =RATIOS. 1950-83 - [Assets of the begin* mi cub rcu an a peraeat of outgo dwelt the 1'm1 Trost funds Calendar yut 0L and all com1 * 1 1950 1,156. . 1,156 1,156 1955 -405 -405 405 1960 186 180 304 186 1965 -110 109 121 110 1970 103 101 126 47 95 . .1971 99 94 140 54 93 1972 93 88 140 47 87 1973 80 75 125 40 76 1974 73 68 110 69 73 1975 66 63 92 79 69 1976 57 54 71 77 60 1977 47 47 48 66 50 1978 37 39 26 57 40 1979 30 30 30 54 34 1980 25 23 35 52 29 1981 18 18 21 45 23 1982 15- 15 17 53 22 1983 11 8 11 39 16 I Estimated using Tnmrtees' i dermedzte (U-B) assumptions.-- Source: 1922 Wall and lU males' Reportz TABLE -HISTORICAL LEVELS OF OASDHI TRUST FUND ASSETS. NUMBER OF MONTHS' WORTH OF BENEFITS ON HAND Calendar year Number of months ofapa&tures an band n 1950 138.7 138.7 1960 22.3 22.3 1965 13.2 13.2 1970 12.4 16 11.5 1975 .8.0 9.4 8.3 1980 2.9 6.2 3.5 1982 1.8 6.3 2.6 Statement (5), Page S Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Among other public groups to report in the last 5 to 10 years, the social security advisory councils of 1975 and 1979, an expert consultant panel of actuaries and economists, reporting in 1976, and President Carter's Commission on Pension Policy and the National Commission on Social Security, both reporting in 1981, all underscored the seriousness of the short- and long-term financing problem. Social security's financing problem dates to the early 1970s and even earlier, when Congress increased benefits and expanded eligibility without facing up to the cost of doing so. The Time for Action is Now There is no denying that we have a big job ahead of us in Congress. We face many difficult decisions as to the details of the legislation, and the adequacy of the measures proposed. The balance of the long-term deficit will also have to addressed. Ir. our view, a balanced solution to this problem will involve bringing: the cost of social security into line with the ability of our working population to finance the system. The tax burden is already heavy, and the confidence of young people critically low. As reflected in the additional views, a majority of commission members recommends increasing the retirement age, for Statement (5), Page 9 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 people retiring in another 20 or 30 years, as an equitable way of reducing long-range costs. The American people--the 36 million people receiving benefits as well as*the 116 million working people who support the system--deserve more than another "quick fix" that holds the system together until the next crisis comes along. They deserve the speedy consideration of this bi-partisan package of recommendations. Confidence in the long-term viability of social security will only be restored by enacting measures that put the system back on a sound financial footing and do so without imposing an unrealistic tax burden on present and future workers. Within a matter of weeks, the House Ways and Means Committee and the Senate Finance Committee will begin the task of weighing the options and then drafting social security financing legislation. We feel confident that the essential elements of the reform package we now recommend, as endorsed by President Reagan, Speaker O'Neill, Majority Leader Baker and others, will be adopted by the Congress and enacted into lat?; by May. Moving quickly.to shore up the nation's largest domestic program is in all of our interests. Statement (5), Page 10 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Dissenting Views of Congressman Bill Archer to the Report of the National Commission on Social Security Reform It is customary in instances such as this to address one's dissenting views to the body of the main report itself. In this case, however, it is perhaps more appropriate for me to address my comments on the report to my children and future grandchildren and those of their generations who will be most affected by the changes proposed. Should the Commission's pro- posals be enacted into law, it is they who have the most at stake. Unquestionably, great credit is due the President, the Congres- sional leadership and Commission negotiators who were able to arrive at this point where a plan exists to be considered by the Congress. The fact that I personally have strong reservations about the specific plan proposed in no way diminishes my respect for that effort. It is unfortunate that the agreement reached continues to leave in doubt, in my opinion, the future stability of the Social Security system. We have not taken advantage of this rare historic oppor- tunity to do more toward designing greater stability. The pro- posals treat symptoms, not causes. My concern stems from a variety of sources, but primarily from those involving the basic economic and demographic assumptions used to assess the short and long term deficits, and the failure to address adequately the basic structural deficiencies which will continue to cause severe strains on the system in the future. The compromise agreement does not make a specific recommen- dation regarding a portion of the long term need (.58% of payroll), even assuming the accuracy of the projections of the dimensions of the gap it sought to close. That significant element has been left open to Congressional consideration under the terms of the agreement. Neither does the agreement address certain factors influencing the short term need, such as the repayment of loans made to the retire- ment fund by the Health Insurance trust fund. Those revenues will be badly needed as the HI fund becomes deficient in the near future. In fact, the Commission's agreement bears no relationship to the parallel dilemma faced in the health insurance program. Statement (6), Page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Fundamental principles inherent in the basic concept of Social Security have been abrogated by the Commission's recommendations. The large infusion of general revenues into the system makes it self- sustaining no longer. The "earned right" concept which has been basic to the system since it was created has been abridged by a new means test. The concept of Social Security as a floor of protection to supplement other retirement savings has been further eroded by the agreement's perhaps unintended result of encouraging Social Security to be viewed as a sole source retirement system. Certainly there is some good`in the recommendations. The proposal to bring federal employees into the system is a welcome one, but its coverage of only newly hired employees continues an inequity. Ironically, those now in Congress who must vote on the plan are themselves going to continue to be exempt from coverage. So will those presently employed by the federal government who will administer the changes. The plan provides very modest improvement in the treatment of women, but continues major inequities in this area as well as in other areas of the system. There is a brief delay in cost of living increases for present beneficiaries, as a partial attempt to offset benefit increases which resulted in an increase of 52 percent in purchasing power for the average Social Security recipient over the past 15 years. This is essentially the only element of the plan which directly affects those now retired or soon to retire -- except for those retirees who have set aside a portion of their earnings in savings for their retirement. The plan taxes those who have saved for their retirement and imposes a means test for full benefits. Those who do not save are rewarded by the system because of this change. Statement (6), Page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 A Congress which has acted in recent years to encourage indi- vidual retirement savings is now being asked to enact a significant disincentive to retirement savings. There is also a basic flaw in the way the "means test" inherent in the tax on benefits is deter- mined. Individuals with non-Social Security retirement income of $20,000 or more will be taxed on half of all their Social Security benefits. Those with incomes of $19,999.99 or less will not be taxed on any of their benefits. One penny of income could make the difference in whether hundreds of dollars in taxes must be paid. The imposition of a means test, for the first time, destroys the earned right concept fundamental to Social Security and lends a new welfare aspect to its administration. The same is true of the large infusion of general revenues proposed by the plan. The self-financing structure of the Social Security system has been significantly eroded. Of the $168.7 billion in short term deficit reductions in the plan, approximately one-third is represented by direct and indirect infusion of general revenues, which, combined with payroll tax increases accounts for some 75% of the short term deficit reductions. In terms of the long term deficit, new taxes account for even more of the reduction (excluding the portion of the deficit left unresolved by the report). I do not hold the position that the deficit reductions for both the short term and long term should be accomplished without any addi- tional taxes beyond those already scheduled by existing law to go into effect. I am concerned, however, about a recommended proposal which includes such an imbalance of dependence upon new revenues (taxes and general Treasury funds) relative to structural changes which would restrain the growth of spending outlays. I question the ability of our tax base in the future to support this enormous projected growth. Structural changes are critical to the long term stability of the system. The report leaves unanswered the question of what bene- fit level our economy can afford in the next century and what those in the work force at that time will be able to pay. Statement (6), Page 3 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 What we should be providing here is a basis for realistic expectations for future Social Security recipients against which they can determine their own needs for retirement security beyond what the system may provide them at that time. There is great danger that these proposals have made promises which the system will not be able to support. Changes which would more directly relate taxes paid into the system to benefits received are the type of structural changes which would lend greater credibility to Social Security. The Commission recommendations continue present inequities instead. An individual with a short covered employment history continues to be treated more favorably than his counterpart with the same average income who has a longer covered employment history. Another important consideration the agreement does not address adequately is that of demographic changes, increased life expectancy and improvements in the physical and mental ability of individuals to continue to work. There is no direct recommendation by the Commission that the age of retirement be adjusted to take such changes into account. Nor is there adequate attention given to revision of automatic cost of living increases relative to the taxes which support them. In regard to taxes imposed by the compromise, the use of a refundable tax credit (a concept which has been rejected repeatedly by Congress) ruptures the fundamental parity between employer and employee. The 33% increase in the OASDI tax rate on the self-employed is too great a burden for those who are already operating at the margin because of difficult economic conditions. In summary, the recommendations proposed by the National Commission on Social Security Reform, in my judgement, leave the system's future very much in doubt. We are again addressing the symptomatic deficits facing Social Security, rather than taking advantage of this opportunity to address the causes of the problems themselves. Statement (6), Page 4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 We have postponed once again the day of reckoning by tranferring the burden of supporting the system's shortcomings to future genera- tions. Social Security represents the single most important commitment to the elderly made by our society. It is a great testimony to our nation's dedication to assuring retirement security for our elderly of all generations. The question facing Congress as we begin consideration of the Commission's recommendations is whether this particular plan exactly fulfills that commitment as completely as it must. I clearly have misgivings that it does. As the legislative process begins, there remains an opportunity for the thoughtful concerns of others who share those misgivings to strengthen the product which is ultimately enacted. My own greatest hope is that my strong desire to guarantee the solvency of Social Security into the future can be matched by a confidence that the solution accomplishes that goal. Statement (6), Page 5 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 VIEWS OF SENATOR WILLIAM L. ARMSTRONG Since 1971 maximum Social Security tax rates have quadrupled. These rates are scheduled to triple again in the 1980s as a result of legislation already on the books.l/ During the approximately same period of time, from 1970-1981, the "real" pay of working men and women fell hile Social Security benefits went up about 50% faster than the cost of living .2 Now the National Commission on Social Security Reform is recommending new taxes as well as acceleration of tax increases already scheduled. Can such increases be justified? I do not think so. The vast majority of workers, small business men and women and retirees are not likely to think so either. I expect there will be howls of outrage when Middle America discovers what the National Commission has recommended and some political leaders have already endorsed. Hopefully, grass roots lobbying will be sufficient to convince Congress to amend the Commission's plan to make it more workable, fairer, and more sound economically. If such amendments are ignored, Congress will be repeating the same basic mistake made in 1977. At that time, legislation was enacted which purported to shore up the financial solvency of the Social Security trust funds for the rest of our lives. But instead of focusing on basic systemic difficulties of the trust funds -- especially the growing ratio of retirees to taxpaying workers and benefit increases far outstripping the cost of living -- Congress concocted the largest tax increase in history. A few of us objected. But the majority of Congress went along, and President Carter hailed passage "as the guarantee that from 1980 to 2030 Social Security funds will be sound." I didn't quite work out that way. Social Security is again running out of money. By midyear, unless Congress intervenes, the trust fund will be unable to meet its obligations. The National Commission on Social Security Reform estimates a funding gap of $150-$200 billion between now and the end of the decade and a long-term deficit of 1.8 percent of payroll -- approximately $1.6 trillion. Even these gloomy prospects may prove too optimistic. And once again the recommended solution is to raise taxes. Taxes paid by "average" workers rose 259% from 1970 to 1980; they are projected to rise another 246% this decade. 2/ From 1970 to 1981, pretax wages increased 122%; the Consumer Price Index rose 136%; Social Security benefits (OASDI) went up 205%. Statement (7), page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 On January 15, after a series of marathon negotiating sessions, and with the approval of President Reagan and House Speaker O'Neill, the National Commission recommended legislation. Unfortunately, the Commission suggested closing the gap primarily through new taxes. But even with the recommended tax increases, the plan fails to raise enough money to put Social Security back in the black. It also avoids the permanent structural changes necessary to restore public confidence in the solvency and fairness of Social Security. Moreover, the Commission's recommendations violate several basic principles on which the Social Security system has previously rested. Consider these facts about the Commission recommendation: Including revenue from expanded coverage, higher taxes account for 75 percent of the proposed deficit reduction between now and 1990 -- $126 billion out of the $169 billion total. In the long run, the balance is even more lopsided. Tax increases constitute 91 percent of the Commission's total recommendation. Such tax increases raise serious questions of economic impact. The first payroll tax hike in the Commission's plan will cut paychecks in 1984. Will the higher employment tax dampen the recovery? Will additional joblessness result? I think most economists would agree that higher payroll taxes are bound to have these undesirable effects. Worse yet, the Commission's recommendations do not close the projected gap between revenues and outlays in the trust funds, which totals several trillion dollars: $1.6 trillion is the discounted present value of the deficit. Faced with actuarial estimates of a deficit of 1.8 percent of payroll, the Commission recommends measures solve only about two-thirds of the problem. Still more taxes have already been proposed to cope with the remaining .58 percent payroll deficit that the Commission left dangling. It would not have been necessary to leave the long-term funding issue unsettled had the Commission been willing to recommend modest changes in the age of normal retirement. Previous advisory groups have suggested a variety of gradual changes such as increasing the retirement age by one month each year for the next 36 years or, possibly, even waiting to start such a phasing process five or 10 years from now. The approach I favor is to gradually increase the normal retirement threshold to age 66 with a phase-in period starting after the turn of the century; thereafter, the retirement age would be automatically indexed to changes in longevity. Such a proposal would apply only to persons fully able to work and would not preclude early retirement for those entitled to disability. Incredibly, this single, gradual change, which was ignored by the National Commission, would be sufficient to fulfill the entire long-term funding problem of Social Security, according to the actuaries. Finally, the Commission may have erred in overturning at least three basic principles on which Social Security has long rested: taxation of benefits, the Statement (7), page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 parity of treatment between employers and employees, and general fund financing. These conventions are deeply ingrained in the Social Security system and can only be abandoned at substantial risk of losing public support for the system itself. In my opinion, the present circumstances do not justify doing so. There are other flaws in the Commission recommendations and, to be fair, a number of good points as well. Overall, however, I cannot escape the conclusion that the plan needs much improving. Whether this will happen remains to be seen. At least one White House insider is freely predicting quick legislation approval with few, if any, changes. He points out that a lot of "heavyweights" are already backing the package. He could be right. He may be wrong. There are also some heavyweights who are convinced the package must be amended in order to make it fairer and more financially sound. Among those who insist on amendments and oppose the plan in its present form are the 13 million-member American Association of Retired Persons and the largest association for small businesses -- who will feel the most impact of the plan -- the National Federation of Independent Business. If these and other citizen groups will energize their memberships to protest the Commission's plan and work to develop an alternative package, there is reason to hope amendments can be adopted that will significantly improve the final legislation. As this issue develops, I expect strong support from employees and from business men and women. They have important economic interest at stake. However, I am increasingly convinced that support will also be forthcoming from retirees and the elderly. Based on many conversations with senior citizens, I doubt they will take a narrow or selfish view. They have much more at stake than merely their personal well-being. They are also concerned about their children and grandchildren. The last thing they wish is to leave a heritage of economic wreckage or an unfair retirement system. The Commission's Major Accomplishment -- And Some Objections The most important single achievement of the Commission, under the patient, considerate, and scholarly leadership of Chairman Greenspan, has been to marshall a consensus for admitting the problem. Some of those who now hail the recommendations were quite recently claiming no changes were needed. They said, in effect ..don't let them touch Social Security...all this talk about reform is just a plot to wreck Social Security...." As the Washington Post pointed out, "The first step toward solving any problem is to get people to admit the problem exists. The National Commission on Social Security Reform, meeting this week in Washington, has already made a huge contribution by getting its members of different political persuasions to Statement (7), page 3 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 agree that Social Security's problems are real, urgent, and -- within reason -- measureable." A number of the Commission's recommendations make sense to me. On balance, however, in its present form, the plan falls short of the kind of balance program needed to restore public confidence in the solvency and fairness of the system. The plan: ? Does not meet the minimum long-term need of 1.8% of payroll, but leaves needed reforms open for further consideration; ? Settles the short-term problem at the low end of projected need; ? Tax benefits for the first time; ? Will create a severe "notch" between Social Security recipients whose adjusted gross income is just above and those just below the arbitrary point at which benefits are to be taxed; the result is unfair and will be so perceived; ? Grants refundable tax credits to employees, thereby upsetting the historic parity between employees and employers; ? Provides permanent general fund financing; ? Prohibits withdrawal of State and local government units, a legislative solution which may be subject to successful challenge on constitutional grounds; ? Avoids decision on changing the normal retirement age, considered by many experts and earlier advisory groups as essential to the long-term stability of Social Security; ? Including revenue derived from expanded coverage, increased taxes account for 75% of deficit reductions; (63% if expanded coverage is excluded); ? In the long term, excluding the portion (.58% of taxable payroll) left unresolved and including revenues from expanded coverage, new taxes account for 91% of deficit reduction (not including revenues from expanded coverage, Congress Must Act Promptly The need for congressional action is immediate. Statement (7), page 4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 ? Every single minute of every hour of every day, on the average, OASDI pays out $17,000 more than it takes in. ? Present reserves in the retirement system will be insufficient to fully meet benefit payments by mid-1983, unless Congress enacts corrective legislation. ? In 1950, there were 16 workers paying Social Security taxes for each beneficiary. Today there are just three workers per beneficiary. By 2025, there may be only two workers per beneficiary. The result? A steeply rising burden on workers whose Social Security taxes keep the trust funds solvent. ? A fourth of U.S. taxpayers are paying more in Social Security taxes than in federal income taxes, and sharply higher tax rates are scheduled to support projected benefits. ? Polls show Americans are losing faith in the Social Security system. Fifty-four percent of those surveyed by CBS/New York Times doubt that Social Security will have money to pay en6 efit in the future. How does Congress begin the important work of enacting a fair retirement system? I suggest adopting five principles to guide its work: 1. Current basic level of benefits on which so many persons depend, must not be reduced. 2. Needed changes -- whether in future rates of benefit increases, retirement ages, eligibility standards, etc., should be made gradually, not in a drastic or abrupt manner. 3. Economic projections, on which the system is based, should be conservative -- in short, we should hope for the best, but plan for less optimistic economic conditions. 4. Permanent solvency must be achieved. Stopgap solutions are not satisfactory. 5. Public confidence must be restored. The politics of fear -- which has surrounded past Social Security decision-making -- must end. No solutions are easy, but we are in firm agreement on the goal: Our elderly must feel assured of our good faith, and Social Security must be restored and maintained as a valuable bond between generation and generation. Statement (7), page 5 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Toward that end, it is important that everyone know the basic facts of Social Security...how it began, how it grew, who it affects, what its future will be. Social Security Highlights ? One trillion dollars will be paid out in Social Security benefits the next four years. ? Thirty-six million Americans receive Social Security benefits. ? Most Social Security retirees today receive more in benefits than they paid in taxes -- by a ratio of 5 to 1. ? Social Security benefits have risen sharply over the past few years. In the beginning, Social Security was designed to be supplemental retirement income. Today, Social Security benefits on average equal 60% of their after-tax working income. ? In recent years, Social Security benefits have increased faster than increases in wages or prices. ? Americans are living longer. Women becoming 65 in 1982 live, on average, an additional 19 years; men live an additional 15 years. This is a 20% increase in 40 years. ? Social Security comprises one-fourth of the total federal budget and 5% of the Gross National Product. ? The maximum Social Security tax an employee working from 1935 to 1982 could make is $17,000. This will nearly triple to $44,000 by 1990, just seven years. ? Social Security taxes for the average worker have increased 2,000% since 1935; the maximum Social Security tax has increased 6,500%. ? Fifty-one percent of all Americans pay more in Social Security taxes than federal income taxes. ? Even with the additional $437 billion in tax increases that will be implemented this decade because of a 1977 law, Social Security will exhaust its reserves and total outgo will exceed income by the mid-1980s, unless Congress takes decisive action. ? When Social Security began, only retirement benefits were paid to workers. Today, there are about 21 general types of benefits provided under Social Security. Statement (7), page 6 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 ? One indication of the growth in Social Security: When President Franklin Roosevelt proposed his Social Security program in 1935, he contemplated Social Security expenditures would be about $1.3 billion in 1980. Actual 1980 outlays: $149 billion. ? In designing his Social Security retirement program, President Roosevelt rejected the use of general revenues, wanting instead for the program to pay for itself through separate financing. ? The National Commission on Social Security Reform identified more than 80 options for restructuring Social Security financing to achieve short- and long-term solvency. One example of potential savings through gradual changes in Social Security: delaying the full cost-of-living increase two months for three years will save $40 to $60 billion this decade alone. Statement (7), page 7 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Social Security... .. In the Beginning Social Security was created in 1935 to partially replace earnings lost through retirement or death. Initially, only commerce and industry workers (about five out of 10 jobs in America) over age 65 were eligible for benefits. Benefits were supplemental income-about 29% of pre-retirement income (known as the "replacement rate" ...the percent of working income replaced by retirement income). Payroll taxes financed these benefits on a pay-as-you-go basis. Iritial taxes were also small ...$60 per worker maximum (cost split between employer and employee). In 1980 dollars, this tax equalled $360. ..Program Expansion Congress and Presidents dramatically expanded the program through 13 expansionary laws and seven automatic benefit increases (although twice Congress slightly reduced benefits). Today, three separate trust funds pay benefits and collect taxes. Two trust funds -- Old Age and Survivors (OASI) and Disability (DI) -- pay cash benefits directly to recipients. The third -- Hospitalization (HI) -- pays costs of medical care provided to the elderly and disabled. Nine out of 10 jobs in America are included in Social Security. The program now pays retirement, early retirement, widow, children, parent, disability and hospitalization benefits to 35.4 million. Basic benefit rules were expanded, and later made inflation-proof through automatic cost-of-living increases. Generally, eligibility has been liberalized. Cash benefits -- not counting the value of hospital care -- as a percent of pre-retirement income has increased to 49.3%. Consequently, the tax rate, tax base and number of taxpayers have also increased. Today, the combined employee-employer maximum tax is $4,340. One hundred ten million workers pay taxes; 11 million (mostly government employees) do not. While the number of taxpayers has increased, the worker/recipient ratio has not. In 1940, there were 16 workers supporting each recipient. Today, the ratio is only 3 to 1, and declining. ..As Part of the Federal Budget Total Social Security outlays comprise about one-quarter of the budget. Including all programs, 27.7% of the federal budget is devoted to elderly needs. By 1985, pensions, national defense and interest payments will comprise 75% of the U.S. budget. Total Social Security and other senior citizen federal outlays amount to $15,000 per elderly couple. -Statement (7), page 8 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 ..As Part of the National Economy Benefits comprise about 5% of the real gross national product, and it's rising. If no changes are made, and if government spending were to be maintained at 20% of GNP, then by 1985 other government spending must be cut 13.1%. Since Social Security is a major component of the economy, it is particularly sensitive to economic fluctuation. Each 1% of inflation increases costs $1.5 billion annually (although the higher costs are offset in part by higher revenues). Each 1% of unemployment reduces revenues by $2 billion. Social Security tax increases exacerbate unemploy- ment. For example, the Congressional Budget Office projected that the Social Security tax increases since 1977 reduced employment by 500,000 jobs. Accelerating to 1983 the tax increase scheduled for 1990 is projected to increase unemployment two to four million job years by the end of the decade. .Economic and Demographic Developments Since Social Security began, significant changes have reshaped America. Once an economy dominated by manufacturing and agriculture, America is quickly becoming a service based economy. Once men dominated the work force; now half of all jobs are held by women. In 1935, a third of all elderly Americans were impoverished; today less than 15% have incomes below the poverty threshold. Forty years ago, less than three marriages in 10 ended in divorce; today five of 10 marriages end in divorce. Family size has declined. Americans are living longer; on average, men live 15 years past retirement, and women 19 years ...a lifespan increase of 20% over 40 years. Even so, more Americans are opting for early retirement before age 65. Today 90% of Americans who retire opt for retirement before age 65. .As Part of the Lives of Recipients Social Security is a financial lifeline to most recipients. Fifty percent of benefits are paid to elderly single members of households for whom Social Security is their principal income. Median income for all those over 65 is $ 5,771. Average median income for a retired couple receiving Social Security is $14,300. Newly eligible retirees -- 80% of whom opt for early retirement -- generally are improved financially. Median retirement income is $14,259, of which 42% is Social Security. Gross family assets -- including personal residences or automobiles -- exceed $48,000. Seventy percent of new retirees either outright own their home, or pay less than $200 in monthly mortgage or rent. The average value of a new retiree's home is $54,000. Most Social Security recipients today will receive far more in benefits than they contributed in taxes... by a ratio of 5 to 1. This ratio will decline for future recipients. Social Security benefits are progressive... meaning that low-income receive relatively higher benefits than middle- or high-income. Statement (7), page 9 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 .As Part of the Lives of Workers The maximum Social Security tax a worker and his employer could have paid from 1937 to 1982 is $16,932. This will nearly triple by 1990 when the maximum tax possible rises to $43,000. For 51% of all families -- and practically all low-income families -- they pay more Social Security taxes than federal income tax. This is also true for employers, particularly the marginally profitable. One trillion dollars will be spent from the Social Security trust funds in the next four years (1983 to 1986), an amount roughly equal to that spent from 1935 to 1981. Four-year spending and income by trust funds: (billions) Outlays Income Old Age and Survivors (OASI) $728 $634 Disability (DI) 83 135 Hospitalization (HI) 198 210 $1009 $979 --Social Security Administration September 1982 Monthly Social Security costs exceed $17.9 billion. Of trust fund outlays... ...67% go to retirees, their spouses, children or survivors. ...9% go to the disabled, their spouses, children or survivors. ...22% pay medical costs. Cash benefits paid from the OASI and DI trust funds: (millions) Average annual benefit Retired workers 20.3 $4,686 Their spouses 3.0 2,350 Their children .5 1,841 Total 23.8 Survivors Widowed parents .5 3,372 Widowed spouses 4.4 4,210 Children .2 3,278 Disabled, widowed spouses .1 2,760 Parents .01 3,732 Total 5.21 Disabled workers 4.1 4,944 Their spouses .4 1,452 Their children 1.0 1,428 Total 5.5 .1 Statement (7), page 10 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 The maximum possible benefit for a retired couple with children under 18 is $14,748 annually. These benefits do not include the value of medical benefits provided through Medicare. Since all benefits are tax free, current benefits are about 60% of after-tax, pre-retirement income. .Taxes About $1 trillion in taxes has been raised since 1935. If a worker contributed the maximum taxes from 1937 to 1982, he would have contributed $17,000 (an amount matched by his employer). By 1990, this will nearly triple to $44,600. Today, the total Social Security tax is 13.4% of up to $32,400 of income. This rate will increase to 15.3%, and the base up to $45,600 of income by 1990. The average tax paid by a worker and his employer annually is about $2,000. ...Individual Equity and Social Adequacy Social Security emphasizes social adequacy, not individual equity. The social adequacy basis is evident through the provision of relatively high minimum benefits, paying proportionately higher benefits to low average wage earners, the imposition of maximum benefits regardless of past earnings, and the payment of derivative benefits at no additional cost to the worker. While there are some elements of individual equity -- benefits in relation to earnings -- Social Security, over the years, has moved away from individual equity and more toward social adequacy. .As It Affects Women Social Security was created when men dominated the work force. Since then, a number of economic and demographic changes involving women affect Social Security and its future. More women work today, are living longer, and the divorce rate is increasing. Since these changes were not contemplated at the time Social Security was created, retirement benefit adequacy for women is a significant concern because a high percentage of the elderly poor are widowed, divorced or were never married. It is also a concern since the current labor force -- once male dominated -- has a high percent of women workers who pay Social Security taxes, and expect to receive just benefits. Problems in providing benefits to women exist in part because benefits are linked to an individual's earnings and work history. Working women frequently have interrupted work histories due to child rearing. Women also have had generally lower career earnings than men. As a result, a large proportion of women fail to qualify for Social Security benefits, qualify for benefits on their lower earnings, or they qualify based on their husband's benefits, and then receive half of these benefits. Some of these concerns have been addressed by changes made in the computation of spouse benefits, but questions of equity continue to be raised with regard to women, particularly those who work. The National Commission on Social Security Reform identified 12 options that address the issue of making Social Security equitable for women. Statement (7), page 11 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 .and Other Federal Pension Policies Since Social Security was created, there have been significant developments in federal pension policy. Among them: 1. Individual Retirement Accounts: Most workers can contribute up to $2000 annually tax free into Individual Retirement Accounts, the proceeds of which are invested, and then paid out as retirement income as early as age 59 1/2. Workers with wives who do not work contribute up to $2,275 annually. 2. Keogh retirement plans: The self-employed can set aside $15,000 annually to help replace earnings lost through retirement. 3. Employee Retirement Income Security Act: Regulates company sponsored, tax-deferred pension plans. Sixty percent of workers between age 25-34 are covered by retirement pensions other than Social Security. .Financial Status Social Security is going broke. High inflation, slow economic growth, rising numbers of beneficiaries, increased benefit levels and an eroding tax base have increased Social Security's costs, and depressed revenues. The retirement and survivors trust fund has run a de'icit since the early 1970's. This deficit erased the once large cash reserves...to the point where Congress had to enact legislation permitting the OASI trust fund to borrow from the DI and HI trust fund to make full and timely benefits. By the mid-1980s, however, even these reserves will be exhausted. Technically, Social Security will have no choice but to either reduce all benefits by the amount of income then on hand, or delay checks until enough income is on hand to pay full benefits. Thus, Congress must achieve two goals in the short-term: Enact legislation that eliminates the future deficits, and achieve adequate reserves so that enough money is on hand to pay two months of benefits. The National Commission on Social Security Reform unanimously agreed that $150-200 billion is needed this decade to assure Social Security solvency. In addition, the Commission projects that Social Security needs to either increase revenues or reduce spending $1.6 trillion over the next 75 years to guarantee solvency. Statement (7)p page 12 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Social Security... Explained To make changes necessary to insure solvency in Social Security first requires understanding its current benefit and tax structure. A. Coverage Originally, Social Security only provided benefits to those age 65 and over working in commercial and industrial employment. Only five out of 10 jobs in America were covered. Since then, Congress expanded Social Security to cover about nine out of every 10 jobs. Coverage was extended to most self-employed, hired farm and domestic workers, armed forces, and professionals. Optional coverage was provided clergymen. State and local governments and non-profit organizations can opt for Social Security coverage. Both state and local governments and non-profit organizations, if they elect Social Security coverage, can later elect to opt-out of Social Security. For certain military personnel, the armed forces pays Social Security taxes up to a maximum of $1,200 (representing the cash value of non-taxable income). This contribution is not matched by the servicemen. Work not covered by Social Security is federal civilian employment, non-covered state and local governments (30% are'not covered), and non-covered, non-profit organizations (about 15% are not covered). Statement (7), page 13 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 B. The Benefit Structure --- Retirement and Survivors Benefits -- OASI Four principal components comprise the Social Security benefit structure... eligibility, computing initial benefits, annual benefit increases and types of benefits. 1. Eligibility To be eligible a worker must be "insured" through earning "quarters of coverage." Some explanation... Becoming "fully insured" means working in a Social Security covered job (and thus paying Social Security taxes) and earning at least $340 in a calendar quarter. Doing so entitles a worker to a quarter of coverage. A worker receives one quarter for each $340 up to a maximum of four quarters. With 31 quarters -- as little as eight years work -- a worker and his family is entitled to full Social Security benefits based on his earnings. The number of quarters required will increase one quarter for each year until a maximum of 40 quarters is reached. "Currently insured status" applies only to a worker dying before retirement. A worker becomes currently insured -- and thus eligible for benefits -- by attaining six quarters in the 13 quarters preceding death. Of course, a worker does not automatically receive benefits when he becomes insured. A condition for receiving OASI benefits is reaching retirement age or death. Full benefits are paid at age 65; lesser benefits at age 62. Age eligibility varies for other OASI benefits... and are described in Part C. 2. Calculating Initial Benefit Levels Benefit levels for retired and disabled workers, dependents and survivors are generally related to the past earnings of the covered worker, and more directly to a percent of the benefits that the covered worker will receive. There are four basic steps used in most cases to compute a worker's Social Security benefit: a. "Computation Years".. .That is, the years worked in Social Security employment between age 21 and the year of death, disability, or the attainment of age 62, then drop out the five lowest income years. b. "Index Earnings".. .The earnings of each year are converted, or indexed, into more recent levels by increasing them to reflect changes in wage levels since the time they were actually earned. Indexing creates an earnings record that reflects the value of the individual's earnings relative to national average earnings in the indexing year. The indexing year is the second year before the year in which the worker attains age 62 (in other words, age 60), becomes disabled or dies. Earnings after the indexing year are counted at their current value (not indexed). Earnings are indexed by increasing the actual earnings in each year after 1950 by the percentage increase in national average wages between that year and the indexing year. Statement (7), page 14 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 c. "Average Indexed Monthly Earnings" (AIME)...These indexed earnings are then averaged to a monthly amount... known as the AIME. Simply divide total indexed earnings by the number of months in the computation years. d. "Primary Insurance Amount" (PIA)...A percentage formula is applied to the AIME to derive the primary insurance amount, or basic benefit level. The 1982 formula is: 90% of the first $230 of AIME, plus 32% of AIME over $230, but less than $1,388, plus 15% of AIME over $1,388 An example follows: A worker retires at age 62 in 1982, and had earned $2,900 in 1960. The $2,900 would be multiplied by the ratio of average annual wages in 1980 ($12,513), and divided by average annual wages in 1960 ($4,077): $2,900 x_$12,513 = $9,056 $4,077 Although the worker's actual earnings for 1960 were $2,900... his wage indexed earnings would be $9,056. This calculation is applied to each year between 1951 and 1980 (the second year prior to his attaining age 62). Once total indexed earnings are obtained, they are divided by the number of months in the computation years. This monthly amount is the AIME. Let's assume that after this worker's entire wage record is indexed, his AIME is $420. Let's run benefit formula: this through the PIA 90% of the first $230 = $207.00 32% of amount above $230 = 60.80 Total PII: 267.80 His PIA is $267.80. This is the amount he would receive at age 65. Since he opted for early retirement at age 62, he receives 80% of that total...or $214.00. Statement.(7), page 15 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 3. Types of Benefits As already mentioned, benefit levels for retired and disabled workers, dependents and survivors are generally related to the past earnings of the covered worker, and more directly to a percent of the benefits -- or the primary insurance amount -- that the covered worker will receive. Below is a list of benefits provided through OASI, and the percent of PIA each receives: 1. Full retirement: 100% of PIA/eligible at age 65/eligible for reduced benefits at age 62. 2. Widowed spouses: 100% of PIA/eligible at age 65/eligible for reduced benefits at age 60. 3. Spouses: 50% of PIA/eligible at age 65, or younger if caring for a disabled child, or a child under age 16/eligible for reduced benefits at age 62. 4. Divorced spouses: 50% of PIA/same eligiblity for spouses, but must have been married at least 10 years. 5. Children: 50% of PIA/eligible until 18 if child of a retired or deceased insured worker, or until 19 if still in high school. College benefits to age 21 will be phased out by 1985. 6. Surviving children: 75% of PIA/eligibility same as 5. 7. Parents: 75% of PIA/eligible if surviving spouse caring for a child under 16 at time of death. 8. Maximum Family Benefits: 188% of PIA (175% of PIA for high income earners) if total benefits to a family exceed 188% of PIA (or 175%) then all benefits for family members is reduced by an amount to bring all benefits under the 188/175% caps. 9. Lump Sum Death Benefit: Not a percent of PIA... just a $255 payment on the death of a worker. Paid to survivors. 10. Transitionally insured benefits: Not a percent of PIA... is paid to those over age 65 with insufficient quarters of coverage. 11. Special age 72: Not a percent of PIA... paid to those over 82 with insufficient quarters of coverage to qualify for a retired worker benefit and who do not receive public assistance. 12. Special minimum: Not a percent of PIA... increases benefits for workers with low average earnings. 13. Retroactive: For persons over age 65, retroactive benefits can be paid up to six months. For disabled beneficiaries, benefits can be paid retroactively up to 12 months. 14. Currently Insured: OASDI benefits paid to survivors of workers not fully insured but who worked at least six of the 13 quarters preceding death. Statement (7), page 16 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 4. Annual Cost-of-Living Adjustments All benefit levels are increased each year when the Consumer Price Index exceeds 3% increase each year, and when it does, the full CPI increase -- not just the amount above 3% -- is applied to benefit levels automatically without action by Congress. 5. The Retirement Test Under current law, all benefits are reduced when a beneficiary's earnings record exceeds certain levels. This is called the earnings test, or retirement test, and applies to beneficiaries until they reach age 72 (in 1983 and later, the retirement test will not apply after age 70). The amount of annual earnings permitted in 1982 without causing a benefit reduction is $4,440 for persons under age 65, $6,000 for persons age 65-72. Each $2 of earnings in excess of these amounts reduces annual benefits by $1. 6. Policy Summary These five sections summarize the mechanics of the benefit and eligibility rules. But what is the overall effect of this formula, and what are the policy implications? Several aspects should be mentioned: First, only minimum requirements are imposed to become eligible for Social Security. The fact that eligibility is so easy to attain is the reason why there are so many who receive more than one federal pension... the so-called "double-dippers" who receive "windfall" benefits. Second, the entire benefit structure heavily favors those with low average earnings. This does not necessarily mean the low income... it means those with sporadic work histories, those who often shift between covered and non-covered Social Security employment, go through periods of unemployment. It achieves this effect through three ways... the low minimum eligibility requirements, dropping out of the computation years the five lowest income producing years, and heavily weighting the PIA formula to the low-income. Third, wage indexing provides retirees with a significant though usually not noticed added benefit: By basing retirement benefits on real wage increases, it permits retirees to share in retirement the overall productivity growth achieved by workers. Fourth, wage indexing, coupled with drop-out years and automatic cost-of-living increases for all benefits, is achieving a remarkable effect. This formula increases real benefits paid to new beneficiaries each year. For example, those who retire in the year 2040 will receive double the current value of benefits paid to those retiring this year. Statement (7), page 17 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Fifth, replacement rates -- the percent of working income replaced by retirement income -- have increased sharply. When Social Security began, the average replacement rate was about 29%. Today, the average is 49% for all beneficiaries. That is for pre-tax income. The replacement rate today for after-tax income is closer to 60%...meaning that in retirement a worker will receive 60% of his pre-retirement income. Incredible though it may seem, a worker with low average earnings in his lifetime who retired in 1981 will in retirement earn more in Social Security benefits than he earned while working. Because of legislation enacted in 1977, these high replacement rates will gradually decline somewhat. Replacement rates have increased primarily because of legislative and automatic benefit increases. Cost of living increases the past decade have been generous. From 1970 to 1981, pre-tax wages went up 122%; the CPI increased 136%; Social Security benefits have increased 205%. 7. Program Growth Since Social Security Began Although the number of benefits has vastly increased and the requirements determining insured status have been liberalized, the basic notion of insured status has not changed since Social Security began. In 1940, three requirements had to be met before a worker or his family received benefits: The worker had to be industrially or commercially employed, earning at least $50 ($568 in 1982 dollar) in at least six calendar quarters, and be over age 65. Since then, almost all age requirements for benefit eligibility have been reduced, types of benefits expanded. Benefits are now increased automatically each year. Statement (7), page 18 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 C. Benefit Structure -- Disability Insurance (DI) Social Security disability began in 1956, and operates on the same insured status concept used by OASI. To be eligible for disability, a worker must be both fully insured under OASI, as described in Section II-A, and disability insured. To be disability insured, the worker must have 20 quarters of coverage in the 40 quarters immediately preceding disability. Generally, disability is defined as the inability to engage in gainful activity by reason of any medically determinable physical or mental impairment that can be expected to result in death, or last at least 12 continuous months. Before benefits can be paid, a waiting period must lapse of at least five months, benefits are paid up to age 65, and then regular full retirement benefits are paid, and benefits can be paid retroactively up to 12 months. A worker disabled in the line of work need not file for worker's compensation. Disability benefits are offset by all other disability benefits, with the exception of veterans disability benefits. Currently, Social Security and the states are reviewing all disability cases, and terminating benefits to those who never were or no longer are eligible. Benefits are being denied in about 50% of all cases, but are restored on appeal to administrative law judges about 64% of the time. Appeal takes six months or longer, and benefits are paid for only 60 days during that time. 1. Disabled worker: 100% of PIA/eligible 5 months after disability 2. Disabled surviving spouse: 100% of PIA/eligible at age 60/eligible for reduced benefits at age 50 3. Disabled child: 50% of PIA/eligibility begins at age 18 4. Disabled surviving child: 75% of PIA/eligibility begins at 18 5. Retroactive: up to 12 months Only benefits for disabled workers (and their dependents) are paid out of the DI trust fund. Benefits #2 - #4 are simply the dependents and survivors benefits paid out of the OASI trust fund. Statement (7), page 19 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 D. The Benefit Structure -- Hospitalization Insurance/Medicare (HI) Created in 1965, Medicare is a national health insurance program for the aged and certain disabled persons. Almost all citizens over age 65 are automatically entitled to Medicare coverage. If they are not, they can purchase the coverage for an annual premium of $1,360. Medicare has two parts: Part A, hospital insurance, pays hospital, post-hospital and home health services. This program is financed through Social Security payroll taxes. Part B, supplementary medical insurance, is a voluntary program, financed through individual medical premiums, and through general revenues. Elderly beneficiaries pay one-quarter of the costs (about $150 a year with a $75 deductible), the disabled pay one-seventh, and the federal government pays the difference. Services and fees vary between the two programs. PART A: During each benefit period -- whenever a patient has not been in a hospital for 60 consecutive days, Medicare Part A pays for the following services: Inpatient Hospital Care: Ninety days of coverage. For the first 60 days, all costs are paid, except for the first $304 deductible. For the last 30 days, Medicare pays for all but $76/daily in covered costs. After that, patients can draw upon a lifetime reserve of 60 hospital days. For reserve days, all costs after the first $152 each day are paid. Nursing Facility Care: One hundred days of coverage are paid for. The first 20 days of care are free for the patient. After that, all patients pay $38 each day, and the rest of the cost is paid by Medicare. Home Health Care: Medically necessary home health care visits by nurses, therapists and other health workers are paid for by Medicare. There is no limit to the number of benefit periods a patient can Institutions are reimbursed for their reasonable costs incurred in providing services to Medicare patients. Reasonable costs are determined by law and regulation. Services and costs are reviewed by Professional Standards Review Organizations. Medicare is administered by the Health Care Financing Administration which, in turn, contracts much of the operational work to private sector intermediaries. PART B: During any calendar year, Part B pays 80% of reasonable charges for services rendered by doctors, osteopaths, chiropractors, psychiatrists, independent therapists. Most medical services and outpatient and laboratory services are covered. Statement (7), page 20 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 E. Administration Administration costs in 1981 were $1.7 billion or 1.2% OASDI benefit payments or 1.3% of revenues. Retirement and survivors insurance is largely administered by the federal government, with disability insurance administered by the states. F. Taxes In 1982, the combined employer-employee tax rate is 13.40% on earnings up to $32,400. The maximum tax today is $4,342. Self-employed pay 150% of the employee's share of the tax. In 1977, Congress enacted legislation that significantly increased taxes during the rest of this decade. By 1990, the tax rate will increase three times, to 15.3%, and the tax base seven times. The total maximum tax paid in 1990 will exceed $9,400. The 1977 law will pump another $437 billion in additional taxes into the Social Security Trust Fund. Under current law, Social Security benefits are tax free. Social Security only taxes payroll, and no other tax revenues flow into the Social Security trust funds. G. Social Security Tax, Benefit, Trust Fund, Chronology, Charts, Tables and Graphs The following pages contain selected tables highlighting key aspects of Social Security. Statement (7), page 21 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 IV. References/Recommended Reading Sources: Social Security Administration, General Accounting Office, Congressional Budget Office, Office of Management and Budget, Congressional Research Service, House Ways and Means Committee, Senate Finance Committee, Senate Select Committee on Aging, selected books and publications. For those interested in further reading, perhaps the five best references about the past, present and future of Social Security are: Policymaking for Social Security --Martha Derthick The Brookings Institute Developments in Aging: 1981: Volume 1 --Senator John Heinz, Chairman Senate Select Committee on Aging Social Security --Robert J. Myers McCahan Foundation Book Series Major Federal Expenditures in Jurisdiction of the Senate Finance Committee --Senator Robert Dole, Chairman Senate Finance Committee Social Security: The Need For Action --Robert Beck, Chief Executive Officer Prudential Life Insurance Company Statement.(7), page 22 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 ODD CD fn-JJ-OZU) OLL OOJJ4qfcU) Statement (7), page 23 N z 0 W F- 0 z Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 TOTAL ANNUAL EXPENDITURES OASI AND DI PROGRAMS COMBINED 240 7 220 200 B 180 I L L 160 I 0 N 140 S O F 120 D OL 100 L A 80 R S 60 -I 40 -~ 20-I COST-OF-LIVING ADJUSTMENTS 1974 AND AFTER 51.8 PERCENT \\_ CUMULATIVE BENEFIT INCREASE 1970-1972 DISABILITY BENEFITS 1957 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 NOTE: 1985 BASED ON INTERMEDIATE PROJECTIONS Statement (7), page 24 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 m 0) CD m m CD CD C 0 m CD OD (0 44 b9 44 m m 0 CD m m N 69 b9 Statement (7), page 25 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 CD >- z Q H < } H Q U CL CY- H O li O:D to l~ W OC=WZW QY'HUD O Z 3 U N W CD Z >- H Q }- Q < H O~ a- (y u O (n O LHi Ox OD 0(~ O jy LL- W Oc W Z VZW O QHm 0 O(;;;= O~ U (Y) Q O W CD O H Statement (7), page 26 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 PAYOUTS BY THE FOUR SOCIAL SECURITY FUNDS IN 1980 Hospital Insurance (HI) Trust Fund $25.1 billion 16.1% Disability Insu rance (DI) Trust Fund $15.4 billion 9.9% Old-Ape and Survivors Insurance (OASI) Trust Fund $106.1 billion 67.2% Chart A shows: Of the total benefits paid by Social Security in 1980 ($156.2 billion), more than two-thirds ($105.1 billion) came from the OASI trust fund. Statement (7), page 27 396-938 o - 83 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 PAYOUTS BY THE OASI TRUST FUND IN 1980 Special Aq 72 Benefits $.1 billion, .1% Lump Sum Death Benefits 2 Retiree Benefits $70.4 billion 67.0% Survivor Benefits $26.7 billion 25.4% Retiree Dependent Benefits $7.5 billion 7.1% Chart B Shows: The total of benefits that survivors and dependents of retirees receive is less than half of what retirees receive. SA special benefit is sometimes available to persons 72 or older who do not qualify for regular retirement benefits. -VA sum of $255 to apply to burial expenses. This benefit was restricted in 1981 to entitled spouses and children. Statement (7), page 28 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 A Social Security Fact Sheet Here, as supplied by the Social Security Administration, are some pertinent facts on social security's recipients, its taxpayers and its financial health. NUMBER OF BENEFICIARIES 1972 1977 April 1982 Old age and survivors trust fund 25,204,542 29,228,350 31,808,503 Disability trust fund 3,271,486 4,854,206 4,337,195 AVERAGE MONTHLY BENEFIT 1972 1977 Sept.1982 Retired worker $157 $237 $405 Retired worker and aged spouse 273 404 692 Widowed mother, two children 383 547 925 Disabled worker 175 266 429 Disabled worker and family 363 538 869 SOCIAL SECURITY PAYROLL TAXES The tax rate is for both employers and employees, and the increases shown are already scheduled; the wage base is indexed under the law, and increases assume moderate economic growth. Tax rate Wage base Maximum contribution 1972 5.20% $9,000 $468 1977 5.85 16,500 965 1982 6.70 32,400 2,171 1983 6.70 35,100 2,352 1984 6.70 37,500 2,513 1985 7.05 40,500 2,855 1986 7.15 43,800 3,132 1987 7.15 46,800 3,346 1988 7.15 50,100 3,582 1989 7.15 53,400 3,818 1990 7.65 57,000 4,361 CASH OUTLAYS (Calendar years, billions of dollars) 1972 1977 1982 (est.) Old age $38.5 $75.3 $141.9 Disability 4.7 11.9 18.1 TRUST FUND RESERVES Reserves (in billions) are shown for the old age and survivors, disability and hospital insurance funds; fund ratios-money on band at the beginning of a year as a fraction of the amounts needed for the full year-are for old age and survivors combined with disability, and for all three funds combined. Year-end reserves Fund ratios OAST DI HI OASDI OASDHI 1972 $35.3 $7.5 - 93% - 1977 32.5 3.4 - - - 1982 17.3 1.6 $15.8 15 22% 1983 -2.6 8.7 19.0 11 16 1984 -26.4 18.4 21.0 3 10 1985 -50.0 34.6 23.6 -4 5 1986 -77.6 53.8 28.0 -7 3 Statement (7), page 29 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 NEWLY ENTITLED RETIREE FAMILIES' MEAN AND MEDIAN LNOO, E`. , BY SOURCE AND FAMILY TYPE (note a) All Total reported Social Security other i.ncor e income retirement income (rote b) Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median All respondents $14,259 $11,450 $ 4,777 $ 4,754 $ 9,482 $ 6,252 Early retirees 14,003 11,428 4,615 4,694 9,388 6,252 Regular retirees 16,411 13,303 6,134 6,681 10,277 6,350 Family type Early retirees: Retiree only 13,442 10,548 4,121 4,407 9,321 6,075 Retiree & spouse 17,082 14,521 7,500 7,463 9,582 7,200 Retiree, spouse, & children 16,759 16,200 7,965 8,810 8,794 7,200 Retiree & children 17,652 15,358 6,267 6,242 11,385 8,200 Regular retirees: Retiree only 14,999 11,377 5,394 5,776 9,605 5,669 Retiree & spouse 21,165 18,322 8,850 9,008 12,315 8,680 Retiree, spouse, & children 26,884 24,588 10,859 12,181 16,025 13,025 Retiree & children 26,529 22,990 9,694 11,188 16,835 14,188 Table 23 s}yvws: The median social security income ($4,754) accounts for 42 per- cent of the median total first year income ($11,450) of all retirees. The median first year income of regular retirees with a spouse and children who also received benefits was $24,588. Their median family income was about 50 percent higher than that of early retirees with a spouse and children. Notes: 1. Children benefits include student benefits, which are scheduled for significant curtailment by 1985. 2. See note 2, Table 19. a/See note a, Table 19. b/Includes retiree families who reported no other income. Statement (7), page 30 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Newly Retired Workers (65 and older) Average Annual Benefits and Poverty Level Year Retired Workers Annual Benefits Poverty Level Unrelated Individuals (1).(2)= Retired Workers and Spouse Annual Benefits Poverty Level Head of Household (4):(5)= 1959 $1,001.76 $1,397 .72 $1,502.64 $1,761 .85 1960 1,006.44 1,418 .71 1,509.66 1,788 .84 1961 977.97 1,433 .68 1,466.95 1,808 .81 1962 1,005.96 1,451 .69 1,508.94 1,828 .83 1963* 1,033.08 1,470 .70 1,549.62 1,850 .84 1964 1,051.32 1,488 .71 1,576.98 1,875 .84 1965 1,106.00 1,512 .73 1,659.00 1,906 .87 1966 1,206.84 1,565 .77 1,810.26 1,970 .92 1967 1,159.44 1,600 .72 1,739.16 2,017 .86 1968 1,311.44 1,667 .79 1,967.16 2,102 .94 1969 1,374.12 1,757 .78 2,061.18 2,215 .93 1970 1,607.28 1,861 .86 2,410.92 2,348 1.03 1971 1,801.32 1,940 .93 2,701.98 2,448 1.10 1972 1,952.44 2,005 .97 2,928.66 2,530 1.16 1973 2,223.60 2,130 1.04 3,335.40 2,688 1.24 1974 2,465.54 2,364 1.04 3,698.31 2,982 1.24 1975 2,728.71 2,581 1.06 4,093.07 3,257 1.26 1976 2,876.60 2,730 1.05 4,314.90 3,445 1.25 1977 3,285.40 2,906 1.13 4,928.10 3,666 1.34 1978 3,577.50 3,127 1.14 5,366.25 3,944 1.36 1979 4,029.50 3,479 1.16 6,044.25 4,390 1.38 1980 4,543.10 3,950 1.15 6,814.65 4,980 1.37 * Base year. Statement (7), page 31 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 NEWLY ENTITLED RETIREE FAMILIES' INVESTMENTS AND 7VrAL ASSETS, BY MEDIAN AMOUNTS AND FAMILY TYPE (note a) Investments Percent Total family assets Percent no response (note b) Median amount (note c) reported no invest- ments Median amount (note c) Percent reported no assets All respondents Family type 22.0 $ 7,598.14 11.2 $48,499.06 4.9 Early retirees: 21.5 7,581.52 1.1 48,126.45 4.8 Retiree only 20.8 7,565.21 10.5 45,800.00 5.2 Retiree & spouse Retiree, spouse, 28.2 24,897.20 6.8 59,724.42 6.1 & children Retiree & 20.6 3,580.35 27.1 46,250.02 2.8 children 8.8 3,635.41 25.8 44,350.00 6.6 Regular retirees: 26.6 15,028.16 11.9 62,395.59 6.1 Retiree only 13.0 14,967.10 13.2 52,975.01 7.3 Retiree & spouse Retiree, spouse, 8.4 25,076.55 7.1 85,012.93 1.6 & children Retiree & 18.4 25,020.83 7.5 93,000.00 1.8 children 7.5 24,912.50 9.4 78,000.00 2.1 Table 26 shows: For families consisting of a retiree, spouse, and children, the median investment and total assets for early retiree families was $3,580 and $46,250 compared with $25,020 and $93,000 for regular retiree families. a/Excludes personal residence and automobiles. b/No response indicates the percentage of questionnaire respondents who failed to provide ca;plete answers to income-related questions. c/Includes our estimate of what the no response group would have reported had they provided complete answers to income-related questions. Statement (7), page 32 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 TOTAL SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFICIARIES (in millions) 1945............ 1.1 1965............ 20.2 1950............ 2.9 1970 ............ 25.8 1955 ............ 7.6 1975............ 31.4 1960............ 14.3 1980 ............. 35.1 1981 ............. 36.0 -TOTAL SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFICIARIES AND PAYMENTS, STATE-BY-STATE (1980)* State Beneficiaries Paid State Alabama......... .6 $ 2.2 Missouri ......... .9 $ 3.2 Alaska.......... .02 .1 Montana .........1 .5 Arizona......... .4 1.6 Nebraska ......... .3 1.0 Arkansas ........ .4 1.5 Nevada.... ..... .1 .4 California...... 3.2 12.7 New Hampshire.... .1 .6 Colorado........ .3 1.3 New Jersey....... 1.2 5.0 Connecticut ..... .5 2.0 New Mexico....... .2 .6 Delaware........ .1 .4 New York......... 2.9 12.1 Dist. of Col..... .1 .3 North Carolina... .9 3.1 Florida ......... 2.0 8.0 North Dakota..... .1 .3 Georgia......... .8 2.6 Ohio ............. 1.6 6.6 Hawaii.......... .1 .4 Oklahoma......... .5 1.7 Idaho........... .1 .5 Oregon ........... .4 1.7 Illinois........ 1.6 6.7 Pennsylvania..... 2.1 8.5 Indiana......... .8 3.3 Rhode Island ..... .2 .7 Iowa...... ..... .5 1.9 South Carolina... .4 1.5 Kansas.......... .4 1.5 South Dakota..... .1 .4 Kentucky........ .6 2.0 Tennessee ........ .7 2.5 Louisiana....... .6 2.0 Texas ............ 1.8 6.5 Maine ........... .2 .7 Utah :............ .1. .6 Maryland ........ .5 2.0 Vermont .......... .1 .3 Massachussetts.. .9 4.0 Virginia ......... .7 2.6 Michigan........ 1.3 5.7 Washington....... .6 2.4 Minnesota....... .6 2.3 West Virginia.... .4 1.3 Mississippi..... .4 1.3 Wisconsin........ .8 3.0 Wyoming.......... .01 .2 American Samoa... .002 .003 Guam ............. .003 .008 Puerto Rico...... .6 1.2 Virgin Islands... .007 .002 Abroad........... .3 1.0 *beneficiaries in millions, dollars in billions Statement (7), page 33 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Growth of Real After -Tax incomes * of Average Social Security Recipients** (1957=100) 200 190 180 Retired 1981 ? Retired 1980 ----.... 170 160 150 140 130 120 110 100 Retired 1977 Retired 1975 Retired 1972 , ????.,, % 1% off on go % ?` 1967 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 * After-tax incomes deflated by CPI. * * The "Retired" plots reflect the widening spread in benefits for thn.p rptirprl p1irl pr to thnep rptirino in more recent veers. Statement (7), page 34 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Annual Benefits Retiring to "Average" Age 65 Worker in Various Years (in 1967 dollars) 1967 1972 1975 1977 1980 1981 1967 1477 1968 1571 1969 1519 1970 1631 1971 1726 1972 1768 2052 1973 1902 2208 1974 1808 2098 1975 1813 2104 2193 1976 1837 2132 2222 1977 1821 2113 2203 2329 1978 1807 1981 2186 2313 1979 1756 1925 2132 2247 1980 1736 1903 2101 2222 2543 1981 1773 1942 2145 2269 2596 2640 Initial Benefit as a % of Pre-Tax Earnings 29.9 37.7 42.3 44.8 51.1 54.7 1981 Benefit as a % of Pre-Tax Earnings 35.9 32.3 40.1 42.2 53.2 54.7 Initial Benefit as a % of Post-Tax Earnings 35.0 46.0 51.3 52.8 56.4 61.8 1982 Benefit as a % of Post-Tax Earnings 42.0 43.6 50.2 51.5 57.6 61.8 Statement (7), page 35 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Comparison of the Growth in Average Real After-tax Earnings and Social Security Benefits Over Selected Time Periods Percent 20 20 Retiree Worker 15 10 2.1 .06 f6 -5.3 -5.6 -10 -5.3 -1.7 -7.9 i L 1967-81 1972-81 1975-81 1977-81 1980-81 Statement (7), page 36 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Current Law Net Tax Changes Bracket Creep Plus Payroll Tax Increase Less Tax Cut Under ERTA Family of four, 1982 earnings with cost of living adjustment $15,000. $25,000 ..................... $30,000M-..----..-9 $40,000 $15,000 Ills&MM so "less $20,000 $25,000 Net Decrease From 1980 Tax Rate -2001 I 1 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 Statement (7), page 37 ego ..?? 00 $30,000 I I I 1985 1986 1987 1988 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Major Legislative Changes in Social Security 1935: A system of Federal old age benefits covering workers in commerce and industry is established. Benefits were to be based on cumulative wages and to be payable beginning in 1942 to qualified workers age 65 and over. A payroll tax of 1 percent on employer and employees, each imposed on a wage base of $3,000, was to be collected as of January 1937; the tax would rise to 3 percent by 1949. 1939: The starting date for benefits is advanced to 1940. Benefits for dependents of retired workers and for surviv- ing dependents in case of a worker's death are authorized. 1952: Benefits are increased by 12.5 percent. 1954: Coverage is almost universal except for Federal government employees. The wage base is increased to $4,200, and benefits are increased by 13 percent. 1956: Disability insurance (DI) benefits are added payable at age 50. Women are permitted to retire at age 62 with actuarially reduced benefits. 1958: Benefits are added for dependents of DI recipients, and the DI eligibility standard is liberalized. 1960: The age 50 limitation for DI elibility is eliminated. 1961: Men may retire at age 62 with an actuarial reduction. 1965: Medicare becomes part of social security. Cash benefits are increased by 7 percent. 1968: Cash benefits are increased by 13 percent. The tax rate is now 4.4 percent and the wage base $7,800. 1969: Cash benefits increased by 15 percent. 1972: Cash benefit increases, which had previously been made in an ad hoc fashion by the Congress, were made automatic as- was the increase in the wage base. The 20 percent benefit increase which occurred this year was made possible by a change in actuarial assumptions from a level wage growth path to a dynamic one. Statement (7), page 38 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 1977: An error in the 1972 automatic indexing at initial benefit determination produced a long-run deficit due to the high rates of inflation between 1972 and 1977. This error was corrected and the current method of wage-indexing both the earnings history and the bend points was decided upon. Automatic cost-of-living adjustments remained intact. The long-run deficit necessitated the largest increase in scheduled tax rates in the system's history, culminating at 7.65 percent on employee and employer in 1990. 1981: A short-run financing problem requires interfund borrowing and some benefit reductions near-term. The long-term actuarial and economic problems are worse. Even the large pending tax increases are inadequate to cover the large increases in real benefits being promised over time under OASDI. The system's grand promises are depressing the Nation's saving and growth rates, jeopardizing its own tax base. There is a burgeoning long-run deficit under HI which dwarfs the OASDI problem. Some politically acceptable alteration in benefit formulas must be found for the long run. This will inevitably involve indexing changes. Source: Derthick, Martha, Policymaking for Social Security, The Brookings Institution, 1979, pp. 429-432. Statement (7), page 39 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUPPLEMENTARY STATEMENT BY MARY FALVEY FULLER Working Toward Meaningful Social Security Reform After a year's work, the National Commission on Social Security Reform, together with the White House and the Speaker, have produced a package with the potential to be passed into law within the next few months. The overriding objective of our recent negotiations was to produce a package that would generate enough support to be enacted by the Congress in time to prevent either delay of benefit checks in July of this year or an emergency infusion of general revenues. As a result, the compromise includes elements that are distasteful to many Commissioners for different reasons. In my view, the package contains two major provisions that are commendable: 1. Extension of coverage to new Federal employees and all employees of nonprofit organizations, so that Social Security becomes closer to a universal-coverage system. 2. Shift in the COLA to wages or prices or lesser after 1988 if the trust fund ratio falls below 20%. Although this stabilizer of outgo relative to income is effective only in times of real wage loss, it is a step in regulating the COLA to reflect economic conditions. Statement (8), page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 However, there are a number of additional provisions that I believe are necessary for meaningful reform that we should work for vigorously in the months and years ahead, specifically: 1. A clear commitment to increase the retirement age to reflect the increased longevity of the American population. The increased life expectancy of beneficiaries, coupled with the declining birthrate, means that we will have only two workers supporting each beneficiary in 2025 and after, in contrast to the 16 we had in 1950. 2. A combination of COLA stabilizer and fail-safe mechanism to guarantee that crises like the one we face now, and the one we had in 1977, will not recur before the end of the decade and in the future. 3. A balance between tax increases and benefit restraints that is realistic and fair over the long term. This package relies on new sources of revenue and tax increases for about $100 billion of the gap of $168 billion, and the tax increases come on top of $300 billion enacted in 1977 that apply to the 1983-89 period. Relatively little has been accomplished to date in restraining the growth of benefits over the long term. Statement (8), page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 4. Reliance on the payroll tax as the sole source of financing. This is essential to preserve the discipline in managing the growth of benefits relative to taxes, the parity between the employer and employee contributions, and the earned-right character of the program. The remainder of this statement discusses each of these areas. Clear Commitment to Increase the Retirement Age The bi-partisan package leaves open a gap of .58% of payroll as part of the total long-term gap of 1.80%. The package stipulates that the gap would be filled by either a gradual increase in the normal retirement age or a combination of other measures. I support the proposal to fill the entire gap through a gradual increase in the normal retirement age. In fact, I believe that this measure, while adequate based on the economic projections used in costing out the package, may fall short of what will actually be needed. Furthermore, the age of 66 in 2015 is about 5 years below the age at which a person would work the same portion of his/her life as that determined by using age 65 when it was enacted in 1935. Consequently, I believe that the increase in the normal retirement age should be adjusted at some later time so as to reach age 68 by 2015. This would produce long-range savings of 1.3% of payroll. Statement (8), page 3 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 There is a growing belief that this will be needed to fill a long-term gap of 2.4% of payroll, which results from the latest projections of fertility rates by the Bureau of Census. The Congress and the public may not be aware that actual economic performance has, in recent years, consistently fallen short of the most pessimistic economic projections made in the annual reports of the Board of Trustees. It would be responsible, forward-thinking policy to provide for this gap soon -- especially since a retirement age of 68 is what the many research studies have shown to be appropriate by the year 2015 to reflect longevity at that time -- even allowing for some growth in the proportion of life spent in retirement. One could then delay the indexing schedule to begin after 2020 if the trust funds show a substantial surplus. This would be fairer to the working population than allowing another crisis to loom before taking needed action. Combination of COLA Stabilizer and Fail-Safe Mechanism The bi-partisan package includes a provision that would substitute the lesser of the percentage wage increase or the percentage price increase, beginning with 1988 if the combined OASDI trust fund ratio falls below 20%. While this is a positive step, it is possible that action will be needed before 1988 to avoid another funding crisis. Several Commissioners had proposed putting a cap on the COLA between 1984 and 1988 or basing the COLA on wage Statement (8), page 4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 increases minus 1/ percentage points. The latter method would make the adjustment independent of the CPI and yet produce exactly the same benefit increases over the long-term, (after the 1980s) as under present law, if economic conditions are the same as those assumed under the intermediate assumptions of the 1982 Trustees Report. On the other hand, if economic conditions are unfavorable, and wages do not exceed prices by as much as is projected, the financial solvency of the program would be protected, because benefit increases would be smaller than under present law. Conversely, if economic conditions are more favorable than assumed, benefit increases would be larger than under present law, and the financial condition of the system would still be strong. If another funding crisis develops before 1988, we will be faced with further tax increases -- on top of those enacted in 1977 and those that are proposed in the "consensus" package -- or another COLA delay. I hope that this does not occur, because our credibility in controlling the financial condition of the Social Security program would be damaged in the eyes of the American people. However, based on recent experience with actual economic conditions versus projections, we cannot rule this out. Several of us also recommended a fail-safe mechanism to ensure that benefits would continue to be paid on time despite unexpectedly adverse conditions, which can occur with little advance notice. One mechanism would be Statement (8), page 5 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 to reduce, temporarily, benefits payable. Alternatively the same result could be accomplished indirectly by reducing the next benefit increase that would occur as a result of the COLA. Another mechanism could be to increase, temporarily, the OASDI tax rates. Because of the already large tax burden on today's workers, I would favor the first or second alternative. I recognize that Congress is more likely to respond to actual, rather than potential crisis, but I am concerned about further damaging public confidence in the Social Security program by frequent short-term threats. Balance Between Tax Increases and Benefit Restraints The current estimated short-term gap of $150 to $200 billion for 1983-89 comes on top of a tax increase in 1977 that amounts to about $300 billion during this period. The bi-partisan package contains new sources of revenue and tax increases of about $100 to $130 billion depending on whether the taxing of benefits is classified as a tax increase or a benefit reduction. In any case, this means that at least $400 billion in new revenues and tax increases will have been enacted in 1977 and after to close a gap of $500 billion. This is, in my view, an unbalanced reliance on taxes, which places an excessive burden on today's working population, while holding retirees relatively harmless. There is a limit to the psychological as well as financial capacity of the working population to absorb continued tax increases. This is especially true during times when they are asked to accept wage increases that do not keep up with inflation. Statement (8), page 6 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 The clear preference for tax increases rather than benefit restraints has been shown by the actions taken over the last decade. This is one of the major reasons that young people are afraid that the Social Security program will not be around to support them when they retire. The public may be beginning to realize that our overall budget deficit of about $200 billion is, essentially, a commitment on the part of the next generation to pay increased income taxes. The combined effects of increases in Social Security taxes, income taxes and, inevitably, Hospital Insurance taxes appears formidable, to say the least, and unfair when certain groups of people are partially exempt. Reliance on Payroll Tax to Finance Social Security Program The Social Security system has been based on the philosophy that benefits are financed by payroll taxes, paid equally by employers and employees. The bi- partisan package contains a refundable income tax credit for 1984 that would offset the payroll-tax increase. This is a direct violation of this fundamental principle; it upsets the parity between employer and employee contributions and infuses general revenues into the Social Security program. It should not be repeated under any circumstances. In my view, it is essential to maintain the self-financed character of the Social Security program -- both to maintain discipline in managing the system and to protect its status as an earned-right, rather than a welfare program. The self-financed character of the system is essential to prevent moving to a system that conditions benefits based on Statement (8), page 7 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 financial need. Furthermore, to inject general revenues at a time when we have the highest budget deficits in American history, it is very unfortunate and should not be repeated in any form. Americans value the Social Security system as a contributory program, and this is essential to the long-term health of the system. It has been a privilege to serve on this Commission and, though many of us have had to swallow hard, some constructive steps have been taken. I am hopeful that some meaningful reforms will emerge from the up-coming deliberations in the Congress. Statement (8), page 8 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUPPLEMENTARY STATEMENT BY MARY FALVEY FULLER Addressing the Changing Role of Women The effect on women of the Social Security program is a subject of major importance, and much analytical work has been done to identify and evaluate alternative approaches to correct the unintended inequities. In fact, the 1979 Advisory Council on Social Security spent more time on this issue than on any other single issue. Unfortunately, our commission could not address this issue due to the urgent priority of restoring the solvency of the system. But we do not intend this choice to detract from the importance of restoring the equitable treatment of women in today's world. The provisions of the bi-partisan package, while advantageous to certain groups of women, do not begin to address the fundamental, though unintended, inequities, that act to the disadvantage of all people except members of intact one-earner couples. The Social Security system was designed at a time when most families each had one wage earner with a dependent spouse, and marriages were, for the most part, lifelong. As a result, the benefits of the dependent spouse are determined as a function of the earnings of the worker, and divorced spouses do not receive any benefits unless the marriage has lasted for more than arbitrary Statement (9), page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 number of years (which is now 10). Today, the times are different; a substantial majority of women spend most of their lives in the paid workforce, and there is one divorce for every two marriages, with two-thirds of divorces occurring after less than 10 years. The Social Security program, therefore, has some unintended inequities that need to be corrected: 1. The secondary earner, in most cases the woman, gets little, if any, return on her Social Security taxes. Only if she earns more than one-third of the combined couple's income do her benefits as a worker exceed those she would receive as a dependent spouse. 2. Two-earner couples receive less in benefits than one-earner couples with the same earnings. Survivors of two-earner couples are, correspondingly, penalized. 3. Single retirees receive lower benefits relative to their tax contributions then married couples. 4. The spouse receives no benefits on divorce unless the marriage lasted 10 years or more. These inequities result from the continued use of the concept of a dependent spouse which is, in today's world, an anachronism. Marriage today is Statement (9), page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 an economic partnership, and each partner contributes to the well-being of the family. The most direct method of restoring the proper treatment of both spouses is through a program of earnings sharing, where each spouse receives credit for one-half of the combined earnings of the couple during the life of the marriage. In this way, each spouse receives credit for her/his contribution to the marriage year-by-year with no requirement eased on duration of the marriage. The co,iceptual precedent is community property, which prevails in several states. Such a program would need to be tailored to special circumstances, such as protecting the family in the event of loss of the primary earner's income through disability. Moreover, the transition would need to be orderly and fair, which is not to say, protracted and expensive. However, there is in my view, no need to hold harmless groups (like divorced men) whose total benefits may have been high relative to their contributions. There is also no need for increased costs except for the transition. The earnings-sharing program developed for evaluation by the 1979 Advisory Council had an increased cost of .09% of payroll -- excluding the cost of adding disability protection for certain groups, primarily homemakers. I do not believe that the evaluation of earnings sharing should be complicated by adding benefits that do not exist today. Responsibility for supporting homemakers during retirement and disability is a separate subject with different arguments, which are based on different issues. Statement (9), page 3 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 The fact that transition to such a program will be complex to design and implement should not prevent this much-needed change. Work on the program should begin now so that the details can be worked out and communicated well in advance. Implementation should begin as soon as the system is in a position to support the cost of transition -- hopefully by 1990. Change is natural in a healthy society, and effort is better spent implementing orderly change than trying to force-fit elements of the status quo that have outlived their relevance. Statement (9), page 4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Supplementary Statement on Mandatory Coverage of Public Employees by Lane Kirkland I cannot support the Commission's recommendation for mandatory social security coverage of newly hired federal and postal employees. The many complex issues involved make it difficult to protect federal and postal employee rights under the best of circumstances. This is even more difficult at the present time since the proposal is being put forward in the context of a search for additional sources of revenue and Congress is not likely to decide the issue solely on its own merits. I could not support coverage unless all of the following conditions were met: 1. No reduction in the level of pension benefits now available to government workers. 2. No additional financial burden on government employees without a commensurate adjustment in benefits. 3. Preservation of the identity for government workers' retirement plans. 4. No diminution in the opportunity for these employees to improve their retirement systems. The Commission cannot know in advance whether the pension rights of present and future employees will be adequately protected if Congress enacts mandatory coverage. Federal and postal employees should have the right to know and evaluate in advance the details of any proposal before they are asked to take this step. Statement (10), Page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Discussions are going forward to try to develop a solution to this problem which will strengthen and reinforce both the Social Security System and the Civil Service Retirement System. Those discussions ought not to be hampered by untimely and imprecise recommendations of this Commission. The Commission should not recommend nor should the Congress act when the coverage details are unknown. Otherwise, there can be no assurance that they meet criteria essential for assuring equity to those affected. A majority of the Commission supports in principle social security coverage of state and local government employees but has not so recommended because of concern about constitutional barriers. The implication is that Congress should mandatorily cover these employees if the constitutional issues can be resolved. I will not support such coverage unless the protections previously specified for federal employees are met by any legislation applicable to State and local government employees. I support legislation that would remove the option for State and local governments and nonprofit organizations to withdraw from social security once they have elected for coverage. The unilateral right of these employers to withdraw has resulted in their employees losing valuable retirement, survivor and disability protections. This "loophole" in the law should be eliminated. Once this has been accomplished, public employers that have withdrawn in the past should be permitted to reenter the system. The legislation should specify a way for workers or their unions to initiate such action. This is not possible under present law. Proponents of coverage will contend that twenty billion dollars will be lost between now and 1990 to social security trust funds if coverage of federal and postal employees does not take place. As a substitute source of revenue and as a meritorious proposal in its own right, I recommend requiring employers Statement (10), Page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 to contribute to social security on the basis of their total payrolls. This would bring into the system about $40 billion between now and 1990 and would reduce social security's long run deficit by .56% of taxable payroll. The wage base is necessary to determine the maximum employee benefit but plays no similar role for the employer. Employers' responsibility for the welfare of their employees should be based on their total payrolls, not just on a portion of workers' earnings. Employees must pay federal income tax on their social security contributions. Employers do not pay the full rate since they deduct their tax as a business expense. This give-back to employers in reduced income taxes is largely financed by the income taxes of workers since federal revenues to an overwhelmingly degree are based on taxes provided by individuals' incomes. Individual income taxes now provide 71 percent of general revenues, up from 47.5 percent in 1954. The corporate share is expected to be only 11 percent of general revenues for 1982. In 1954, corporation income taxes supplied 34 percent of all revenues (excluding employment taxes). As a result, employers pay only about one-third of the combined costs of the program and employees two-thirds. Thus, there is every reason why employers should pay social security taxes on their total payrolls. Statement (10), Page 3 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Dissenting Views of Joe D. Waggonner, Jr. It has been a privilege and an honor to serve on the National Commission on Social Security Reform. Our country needs a sound, adequately financed Social Security program. I thank the President for the opportunity to serve. I strongly support the Social Security program and recognize its critical role in providing income security. The program has been extremely successful and must be preserved for this generation as well as future generations. I am in complete agreement with the initial finding of the Commission, that the fundamental structure of the Social Security program has proven to be sound and should not be altered. Since its inception nearly a half a century ago, the program has been maintained on a self-financing, contributory basis. With a few limited exceptions (i.e., gratuitous military wage credits and special benefits for certain uninsured persons age 72 and over) the program has been financed exclusively by taxes paid by workers and employers. The self-financing principle has served a dual purpose. It has helped to protect the program -- although it has not completely guaranteed it -- against unwarranted and ill-considered over-expansion. At the same time, the "earned Statement (11), page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 right" concept inherent in a self-financed program has helped to protect it -- although it has not completely guaranteed it -- from gradual conversion to a needs-tested welfare program. Therefore, the public should rest assured that there is strong support for the program. Neither party wants to see the system fail. Consequently, I believe that the program is too important to be subjected to politics. It is now, and in fact long since, time to cease the political rhetoric and enact legislation that responsibly solves both the short-term and long-term financing problems. The longer such action is delayed, the more severe the consequences of such inaction. There are a variety of reasonable solutions to the financing problems of the system. Those solutions do not have the dire consequences that people fear as a result of the emotional rhetoric. It is unnecessary to reduce benefits currently being paid or to make precipitous changes in the future growth of benefits. However, the future growth of benefits must be slowed. Revolutionary or radical changes are not desirable. Similarly, there is no need for massive tax increases or for the use of non-existent general-revenue financing. It is critical that the solutions to the problems address the causes of the short-term and long-range problems. The immediate cause of the short-term problem is a technical deficiency in the cost-of-living adjustment that causes the program to be unstable. It absolutely must be changed if a stable system is to survive. The long-term problem is essentially the product of demographic changes. The "baby boom" generation and continuing improvements in life Statement (11), page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 expectancy will overwhelm the program unless changes are made. Demographics in the long-range demand structural changes. Demographics is the long-term problem. I am greatly concerned that proposals have been made that do not adequately address those causes. A brief background on the growth of the Social Security program and further explanation of the causes is warranted. Disability and Medicare benefits have been added since monthly benefit payments started in 1940, coverage has been expanded, the level of benefits has grown, and the tax liabilities of workers and employers have increased. Fundamentals for financing and redistribution of benefits have changed very little. The combined maturing of the program and the growth of real benefits brought on by the runaway inflation of the 1970s, have raised the increased tax burden. In 1950, only 20% of people above age 65 received Social Security benefits. Today, more than 90% do. The average retired worker benefit has increased from $70 a month in 1960 to about $420 a month today. It was unquestionably intended that Social Security benefits provide a basic floor of protection to be supplemented by other retirement income when Social Security was enacted. Other retirement income was available then and continues to increase. Too often, older Americans are portrayed as being totally dependent on Social Security benefits for retirement income. Those who paint the economic picture of the elderly often overlook certain truths. In Statement (11), page 3 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 past years, the relative value of other sources of income has significantly increased. Among these sources are (1) pension programs, which have increased from some 750 plans (private) in 1935 to some 700,000 plans today; (2) the Keogh program for the self-employed recently was enlarged to encourage savings; (3) Individual Retirement Accounts have been liberalized and will encourage a more responsible attitude for retirement planning among employed workers; (4) CODAs, which are cash or deferred arrangements are allowed by changes to the tax code in 1978 which provide that workers can now establish cash or deferred arrangements under qualified profit sharing or stock bonus plans; (5) in addition, some 70% of the elderly couples own their homes at retirement and some 80% of those have no mortgage; (6) many have accumulated a significant amount of wealth at retirement; (7) some continue to work after age 65; and (8) programs with means-test eligibility criteria for the elderly such as the Supplemental Security Income program, housing, food stamps, Medicaid, and energy assistance provide additional protections for low-income elderly persons. Just since 1968, cumulative Social Security benefit increases have totaled 270%, compared with a CPI increase over that same period of 189%. The proportion of before-tax income replaced by Social Security benefits has increased steadily over this same 15-year period. A male aged 65 with average covered earnings who retired in January 1968 had 32.3% of his before-tax earnings replaced by Social Security; in January 1983 a similar individual will have 45.7% of his before-tax earnings replaced. Statement (11), page 4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 As Social Security benefits and replacement rates have been steadily increasing, the Federal Government has essentially placed itself in direct competition with the private sector in the providing of retirement income security. As indicated previously, the method by which benefits are adjusted for inflation permits benefits to increase more rapidly at times than the wages of those paying taxes to support those benefits. As a result, benefits can grow more rapidly than taxes, causing the program to be unstable when economic conditions are adverse. For example, in the past four years, CPI-indexed benefits grew by 50%, while average wages grew by only 37%. If benefits had increased at the same rate as wages, the program would be generating excesses of income over outgo and there would be no short-term problems. The Social Security program as presently structured is widely accepted by the American people, although their confidence in its financing basis has been unnecessarily shaken. The present financial difficulty is real, arguments to the contrary notwithstanding, but emotion has overwhelmed reason. This Commission is obligated to the President and the American people to recommend a plan whose policy or policies would assure an on-going program for the benefit of this Nation, our present and future generations. What are our options? Basically only four exist. They are: Statement (11), page 5 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 (1) Increase or accelerate already scheduled tax increases. Surely, past experience has demonstrated and proved the futility of such a policy. The last major Social Security refinancing legislation, enacted in 1977, is a good example. At that time, Congress and the Administration attempted to solve Social Security's financing problems by the enactment of the largest peace-time tax increases in U.S. history. In spite of this tremendous tax increase, because subsequent economic conditions were far worse than those assumed in the formulation of the legislation, the solution failed. This recent experience must not be reenacted. Because forecasting future economic conditions is, at best, an imprecise science, extreme caution must be taken when considering current reform proposals to err on the side of caution -- to avoid simply another short term fix. Four tax rate changes have already gone into effect since 1977. Three more are scheduled to go into effect during the next several years, and large increases in the maximum earnings subject to taxes are also scheduled. Because of the 1977 legislation, wage earners and their employers will pay an additional $299 billion in taxes during the period 1983 through 1989. That does not include the huge tax increases scheduled to begin in 1990. Since 1977, maximum annual taxes paid by an individual have increased from $965 to $2,392, an increase of almost 150%. In fact, since 1949, maximum taxes have increased by 7900%. Statement (11), page 6 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 I am strongly opposed to a solution that depends to a large extent on tax increases, which increase the cost of labor at a time when we should be concerned about creating jobs. A further tax on labor will only serve to significantly increase unemployment, as forecast by several econometric studies. Such action would weaken some of our major industries struggling for survival in the face of stiff foreign competition, as well as many small companies struggling to avoid bankruptcy. Furthermore, despite the adverse effect on unemployment, large payroll tax increases would be inflationary because some companies would be able to pass along the higher labor costs to consumers. Alternatively, further tax increases will tend to depress wage growth. While decoupling provisions of the 1977 legislation cut the long-term deficit by about 80 percent, its short-term financing provisions relied primarily on tax increases rather than on reductions in costs. Thus, legislation which was heralded as guaranteeing the financial soundness of the program well into the second decade of the next century has proven inadequate in less than five years. You simply can't raise enough money by taxation to satisfy people's wants. We have long since exceeded our ability to pay for all that people want from government. (2) Provide general Treasury direct or indirect financing to meet the program needs. Statement (11), page 7 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 This approach is totally unrealistic in the light of today's circumstances. Even with the budget growth cuts that have been painfully enacted in the last two years, there is now no end in sight for annual Federal budget deficits in the neighborhood of $200 billion. Under these conditions, introducing general revenues into the financing of the Social Security program would require the program to compete with all of the other demands for the general funds of the Treasury. It would be disastrous on the economy. Financial stability of the Social Security program depends on a healthy economy. The "earned right" concept would be abandoned, and almost overnight the program would take on all the aspects of a welfare program. It would in fact become a "guaranteed annual income" from the government such as the already rejected "Family Assistance Plan". I strongly oppose this. (3) Combine additional taxes through the system or Treasury financing A mix of unrelated taxes such as excise taxes would simply employ the use of concepts which would work to undermine the earned-right concept so central to Social Security. I strongly oppose this. (4) Tailor benefits to revenues. This is the only reasonable course. In fact this Commission and, this policy may have been our last chance to preserve the Social Security program as it was intended and should be. There will be no return to reason, stability and solvency, you just don't go back. We must tailor benefits to revenues. Statement (11), page 8 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 The elderly are fair and responsible. They don't want to see their children and grandchildren, whose wages have not been keeping pace with inflation and who face high levels of unemployment, burdened with large tax increases. However, they are also very concerned about drastic cuts in benefits because of all the political rhetoric. When the problems and solutions are presented to them objectively and unemotionally, most agree to balanced solutions that address the causes of the problems. The demographic problems are well-documented. The "baby boom" represents a tidal wave of future beneficiaries. Their benefits will be paid for by the relatively small "baby bust" generation that results from the dramatic reduction in birth rates since 1970. Substantial improvements in mortality compound the problems because benefits will have to be paid over longer periods of time. Once the baby boom generation retires, "best estimate" projections predict there will be only two workers supporting each beneficiary. If the Office of the Actuary modifies those "best estimate" assumptions to reflect continuation of current birth rates, as has been done by the Census Bureau in its most recent population forecast even fewer workers will be expected to support each beneficiary. While this Commission has not addressed the financing problems facing Medicare, I recommend that the policy implications of Medicare be reflected in OASDI legislation. The long-term deficit for the Hospital Insurance portion of Statement (11), page 9 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Medicare is almost three times as large as the OASDI deficit. It is 5.21% of payroll. That deficit occurs despite massive cost shifts and despite assumptions that predict that health care costs will ultimately be controlled. I recommend that it is imperative that long-term changes be enacted now for several reasons. First, the confidence of young workers must be restored. The best way to accomplish this is to make realistic and affordable benefit promises. Second, those who are to be affected must be given adequate advance notice for personal and financial planning, and the changes should be gradual. If action is delayed, the changes may have to be precipitous. Third, the Hospital Insurance program will begin to experience large deficits by the end of the decade and proper OASDI changes can help mitigate the effect of those deficits. The Social Security program is an intergenerational transfer program. As such, parents have to ask the question, "At what age should they expect their children to support them and what level of income should their children transfer to them?" With all of this as background, I believe that the legislation should meet certain reasonable and specific tests and/or constraints as follows: 1. All changes in their totality should be perceived to be fair to everyone affected by Social Security -- taxpayers and beneficiaries alike. Statement (11), page 10 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 2. All changes should have the objective of placing the Social Security program on a sound financial basis for the short-term and long-term. Those changes should not have the objective of balancing the budget, but rather of preserving the solvency of the Social Security program. Conversely, those changes should not increase the enormous budget deficits of other government programs. The objective should be to consistently maintain the trust funds in total at a reasonable level through the years. 3. Changes should not be precipitous -- gradual changes can and should be made so as to allow adequate time for planning. 4. Changes need not and should not reduce benefits of those now receiving 5. Recommended changes to improve the viability of the Social Security program and to restore public confidence in the system must respond to the causes of both the short and long-term problems: There is a technical deficiency in the cost-of-living adjustment that permits benefit increases to grow faster than wage increases. Statement (11), page 11 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 The "baby boom" generation is not replacing itself. It is responsible for the "baby bust". People are living longer. The ratio of taxpayers to beneficiaries will decrease. Health care costs continue to increase rapidly. 6. Future tax rates for the entire Social Security program, including Hospital Insurance, should be reasonable and affordable. 7. Should not (a) increase already scheduled tax increases; (b) provide General Treasury, direct or indirect, financing to meet the program needs; (c) funnel unrelated additional taxes through the system. Recommendations approved by the National Commission on Social Security Reform show progress toward closing the gap between projected revenues and outlays in the OASDI system. The efforts which produced this package of proposals also reflects credit on those who took part in extended negotiations, including representatives of the President and the Speaker of the House. Statement (11), page 12 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Unfortunately, however, in its present form, the bi-partisan plan falls far short of fulfilling the mandate of our Executive Order insofar as it does not specifically address or assure the long-term solvency of the Social Security system. It is also deficient as a balanced solution which is necessary to restore public confidence in the solvency and fairness of the Social Security program. Specific elements of the plan that I find unacceptable are: 1. The granting of a temporary refundable income tax credit to employees for the differential between the proposed payroll tax rate and the already scheduled payroll tax rate establishes a precedent for permanent General Treasury financing of the program. It moves us closer to the establishment of a guaranteed-annual-income policy by putting the government in support of a refundable tax credit for the first time and it upsets the historic parity of taxes between employers and employees. The matter of providing a refundable tax credit is a major tax policy consideration. It should not be resolved as a Social Security matter in isolation from the Tax Code. 2. Taxing Social Security benefits establishes a means test on benefits, effecting a penalty upon those who are prudent in saving and investing for their retirement. Future program financing difficulties or Statement (11), page 13 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 efforts to further enhance the regressive redistribution of benefits will exert pressure to retain the fixed thresholds of $20,000/$25,000 which will result in the taxing of a greater proportion of beneficiaries in the future. In effect, certain people will never quit paying into the system. Future retirees, especially those of the baby-boom generation and beyond will receive far less of a return on the taxes they they will have paid while working. Also, major "notches" will develop as a result of this recommendation. The matter of taxing Social Security benefits is a major tax policy consideration, as is, for example, taxing unemployment compensation, and should not be considered in isolation of the Tax Code. 3. The short-range deficit is met only at the low end of the projected need. There is no adequate margin of safety provided through the end of this decade, particularly in the years prior to 1988. Unless economic conditions are much better than expected over the next few years, we could once again be in a situation of having inadequate revenue to pay checks on time. In fact, I believe the short-range deficit is far more serious and the projected need is inadequate. 4. Over the period 1983-84 over one-half of the new revenue comes directly from the General Treasury. The large infusion of general revenues for the first time into the system assures that it will never Statement (11), page 14 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 again be self-sustaining. General funds should never be used. To combine Treasury revenues and a refundable tax credit will complete the transition of the program to welfare and once done, will not be changed. The hope of the young is diminished. 5.) The plan adds to projected budget deficits by permanently increasing the cost of the Supplemental Security Income program at a time of severe overall budgetary concerns. This is a welfare consideration. 6.) Major necessary structural long-term reforms are entirely avoided. There is no specific plan by which the long-term cost is met. Demographic changes which are the primary cause of the long-term problem are not adequately addressed. The proposed change in the retirement age is tragically deficient. 7.) Adding to the cost of the program in the long-term through increasing the delayed retirement credit is irresponsible inasmuch as the long- term cost reduction goal is not specifically met. 8.) It repeats the mistake of the 1977 Amendments by relying primarily on increasing taxes. Including revenue derived from expanded coverage, increased taxes account for 75% of deficit reductions; (63% if expanded coverage is excluded); Statement (11), page 15 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 In the long-term, excluding the portion left unresolved (.58% of taxable payroll) and including revenues from expanded coverage, new taxes account for 91% of deficit reduction (not including revenues from expanded coverage, 66%). 9.) It does not provide a specific fail safe mechanism to assure that benefits could continue to be paid on time despite unexpectedly adverse conditions which occur with little advance notice. (See point #3) The list of options which I would now like to present do meet the tests and/or constraints previously described in this statement. While these options do address the basic causes of both the short-range and long-term problems they by no means constitute an all inclusive list. It should be noted that the options do not specify a single solution to either the short-range or the long- term problem, but instead, the list provides several examples of changes, that in combination could resolve the problems facing Social Security more fairly and equitably than those in the Commission report. At the same time, these options avoid violating the basic tenents of Social Security, in that they allow the system to remain self-financing and do not introduce any elements of means- testing. (The bi-partisan approach developed in 1981 by Congressmen Barber Conable and Jake Pickle adopted a combined approach.) Statement (11), page 16 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Some Alternative Options to the Commission Report 1. Coverage of new Federal hires and Federal employees with under 5 years of service, all nonprofit employees, and elimination of windfall benefits (also, prohibit opting out) 2. Suspend COLA adjustment for one year, 1983 3. COLA based on CPI minus 2% for next 3 years' COLAs, with cap on COLA of 6%; thereafter, use "wages minus 1/%" basis 4. Four percent cap for 3 year's COLAS; thereafter, lesser of wage or CPI increase if fund ratio is under 25% (with catch up when fund ratio is over 50%) 5. Provide future benefit increases equal to 75% of the CPI, effective 1983 6. Prorate both CPI and wage increase adjustments in initial OASDI benefit based on month of eligibility, effec- tive 1984. 7. Accelerate State and Local deposits 8. Increase retirement age to 66 in 2002, beginning phase-in in 1995; thereafter, adjust according to changes in longevity. Statement (11), page 17 Short-Term Savings (billions) (1983-89) Long-Term Savings (% of Payroll) (75 Years) $33 .31% 80 .15 75 1.45 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Short-Term Long-Term Savings Savings (billions) (% of payroll) 1983-89 (75 years) 9. Gradually increase the "normal" retire- ment age from 65 to 68 in 2017 beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 2000. 10.Increase "bend points" in the PIA benefit formula by 75% of the increase in wages until they are 80% of what they would have been under 100% wage indexing, effective 2000. 1.22 11.Reduce percentages in PIA benefit formula by 10% relatively, over a 15-year period beginning 1984-98 1 1.10 "Fail-Safe" Mechanism A "fail-safe" mechanism should be provided in the event that the OASDI trust fund ratio falls below a specified level. In the event of the determination of a fund-ratio-deficiency, all benefits due during the coming year should be guaranteed to be sent out on time, but should be proportionately reduced automatically by first affecting any scheduled COLA increase. In the event that the fund-ratio-deficiency exceeded the scheduled COLA increase, then the existing benefit amounts would be reduced proportionately unless Congress acted to provide for the remaining fund-ratio-deficiency through raising payroll tax rates. Statement (11), page 18 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Dec. 16 / Administration of Ronald Reagan, 1981 National Commission on Social Security Reform Executive Order 12335. December 16, 1981 By the authority vested in me as Presi- dent by the Constitution of the United States of America, and to establish, in ac- cordance with the provisions of the Federal Advisory Committee Act, as amended (5 U.S.C. App. I), the National Commission on Social Security Reform, it is hereby ordered as follows: Section 1. Establishment. (a) There is es- tablished the National Commission on Social Security Reform. The Commission shall be composed of fifteen members appointed or designated by the President and selected as follows: (1) Five members selected by the Presi- dent from among officers or employees of the Executive Branch, private citizens of the United States, or both. Not more than three of the members selected by the Presi- dent shall be members of the same political party; (2) Five members selected by the Major- ity Leader of the Senate from among mem- bers of the Senate, private citizens of the United States, or both. Not more than three of the members selected by the Majority Leader shall be members of the same politi- cal party; (3) Five members selected by the Speaker of the House of Representatives from among members of the House, private citi- zens of the United States, or both. Not more than three of the members selected by the Speaker shall be members of the same political party. (b) The President shall designate a Chair- man from among the members of the Com- mission. Sec. 2. Functions. (a) The Commission shall review relevant analyses of the current and long-term financial condition of the Social Security trust funds; indentify prob- lems that may threaten the long-term sol- vency of such funds; analyze potential solu- tions to such problems that will both assure the financial integrity of the Social Security System and the provision of appropriate benefits; and provide appropriate recom- mendations to the Secretary of Health and Human Services, the President, and the Congress. (b) The Commission shall make its report to the President by December 31, 1982. Sec. 3. Administration. (a) The heads of Executive agencies shall, to the extent per- mitted by law, provide the Commission such information as it may require for the purpose of carrying out its functions. (b) Members of the Commission shall serve without any additional compensation for their work on the Commission. How- ever, members appointed from among pri- vate citizens of the United States may be allowed travel expenses, including per diem in lieu of subsistence, as authorized by law for persons serving intermittently in the government service (5 U.S.C. 5701-5707), to the extent funds are available therefor. (c) The Commission shall have a staff headed by an Executive Director. Any ex- penses of the Commission shall be paid from such funds as may be available to the Secretary of Health and Human Services. Sec. 4. General. (a) Notwithstanding any other Executive Order, the responsibilities of the President under the Federal Advi- sory Committee Act, as amended, except that of reporting annually to the Congress, which are applicable to the Commission, shall be performed by the Secretary of Health and Human Services in accordance with the guidelines and procedures estab- lished by the Administrator of General Services. (b) The Commission shall terminate thirty days after submitting its report. Ronald Reagan The White House, December 16, 1981. [Filed with the Office of the Federal Regis- ter, 2:22 p.m., December 16, 1981] National Commission on Social Security Reform Appointment of the Membership. December 16, 1981 The President today announced his inten- tion to appoint/ designate the following indi- Weekly Compilation of Presidential Documents, Monday, December 21, 1981; Volume 17 -- Number 51; Pages 1371-1394 Appendix A, page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Administration of Ronald Reagan, 1981 / Dec. 16 viduals to serve on a 15-member bipartisan National Commission on Social Security Reform. Alan Greenspan will serve as Chairman. Establishment of the Commission fulfills a pledge made by the President in Septem- ber to create a bipartisan task force to work with the President and Congress to reach two specific goals: -To propose realistic, long-term reforms to put social security back on a sound financial footing, and -To forge a working, bipartisan consen- sus so that the necessary reforms can be passed into law. Robert A. Beck, chairman of the board and chief executive officer, Prudential Insurance Co. of America, Newark, NJ. He is a member of the President's Export Council. Mary Falrey Fuller, vice president, finance, Shak- lee Corp., San Francisco, Calif. Previously she was senior vice president and director, Blyth Eastman Dillon & Co., Inc., New York, N.Y. Alan Green.epan, chairman and president, Town- send-Greenspan and Co., Inc., New York, N.Y. He is a member of the President's Economic Policy Advisory Board. Alexander B. Trowbridge, president, National As- sociation of Manufacturers, Washington, D.C. He is a member of the President's Task Force on Private Sector Initiatives. Joe D. {iaggonner, Jr., consultant, Bossier Bank & Trust Co., Plain Dealing. La He represented the Fourth Congressional District of Louisiana during the 87th to 95th Congresses. Senate Majority Leader Howard Baker, in consultation with Senate Minority Leader Robert B%Td, selected the following individ- uals to serve on the Commission: William Armstrong, United States Senate (R- Colo.), chairman of the Subcommittee on Social Security of the Senate Finance Committee. Robert Dole, United States Senate (R-Kans.), chairman of the Senate Finance Committee. John Heinz, United States Senate (R-Pa.), chair- man of the Senate Special Committee on Aging. Lane Kirkland, president of the American Fed- eration of Labor-Congress of Industrial Organi- zations. Daniel Patrick Moynihan, United States Senate (D-N.Y.), ranking minority member of the Sub- committee on Social Security of the Senate Fi- nance Committee. House Speaker Thomas P. O'Neill, in con- sultation with House Minority Leader Robert Michel, selected the following indi- viduals to serve on the Commission: William Archer, United States House of Repre- sentatives (R-Tex.), ranking minority member of the Subcommittee on Social Security, House Ways and Means Committee. Robert M. Ball, was Commissioner of Social Se- curity in 1962-73. He is senior scholar, Insti- tute of Medicine, National Academy of Sci- ences. Barber Conable, United States House of Repre- sentatives (R-N.Y.), ranking minority member, House Ways and Means Committee. Martha E Keys, former Assistant Secretary of Health and Human Services. She served in the 94th and 95th Congresses. Claude D. Pepper, United States House of Repre- sentatives (D-Fla.), chairman, House Select Committee on Aging. Weekly Compilation of Presidential Documents, Monday, December 21, 1981; Volume 17 -= Number 51; Pages 1371-1394 Appendix A, page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Federal Register Vol. 47, No. 249 Tuesday, December 28, 1982 Presidential Documents The President National Commission on Social Security Reform By the authority vested in me as President by the Constitution and laws of the United States of America, and specifically the Federal Advisory Committee Act, as amended (5 U.S.C. App. I), it is hereby ordered that Section 2(b) of Executive Order No. 12335, establishing the National Commission on Social Security Reform, is hereby amended to provide as follows: "The Commission shall make its report to the President by January 15, 1983.". THE WHITE HOUSE, December 23, 1982. IFR Doc. 82-35230 Filed 12-23-82; 1:21 pm] Billing code 3195-01-M Appendix A, page 3 396-938 0 - 83 - 10 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 For Immediate Release January 15, 1983 NATIONAL COMMISSION ON SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM By the authority vested in me as President by the Constitution and laws of the United States of America, and specifically the Federal Advisory Committee Act, as amended (5 U.S.C. App. I), it is hereby ordered that Section 2(b) of Executive Order No. 12335, as amended, establishing the National Commission on Social Security Reforn, is hereby further amended to provide as follows: "The Commission shall make its report t3 the President by January 20, 1983.". THE WHITE HOUSE, January 15, 1983. Executive Order 12402 (January 15, 1983) Appendix A, page 4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Administration of Ronald Reagan, 1981 / Dec. 16 As a candidate in 1980 1 pledged that I would do my utmost to restore the integrity of social security and do so without penalty to those dependent on that program. I have honored that pledge and will continue to do so. We cannot and we will not betray people entitled to social security benefits. In September I announced that I would appoint a bipartisan task force to work with the President and the Congress to reach two specific goals: propose realistic, long- term reforms to put social security back on a sound financial footing and forge a work- ing bipartisan consensus so that the neces- sary reforms will be passed into law. Senate Majority Leader Baker, Speaker O'Neill, and I agreed we would each select five members for a new national commis- sion on social security. Today I am pleased and honored to announce the formation of the commission and that Alan Greenspan has agreed at my request to serve as Chair- man of that commission. I'm asking the commission to present its report to the American people at the end of next year. I can think of no more important domestic problem requiring resolution than the future of our social security system. Let me make one thing plain: With bi- partisan cooperation and political courage, social security can and will be saved. For too long, too many people dependent on social security have been cruelly frightened by individuals seeking political gain through demagoguery and outright falsehood, and National Commission on Social Security this must stop. The future of social security Reform is much too important to be used as a politi- cal football. Remarks Announcing Establishment of the Commission. December 16, 1981 In recent years inflation has created great uncertainty about our social security system. Time and again we've been reas- sured the system would be financially sound for decades to come, only to find that recal- culations of receipts and benefits forecast a new crisis. Current and future retirees now question the system's ability to provide them the benefits they've been led to expect. Americans look to us for leadership and for answers. Saving social security will require the best efforts of both parties and of both the ex- ecutive and legislative branches of govern- ment. I'm confident this can be done and that in its deliberations this commission will put aside partisan considerations and seek a solution the American people will find fis- cally sound and fully equitable. That's the end of the statement. Note: The President spoke at 12:03 p.m. to reporters assembled in the Briefing Room at the White House. Weekly Compilation of Presidential Documents, Monday, December 21, 1981; Volume 17 -- Number 51; Pages 1371-1394 Appendix B Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 C H A R T E R National Commission on Social Security Reform Purpose The National Commission on Social Security Reform was established by Executive Order No. 12335 on December 16, 1981 to provide appropriate recommendations to the Secretary of Health and Human Services, the President, and the Congress on long-term reforms to put Social Security back on a sound financial footing. Authority The National Commission on Social Security Reform was established by Executive Order of the President on December 16, 1981 (Executive Order 12335), and is governed by the provisions of the Federal Advisory Committee Act, (5 U.S.C. App. I; 86 stat. 770) which sets forth standards for the formation and use of advisory committees. Function The National Commission on Social Security shall: (1) review relevant analyses of the current and long-term financial condition of the Social Security trust funds; (2) identify problems that may threaten the long-term solvency of such funds; (3) analyze potential solutions to such problems that will both assure the financial integrity of the Social Security System and the provision of appropriate benefits; and (1+) provide appropriate recommendations to the Secretary of Health and Human Services, the President, and the Congress. Structure The Commission shall be composed of fifteen members appointed or designated by the President and selected as follows: (1) Five members selected by the President from among officers or employees of the Executive Branch, private citizens of the United States, or both. Not more than three of the members selected by the President shall be-members of the same political party; Appendix C, page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 (2) Five members selected by the majority leader of the Senate from among members of the Senate, private citizens of the United States, or both. Not more than three of the members selected by the Majority Leader shall be members of the same political party; (3) Five members selected by the Speaker of the House of Representatives from among members of the House, private citizens of the United States, or both. Not more than three of the members selected by the Speaker shall be members of the same political party. The President shall designate a Chairman from among the members of The Commission. The Commission shall have a staff headed by an Executive Director. Any expenses of the Commission shall be paid from such funds as may be available to the. Secretary of Health and Human Services. Notwithstanding any other Executive Order, the responsibilities of the President under the Federal Advisory Committee Act, as amended, except that of reporting annually to the Congress, which are applicable to the Commission, shall be performed by the Secretary of Health and Human Services in accordance with the guidelines and procedures established by the Administrator of General Services. Meetings Meetings are held approximately once a month at the call of the Chairman, who approves the agenda. A Government official is present at all meetings. Meetings are open to the public except as determined otherwise by the Secretary; notice of all meetings is given to the public. Meetings are conducted and records of the proceedings kept, as required by applicable laws and Department regulations. Compensation Members of the Commission shall serve without any additional compensation for their work on the Commission. However, members appointed from among private citizens of the United States may be allowed travel expenses, including per diem in lieu of subsistence, as authorized by law for persons serving intermittently in the Government service (5 U.S.C. 5701-5707), to the extent funds are available therefor. Appendix C, page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Subject to the availability of funds, the estimated cost for operating the Commission, including travel expenses for members, but excluding staff support, is $300,000 to $700,000. Estimate of man-years of staff support required is 10 to 15, at an estimated cost of $325,000 to $525,000, totaling an estimated cost of $625,000 to $1,225,000. Reports The Commission shall make its report to the President by December 31, 1982. The Commission shall terminate thirty days after submitting its report. Approved: ,6 82_ Date Ric Secretary Appendix C, page 3 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 February 27, 1982 Dear Chairman Greenspan and Commission Members: As you convene for the first time today, the Nation will be watching with great interest the work and progress of the National Commission on Social Security Reform. As I wrote to you at the time you agreed to serve, I can think of no more important domestic problem requiring reso- lution than restoring the integrity of Social Security and to do so without penalty to those dependent on the programs. Every American, of every age, has an important stake in the success of your work. Each of you comes to this Commission from a position in gov- ernment or the private sector through which you can make possible the successful implementation of a truly bipartisan solution to this great national problem. This Commission is the product of the leadership of both parties of both houses of the Congress as much as it is mine. Therefore, on'behalf of all Americans I wish you success as you begin your deliberations. Sincerely, e %--~ (Lo-~ Chairman Alan Greenspan and Members of the National Commission on Social Security Reform Appendix D Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 MEETINGS OF THE NATIONAL COMMISSION SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM Date Time Saturday, February 27 10:00 a.m. - 2:00 p.m. Friday, March 26 9:00 a.m. - 1:00 p.m. Monday, May 10 1:00 p.m. - 5:00 p.m. Monday, June 21 2:00 p.m. - 6:00 p.m. Monday, July 19 2:00 p.m. - 6:00 p.m. Friday, August 20 9:00 a.m. - 1:00 p.m. Monday, September 20 2:00 p.m. - 6:00 p.m. Thursday, Friday, and Saturday, November 11-13 10:00 a.m. - 5:00 p.m. Friday, December 10 2.00 p.m. - 5:00 p.m. Appendix E Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 STAFF MEMORANDUMS PREPARED FOR THE NATIONAL COMMISSION ON SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM Staff Memorandum, Latest Cost Estimates for OASDI and HI Programs, February 26, 1982 Staff Memorandum, Development of the Social Security Program, February 27, 1982 Memorandum No. 1, Basic Method of Computing Social Security Benefits, March 9, 1982 Memorandum No. 2, History of Replacement Rates for Various Amendments to Social Security Act, March 10, 1982 Memorandum No. 3, Measurement of Actuarial Status of OASDI Program, March 11, 1982 Memorandum No. 4, Survey as to Valuation Period for OASDI and HI Programs, March 12, 1982 Memorandum No. 5, Annual Actuarial Balances of the Social Security Program, March 13, 1982 Memorandum No. 6, Progress of OASDI Trust Funds over the Years, March 14, 1982 Memorandum No. 7, Sensitivity Analysis of Assumptions in Alternative I and II-B of 1981 Trustees Report, March 15, 1982 Memorandum No. 8, Actuarial Status of OASDI Program over Next 25 Years under Alternative Assumptions, March 16, 1982 Memorandum No. 9, Analysis of Various Marginal Changes in Assumptions in Actuarial Cost Estimates, March 25, 1982 Memorandum No. 10, Short-Range Cost Estimates Made by CBO, March 29, 1982 Memorandum No. 11, Reimbursements to the Social Security Trust Funds from General Revenues, April 6, 1982 Memorandum No. 12, Comparison of Status of OASDI and HI Trust Funds as Shown in 198 and 1982 Trustees Reports, April 6, 1982 Memorandum No. 13, Survey of Public Confidence as to Financial Status of the Social Security Program, April 7, 1982 Appendix F, page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Memorandum No. 14, History of Net Replacement Rates for Various Amendments to the Social Security Act, April 22, 1982 Memorandum No. 15, Past Trends of Actuarial Imbalances of OASDI and HI Trust Funds, April 7, 1982 Memorandum No. 16, Possible Method of Revising Social Security to a Self- Adjusting, Self-Stabilizing Basis, April 29, 1982 Memorandum No. 17, Background Information on Private Pensions, May 4, 1982 Principal Consultant Memorandum, Problem Areas in Private Pensions and State and Local Government Pensions, May 4, 1982 Memorandum No. 18, Analysis of Various Marginal Changes in Assumptions in Actuarial Cost Estimates, May 6, 1982 Memorandum No. 19, Possible Method of Revising Social Security to a Self- Adjusting Self-Stabilizing Basis (continued), May 27, 1982 Memorandum No. 20, The Low-Cost Demographic Period in the 1990s and Early 2000s, May 25, 1982 Memorandum No. 21, Further Information on Cost of OASDI Program According to 1982 Trustees Report, May 27, 1982 Memorandum No. 22, Increasing the Normal Retirement Age Under Social Security by an Automatic-Adjustment Method, June 4, 1982 Memorandum No. 23, How a Proposal for Automatic Changes in OASDI Tax Rates Would Operate, June 4, 1982 Memorandum No. 24, Possible Solutions to Long-Range Financing Problems of OASDI Program, June 4, 1982 Memorandum No. 25, Prevalence of Elections of Joint-and-Survivor Annuities under Private Pensions, June 7, 1982 Memorandum No. 26, Possible Method of Revising Social Security to a Self- Adjusting, Self-Stabilizing Basis (continued #2), June 4, 1982 Memorandum No. 27, Pension Receipt and Pension Coverage by Sex, June 14, 1982 Memorandum No. 28, Illustrative Cost Effects on Year-by-Year Basis for Several Proposals Affecting OASDI Long-Range Costs, June 21, 1982 Memorandum No. 29, Cost Aspects of Increasing the Normal Retirement Age under ooial Security by an Automatic-Adjustment Method, June 28, 1982 Appendix F, page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Memorandum No. 30, Investment Procedures for the Social Security Trust Funds, June 28, 1982 Memorandum No. 31, Changes in Tax Treatment of Employee Contributions to Social Security and of Benefits and Faster Implementation of Currently Scheduled Payroll Tax Increases, July 1, 1982 Memorandum No. 32, Advantages of Social Security Coverage for Federal Employees, June JU_ 1982 Memorandum No. 33, Relative Changes in Social Security Benefit Levels, June 30, 1982 Memorandum No. 34, Constitutionality of Prohibiting Withdrawal of Nonprofit Organizations Which Elected Social Security Coverage, July 1, 1982 Memorandum No. 35, Various Possible Funding Methods for OASDI Program, July 1, 1982 Memorandum No. 36, Cost Aspects of Indexing OASDI Benefit Formula by 75% of Wage Increases for a Limited Period, July 2, 1982 Memorandum No. 37, Comparison of Social Security Benefits and Replacement Rates Under Present Law and Under Proposal to Index Benefit Formula by'75% of Wage Increases for a Limited Period, July 12, 1982 Memorandum No. 38, Long-Range Cost Effect of Advancing the 1990 OASDI Tax Rate to 1983 or 1985, August 2, 1982 Memorandum No. 39, Ways in Which Civil Service Retirement System Provides Greater Benefit Protection Than Social Security, July 29, 1982 Memorandum No. 40, Crediting Unnegotiated Social Security Checks to the Trust Funds, July 30, 1982 Memorandum No. 41, Pros and Cons Regarding Proposals to Dedicate Alcohol and Tobacco Excise Taxes to Hospital Insurance or Disability Insurance Trust Funds, August 4, 1982 Memorandum No. 42, Earnings Sharing at Divorce under Social Security Programs in Canada and Germany, August 5, 1982 Memorandum No. 43, The Effects of Redeeming Trust Fund Assets, August 6, 1982 Memorandum No. 44, The Relative Economic Status of the "Young-Old" and the "Old- Old", August 12, 1982 Appendix F, page 3 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Memorandum No. 45, Money's-Worth Comparison for Social Security Benefits, August 12, 1982 Memorandum No. 46, Recent Legislation Passed by Congress, September 1, 1982 Memorandum No. 47, "Personal Security Accounts: A Proposal for Fundamental Social Security Reform", by Boskin, Kotlikoff, and Shoven, September 1,1982 Memorandum No. 48, An Independent Social Security Agency, September 1, 1982 Memorandum No. 49, Conceptual Difference Between the Open-Group and Closed-Group Methods of Determining the OASDI Long-Range Unfunded Liability, September 1, 1982 Memorandum No. 50, Adjusting the Payroll Tax Rate to Compensate for the Erosion of the Tax Base Due to the Growth of Fringes, September 7, 1982 Memorandum No. 51, Amounts Needed in Short Run to Restore Financial Soundness of OASDI System, and Possibility of Obtaining Them from Increases in Tax Rates, September 9, 1982 Memorandum No. 52, Actuarial Cost Estimates of the Early 1970s in the Light of Current Conditions, September 8, 1982 Memorandum No. 53, Inclusion of Operations of Social Security and Medicare Trust Funds in the Unified Budget, September 8, 1982 Memorandum No. 54, Additional Information on CBO Estimate of Outlay Reductions and/or Revenue Increases Needed by OASDI Program in FY 1984 and 1985, September 9, 1982 Table, Comparison Of Combined Employer-Employee OASDI Tax Rate With OASDI Cost Rate For Various Future Years Under Different Economic Assumptions, September 28, 1982 Memorandum No. 55, Comparison of Two Alternative Wage Rate Measures That Could be Used in Indexing Social Security Benefits, September 29, 1982 Memorandum No. 56, Cost Effect of Increasing Contribution Rate for Self-Employed Persons to Combined Employer-Employee Rate, October 8, 1982 Memorandum No. 57, Reconciliation of Cost Estimates of CBO and SSA as to Amount of Additional Funding Needed by OASDI Trust Funds in 1982-85 in Order to Have Specified Fund Ratio at Beginning of 1986, October 14, 1982 Memorandum No. 58, The Effect of a Combination of Proposals on OASDI Long-Range Costs Assuming (1) Revocation of the 1985 and 1990 Tax Rate Increases or (2) Revocation of Only the 1990 Increase, October 15, 1982 Appendix F, page 4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Memorandum No. 59, Investment of the Social Security Trust Funds, October 20, 1982 Memorandum No. 60, Selected Temporary Sources of Revenues for the OASI Trust Fund for the 1980s, November 2, 1982 Memorandum No. 61, Number of Months Required for Total Benefit Payments to Exceed Accumulated OASDI Taxes, November 4, 1982 Memorandum No. 62, Amounts Needed in Short Run to Restore Financial Soundness of OASDI System Under "More Realistic" Pessimistic Cost Estimates, November 5, 1982 Background Book, Actuarial Cost Estimates for OASDI and HI and for Various Possible Changes in OASDI and Historical Data for OASDI and HI, November 1982 Table, Various Packages Which Will Meet the Shortfall in 1983-89, According to Alternative III Assumptions of 1982 Trustees Report, November 10, 1982 Tables, Comparison of Estimates of OASDI Income, Outgo, and Trust-Fund Balances Made by Social Security Administration and by Department of Commerce, November 10, 1982 Memorandum No. 63 (Revised), Methods to Assure Adequate Financing of OASDI Program Through Loans or Through Automatic Adjustment of Either Benefits or Taxes, November 22, 1982 Memorandum No. 64, Amounts Needed in Short Run to Restore Financial Soundness of OASDI System Under "More Realistic" Pessimistic Cost Estimates (extension of Memorandum No. 62), November 18, 1982 Decision Memorandum, Adoption of Certain Recommendations, December 3, 1982 General Memorandum, Section 401(k) of the Internal Revenue Code, December 9, 1982 General Memorandum, A Proposal to Index Benefits in Eligibility Status by Increases in Wages Minus 12 Percentage Points, on a 15-Year Moving-Total Basis, December 9, 1982 Decision Memorandum, Adoption of Certain Recommendations (Revision and extension of Memorandum of December 3), December 13, 1982 Memorandum No. 65, Two Proposals as to Stabilizing the Cost of the OASDI Program With Regard to the Indexing of Benefits in Eligibility Status (Revised), December 15, 1982 Appendix F, page 5 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Memorandum No. 66, Dilemma of Making Cost Estimates for Indexing by "Lesser of Wages or Prices", December 15, 1982 Decision Memorandum, Adoption of Recommendation on Extension of Coverage, December 15, Appendix F, page 6 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 PAPERS PRESENTED TO THE NATIONAL COMMISSION ON SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM Alicia H. Munnell, "The Private Pension System and Its Role in Providing Economic Security", May 10, 1982 Quentin I. Smith, Jr., "The Private Pension System and Its Role in Providing Economic Security", May 10, 1982 Robert N. Butler, "Note for Discussions Before the National Commission on Social Security Reform", June 21, 1982 Jacob J. Feldman, "Work Ability of the Aged Under Conditions of Improving Mortality", June 21, 1982 Nancy M. Gordon, "Statement Before the National Commission on Social Security Reform", July 19, 1982 Alice M. Rivlin, "Statement Before the National Commission on Social Security Reform", August 20, 1982 Henry Aaron, "Summary of Remarks to the National Commission on Social Security Reform", August 20, 1982 Michael J. Boskin, "Alternative Social Security Reform Proposals", August 20, 1982 Appendix G Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 STAFF MEMBERS OF THE NATIONAL COMMISSION ON SOCIAL SECURITY REFORM Executive Director Robert J. Myers Nancy J. Altman Merton C. Bernstein E. Annette Coates Suzanne B. Dilk Renato A. DiPentima Susan A. Dower Elizabeth T. Duskin Timothy J. Kelley Eric R. Kingson Edward F. Moore Virginia P. Reno Bruce D.Schobel Carolyn L. Weaver Support Staff Laurie A. Brown Ercell C. Campbell Elisabeth J. Darling Wanda G. Moody Edward E. Mosley Tracey A. O'Donnell Isabel R. Paurowski Carol J. Upperman Doris C. Washington NOTE: Some of these individuals were on the staff for only part of the duration of the National Commission, and some were part-time employees. Appendix H Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Average Indexed Monthly Earnings (AIME) -- The earnings used to determine the Primary Insurance Amount, on which benefits for a worker and family will be based. Earnings for each year after 1950 are updated (indexed) to the indexing year (the second year before the year in which the worker becomes age 62 or, if earlier, becomes disabled or dies) to take account of the increase in average wages since the year that they were earned. Earnings for the indexing year and subsequent years are used at their actual values. Then, the highest years of indexed earnings for a specified number of years are selected and averaged to yield the AIME. Primary Insurance Amount (PIA) -- The amount on which all monthly OASDI benefits are based. A worker's PIA is derived from Average Indexed Monthly Earnings by applying it in a weighted benefit formula. Such formula for persons reaching age 62 in 1983 (or dying or becoming disabled before age 62 in 1983) is 90% of the first $254 of AIME, plus 32% of the next $1,274 of AIME, plus 15% of AIME in excess of $1,528. For persons attaining age 62 in subsequent years, the dollar figures are changed to reflect relative changes in nationwide average wages. A worker's disability benefit or old-age benefit at age 65 is equal to 100% of PIA. Other benefits are various percentages of the worker's PIA. Maximum Family Benefit -- The maximum monthly amount that can be paid on a worker's earnings record. Whenever the amount of benefits payable on an earnings record exceeds the maximum, each auxiliary or survivor benefit is proportionately reduced to bring the total within the maximum. (Benefits for divorced spouses and surviving divorced spouses are excluded from this limit.) Replacement Rate -- The worker's benefit (or the family benefit) as a percentage of prior earnings. If a worker earned $500 a month before retirement and receives a benefit of $350, the replacement rate is 70%. Generally, the replacement rate is the relationship between the annual benefit rate payable for the first month of entitlement and the gross taxable earnings for the year before entitlement. However, in some contexts, it may be the relationship between the benefit and net after-tax earnings for the prior year. (In other contexts, the benefits payable for the first full year of entitlement, including any CPI increase for June and thereafter, are used as the numerator.) Bend Points -- The points in the PIA benefit formula at which the percentage factor that is applicable to the AIME changes. For example, in the formula for those reaching age 62 in 1983, these points are $254 and $1,528. The percentages applicable are 90%, 32%, and 15%. When developing the formula for persons attaining age 62 in subsequent years, the percentages remain constant, but the dollar figures are changed to reflect relative changes in nationwide average wages. Trust-Fund Ratio -- The trust-fund balance expressed as a percentage of total outgo during the next 12 months. Cost Rate -- The outgo for benefits and administrative expenses for a year expressed as a percentage of the payroll that is taxable for Social Security purposes for that year. Appendix I Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Appendix J As a background for the discussion of the extent of the financing problems of the Old-Age and Survivors Insurance program (OASI), and recommendations for dealing with them, this appendix will deal with the operational procedures of the Social Security trust funds, their funding bases, the measures of actuarial or financial soundness, and the past and estimated future financial status of each trust fund. There are four Social Security trust funds -- the OASI Trust Fund, the Disability Insurance Trust Fund (DI), the Hospital Insurance Trust Fund (HI), and the Supplementary Medical Insurance Trust Fund (SMI). The National Commission has considered almost exclusively the first three of these trust funds, which are financed primarily from payroll taxes. The SMI Trust Fund deals with that portion of the Medicare program which primarily provides partial reimbursement for the cost of physician services; it derives its financing from premiums paid by the enrollees and from payments from the General Fund of the Treasury. NOTE: This appendix was prepared by Robert J. Myers, Executive Director. Any views expressed herein are those of Mr. Myers, and not necessarily those of the members of the National Commission. Appendix J, page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 OPERATIONAL PROCEDURES OF THE TRUST FUNDS All four of the trust funds function as separate, closed entities. All sources of their financing (including any interest earned on their invested assets) go into the funds, and all benefit payments and related administrative expenses are paid from them. As a general principle, if a particular trust fund has insufficient assets to meet outgo, there is no way under the permanent law that it can borrow from any of the other three trust funds or from the General Fund of the Treasury. (A temporary borrowing authority, which exists for 1982 only, will be discussed later.) Any assets of the trust funds which are not needed for immediate payment of benefits or administrative expenses are invested in interest-bearing government obligations, and relatively small working cash balances are maintained. The income from payroll taxes for the OASI, DI, and HI Trust Funds tends to be spread rather evenly throughout each month (although not equally throughout the months of the year, with somewhat more being collected in the early months than in the later ones, due to the effect of the maximum taxable earnings base). The vast majority of the benefit payments from the OASI and DI Trust Funds are made at the beginning of each month. In contrast, the outgo of the HI and SMI Trust Funds tends to be more or less evenly spread throughout the month. Appendix J, page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 As a result of these different flows of income and outgo, the three trust funds which are supported primarily by payroll taxes have somewhat different financial situations during the month. The OASI and DI Trust Funds must have sufficient assets during the first few days of each month to meet the full amount of monthly benefit checks sent out then. Benefit checks cannot be transmitted to the beneficiaries unless sufficient payroll-tax and other income has been received to build up the trust-fund balance to the necessary level. The HI Trust Fund need have only a very small balance at the beginning of the month in order to reimburse hospitals and other providers of services in a proper manner, because both its income and outgo are evenly spread throughout the month. The SMI Trust Fund, too, need have only a very small balance at the end of each month, because it receives the vast majority of its enrollee-premium income at the beginning of the month (through automatic deductions from monthly OASDI benefit checks). FUNDING PROCEDURES FOR THE TRUST FUNDS Under present law, the OASI, DI, and HI Trust Funds are financed almost entirely from the OASDI-HI taxes levied on employers, employees, and the self-employed. Eacn or these trust funds receives relatively small payments from the General Fund of the treasury as reimbursement for the cost of benefits Appendix J, page 3 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 for certain special closed groups of persons.!/ This self-supporting financing principle has, on the whole, been applicable to the OASI, DI, and HI programs ever since their inception. For a short period in the late 1940s, the financing basis was rather indeterminate, because provision was made for payments from the General Fund of the Treasury, if needed. This provision was never used, and it was repealed in 1950. In the early years, the OASI program was funded on a modified-reserve basis. It was intended that a sizable fund would be built up, so that interest earnings could help to finance the outgo. This basis would by no means result in a "fully-funded" system. Over the years, the original emphasis on building up and maintaining a large fund was reduced. Gradually, the funding basis shifted, in practice, to what might be called a current-cost or pay-as-you-go basis. The intent under such a basis is that income and outgo should be approximately equal each year and that a fund balance should be maintained which will be only large enough to meet cyclical fluctuations both within the year and also over economic cycles which have durations of several years. There is no established rule as to the desirable size of a contingency fund, although the general view is that it should be an amount equal to between 6 and 12 months' outgo. The financial status of the OASI, DI, and HI Trust Funds has always been evaluated over a long future period. For the OASI and DI Trust Funds, 75 years Appendix J, page 4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 is used (although prior to 1965, a longer period -- namely, into perpetuity -- was used). The valuation period for the HI program is 25 years, although estimates for a 75-year period have been made. The shorter valuation period for the HI program was adopted because of the greater uncertainty about future trends of hospital costs. The actuarial valuation of the SMI program is on an entirely different basis, because it is, in essence, a "one-year term" plan. The valuation procedure used compares the assets on hand with the accrued, but unpaid claims (and associated administrative expenses). MEASURES OF ACTUARIAL OR FINANCIAL SOUNDNESS Several measures have been developed to determine the actuarial status or financial soundness of the programs. Some of these relate essentially to the short-range period (the next 5-10 years), whereas others relate to the valuation period used for the particular program. Short-Range Measures of Soundness Undoubtedly, the primary measure of short-range soundness is that the particular trust fund should always have at least enough assets to meet current expenditures. Appendix J, page 5 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 A measure frequently used for measuring both the short-range and long-range financial status of the OASI, DI, and HI Trust Funds is the "fund ratio". This is defined as the trust-fund balance at the end of a month expressed as a percentage of total outgo during the next 12 months.?/ It is usually stated that the OASI and DI Trust Funds must have fund ratios of at least 8% or 9% as the minimum possible for monthly benefits to be paid on time. Much more desirably, the "bare minimum" size should not be below some higher figure, such as 15% (or perhaps 20%) so as to provide a "cushion" against the effects of adverse economic conditions. The 8-9% figure for the OASI and DI Trust Funds is derived from the fact that, if outgo during the year were spread equally over each month, the monthly disbursements would be 8-1/3% of annual outgo. Accordingly, this amount would have to be on hand at the beginning of the year in order to meet the benefit payments due in a few days.3/ Benefit outgo tends to rise during a calendar year (primarily because of the automatic increase in benefits for June and the gradual growth of the number of persons on the benefit rolls). Also, in the early months of a calendar year, tax income tends to be relatively higher than in later months of the year (due to the effect of the maximum taxable earnings base and the payment of a relatively large portion of the self-employment taxes in April). Accordingly, the fund ratio could be as low as 7% at the beginning of a year, and yet the program could meet all of its benefit obligations as they fall due if the level of tax income during the year (which does not enter into the computation of the Appendix J, page 6 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 fund ratio) is sufficiently high. This could occur either because of an increase in the tax rate or because of better economic conditions. The crucial factor under such circumstances would be the fund ratio which would be reached at the end of the year, which should be at a level of at least 8-9%. The minimum fund ratio for the HI Trust Fund can be considerably lower than the 9% used as the standard for the OASI and DI Trust Funds. It could be argued that a relatively large fund ratio for the HI Trust Fund might be desirable, because of the somewhat greater possible cost fluctuations and uncertainties of this program as compared with the OASDI program. However, the minimum fund ratio at the beginning of a year needed in order to assure prompt reimbursement of providers of services can be as little as 1% -- as long as, in the coming year, tax income will be at least as large as outgo during the year.!/ Long-Range Measures One measure of the long-range financial status of the OASI, DI, and HI Trust Funds is to compare the "average cost rate" with the "average tax rate" over the valuation period. The "cost rate" for any particular year is the outgo for benefits and administrative expenses expressed as a percentage of effective taxable payroll.5/ The "average cost rate" is the sum of the annual cost rates for the valuation period divided by the number of years therein. Similarly, the "average tax rate" is the average of the combined employer-employee tax rates for each of the years in the valuation period. When the average cost rate Appendix J, page 7 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 exceeds the average tax rate for the valuation period, there is a lack of actuarial balance, expressed as a percentage of taxable payroll. FINANCIAL STATUS OF OASI AND DI TRUST FUNDS This section will examine the financial status of the OASI and DI Trust Funds in past years, their current status, and their outlook over both the short range and the long range. Past Operations Table 1 shows the year-end balances of each of the four trust funds for various past years. The OASI Trust Fund increased slowly during the early 1970s, reaching a maximum in 1974. Thereafter, its balance decreased steadily. The decline would have been even more rapid in 1980-81 if it had not been for a reallocation of the combined OASDI tax rate, so that a larger proportion went to the OASI Trust Fund (P.L. 96-403, October 9, 1980). As a result, almost $9 billion was, in essence, transferred from the DI Trust Fund to the OASI Trust Fund. At the end of October 1982, the balance in the OASI Trust Fund amounted to $10.0 billion -- about $1 billion less than the amount needed to pay benefits in early November. As a result, the inter-fund borrowing of $.6 billion from the Appendix J, page 8 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 BALANCES IN TRUST FUNDS AT END OF VARIOUS PAST YEARS (in billions) Calendar Year OASI DI OASDI HI SMI Total 1970 $32.5 $5.6 $38.1 $3.2 $.2 $41.5 1971 33.8 6.6 40.4 3.0 .5 43.9 1972 35.3 7.5 42.8 2.9 .6 46.3 1973 36.5 7.9 44.4 6.5 1.1 52.0 1974 37.8 8.1 45.9 9.1 1.5 56.5 1975 37.0 7.4 44.4 10.5 1.4 56.5 1976 35.4 5.7 41.1 10.6 1.8 53.5 1977 32.5 3.4 35.9 10.4 3.1 49.4 1978 27.5 4.2 31.7 11.5 4.4 47.6 1979 24.7 5.6 30.3 13.2 4.9 48.4 1980 22.8 3.6 26.4 13.7 4.5 44.6 1981 21.5 3.0 24.5 18.7 5.9 49.1 08/31/82 14.3 6.3 20.6 20.9 5.8 47.3 09/30/82 12.5 6.8 19.3 20.8 5.8 45.9 10/31/82 10.0 6.9 16.9 20.5 5.9 43.3 Appendix J, page 9 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 DI Trust Fund, authorized by P.L. 97-123 (December 29, 1981), was utilized to make up the difference. In early December, $3.4 billion was borrowed from the HI Trust Fund. In late December, an additional $13.5 billion was borrowed -- $4.5 billion from the DI Trust Fund, and the remainder from the HI Trust Fund. From this time on (until corrective legislative action is taken), the OASI Trust Fund will, in fact, have a negative balance in at least part of each month -- when the assets on hand are measured against the outstanding loans from the DI and HI Trust Funds. It was not at all unexpected that borrowing would occur in late 1982. In fact, the 1982 OASDI Trustees Report contains estimates which indicate that the total borrowing of the OASI Trust Fund from the DI and HI Trust Funds during 1982 would amount to about $7-11 billion. The actual amount borrowed in 1982 was $17.5 billion. Almost all of this will be utilized in the first six months of 1983, because the legislative action permitted no more to be borrowed in 1982 than would be necessary to meet the estimated outgo requirements through June 1983. The DI Trust Fund had a balance of $7.5 billion at the end of 1972, but this decreased steadily thereafter, reaching $3.4 billion at the end of 1977. Then, as a result of the reallocation of the OASDI tax rate in the 1977 Amendments (P.L. 95-216) to give more of the OASDI tax rate to the DI Trust Fund (as discussed in more detail later), the balance increased -- reaching $5.6 billion at the end of 1979. Such balance was lower at the end of both 1980 and Appendix J, page 10 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 1981, as a result of the further revised allocation of the OASDI tax rate for 1980-81 mentioned previously -- reaching $3.0 billion at the end of 1981. The DI Trust Fund increased during most of 1982 and had a balance of $6.9 billion on October 31. However, by the end of the year its working balance (considering only investments and cash accounts) was lower -- as a result of the loans made to the OASI Trust Fund. From an accounting standpoint, however, the assets of the DI Trust Fund should include the amount of such loans, and so its "true" year-end balance will be significantly higher than its balance on October 31. The balance in the OASI Trust Fund at the beginning of 1970 was approximately equal to annual outgo -- i.e., a fund ratio of about 100% (see Table 2). The fund ratio steadily decreased thereafter, reaching 15% at the beginning of 1982. In the absence of inter-fund borrowing -- or, equivalently, if the loans from the DI and HI Trust Funds were paid back at the beginning of 1983 -- the fund ratio then would be only about 4-6% (which would be insufficient to pay benefits on time). The DI Trust Fund had a fund ratio of 126% at the beginning of 1970. This fell to 26% at the beginning of 1978 and then rose to 35% at the beginning of 1980. As a result of the revised allocation of the OASDI tax rate, it decreased to only 16% at the beginning of 1982. However, at the beginning of 1983, the fund ratio would be about 40% if the loans to the OASI Trust Fund are considered as assets. Appendix J, page 11 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 2 TRUST-FUND RATIOS AT BEGINNING OF VARIOUS PAST YEARS Calendar Year OASI DI OASDI HI OASDI-HI 1970 101% 126% 103% 47% 96% 1971 94 140 99 54 93 1972 88 140 93 47 87 1973 75 125 80 40 76 1974 68 110 73 69 73 1975 63 92 66 79 68 1976 54 71 57 77 60 1977 47 48 47 66 50 1978 39 26 37 57 41 1979 30 30 30 54 34 1980 23 35 25 52 29 1981 18 21 18 45 23 1982 15 16 15 53 22 NOTE: The "trust-fund ratio" is the ratio of the balance in the Trust Funds on a particular date to the outgo in the next 12 months. Appendix J, page 12 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Actual Experience in 1978-81 as Compared with Estimates Made in 1977 The 1978 OASDI Trustees Report stated that the 1977 Amendments would "restore the financial soundness of the cash benefit program throughout the remainder of this century and into the early years of the next one." It was further stated that, beginning in 1981, the short-range and medium-range annual deficits of the trust funds would be eliminated. However, this did not occur -- because of the adverse economic conditions during 1979-81, when prices rose more rapidly than wages and unemployment was substantially higher than anticipated (and despite the actual disability experience being more favorable than had been estimated to occur). The intermediate cost estimates for the OASDI Trust Funds that were made in 1977 for the law as then amended showed decreases in the fund balance in 1978-80 (a total drop of $8.0 billion), but a significant build-up in 1981 ($7.4 billion). In actuality, there were decreases of $9.4 billion in 1978-80 and of $1.9 billion in 1981. The pessimistic estimate made in 1977 showed that income and outgo would be in very close balance in 1981-84, but the actual economic conditions have been worse, so that a substantial deficit occurred in 1981 instead, and much larger ones apparently are ahead. Appendix J, page 13 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Short-Range Cost Situation Under present law, the OASI Trust Fund will very likely be unable to pay benefits on time beginning in July 1983. Table 3 compares the income (exclusive of interest payments) and the outgo of the OASI Trust Fund for 1982-90, under the intermediate cost estimate (Alternative II-B) and under the pessimistic cost estimate (Alternative III). Under the intermediate estimate, the deficit of income as against outgo is about $20 billion in most years. Under the pessimistic estimate, the annual deficit increases from about $20 billion in the early years to $55 billion in 1989 (and even in 1990, when there is a higher tax rate, it is $43 billion). The bleak picture for OASI changes somewhat when the DI program is also considered. It will be recalled that, in the 1977 Amendments, the portion of the OASDI tax rate which is allocated to the DI Trust Fund was increased significantly, because of its unfavorable and worsening situation during 1970-75 and the expectation that this adverse trend would continue. Instead, beginning in 1976, the disability experience became more favorable (although this was not recognized in the cost estimates made at the time of the 1977 Amendments). In addition, several legislative changes were made in 1977 and 1980 which resulted in lower costs for the DI program. As a result, the DI Trust Fund had, following 1977, very favorable net-income experience. Appendix J, page 14 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 3 COMPARISON OF INCOME (EXCLUDING INTEREST) AND OUTGO (in billions) OAS I Calendar Net Year Income Outgo Income DI OASDI, Net Net Income Outgo Income Income Alternative II-B Estimate 1982 $124.9 $141.9 -$17.0 $22.3 $18.1 +$4.2 -$12.8 1983 137.4 156.5 -19.1 24.9 19.0 +5.9 -13.2 1984 152.3 173.0 -20.7 27.5 19.9 +7.6 -13.1 1985 172.4 190.9 -18.5 34.4 21.3 +13.1 -5.4 1986 187.8 208.5 -20.7 37.6 22.7 +14.9 -5.8 1987 203.4 226.3 -22.9 40.8 24.2 +16.6 -6.3 1988 220.2 244.5 -24.3 44.1 25.8 +18.3 -6.0 1989 237.3 263.2 -25.9 47.6 27.6 +20.0 -5.9 1990 272.4 282.2 -9.8 58.6 29.4 +29.2 +19.4 Alternative III Estimate 1982 $124.9 $141.9 -$17.1 $22.2 $18.1 +$4.1 -$13.0 1983 134.5 157.7 -23.2 24.3 19.1 +5.2 -18.0 1984 147.3 177.2 -29.9 26.6 20.3 +6.3 -23.6 1985 170.1 199.8 -29.7 33.9 22.2 +11.7 -18.0 1986 188.8 224.0 -35.2 37.8 24.3 +13.5 -21.7 1987 208.3 250.2 -41.9 41.8 26.5 +15.3 -26.6 1988 229.5 277.7 -48.2 46.0 28.9 +17.1 -31.1 1989 252.0 306.8 -54.8 50.5 31.6 +18.9 -35.9 1990 294.6 337.5 -42.9 63.4 34.4 +29.0 -13.9 Appendix J, page 15 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Both the intermediate and pessimistic cost estimates for 1982-90 show that the DI Trust Fund will have steadily increasing annual net income (as shown in Table 3). When the OASI and DI Trust Funds are considered in combination,6/ deficits of income over outgo remain, but of a much smaller magnitude than for the OASI Trust Fund alone. As Table 3 shows, even under the intermediate cost estimate, the net income of the combined OASDI Trust Funds shows deficits during the remainder of the 1980s -- about $13 billion per year in 1982-84 and about $6 billion per year in 1985-89. In 1990, however, with the scheduled increase in the tax rate, a positive net income of almost $20 billion is shown. However, a quite different picture for the combined OASDI Trust Funds during 1982-90 is shown under the pessimistic estimate. The annual deficits are about $20 billion in the early years of the period and increase to $36 billion by 1989. In 1990, even with the tax-rate increase, a deficit of $14 billion is shown. A somewhat more precise way to examine the financial status of the OASI Trust Fund in the 1980s is to consider the increase in tax income -- or, alternatively, the reductions in benefit outgo -- that would be required during the period to reach certain alternative target levels of the fund ratios for the OASDI Trust Funds by the beginning of 1988.x/ Appendix J, page 16 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Tables 4a and 4b present the estimates of the increase in tax income needed for the OASDI Trust Funds -- or, alternatively, the decrease in benefit outgo needed -- according to the intermediate and pessimistic cost estimates of the 1982 Trustees Report. The figures are only slightly different whether there are increases in tax income or decreases in benefit outgo. Table 4c gives similar data for two other pessimistic sets of economic assumptions. To achieve a trust-fund ratio of 15% by 1988 would require additional tax income or decreased benefit outgo (or a combination of both) of about $200 billion under the pessimistic estimate. If a trust-fund ratio of 25% were desired, the corresponding figure would be about $225 billion under the pessimistic estimate. Under the intermediate cost estimate, the corresponding figures are about $75 billion for a 15% fund ratio and $100 billion for a 25% fund ratio. Quite obviously, if the additional financing were provided on the basis of the pessimistic estimate, and if the economic experience is more favorable, the trust-fund ratio which would be obtained by the end of the period would be higher than the target -- a not undesirable result. In some ways, the economic assumptions underlying Alternative III do not seem to be realistic in view of current economic events, because both the assumed CPI and wage increases are relatively high as compared with current experience. Accordingly, it seems desirable to test the effect of lower assumed future increases in the CPI and in wages, but with a pessimistic real-wage differential (as is the case, for example, in Alternative III). Appendix J, page 17 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 ESTIMATED TOTAL INCREASE IN OASDI TAX INCOME REQUIRED DURING 1983-89 TO REACH ALTERNATIVE TARGET LEVELS OF TRUST-FUND RATIOS BY BEGINNING OF 1988, UNDER ALTERNATIVES II-B AND III (IN BILLIONS) 1988 Trust-Fund Ratio of 15% 1988 Trust-Fund Ratio of 25% Calendar Year Alternative II-B Assumptions Alternative III Assumptions Alternative II-B Assumptions Alternative III Assumptions 1983 $22 $26 $24 $27 1984 15 26 20 32 1985 7 20 11 25 rD 1986 8 25 13 30 a 1987 8 30 14 39 1988 8 34 8 35 1989 7 40 8 40 CD 1983-89 75 201 98 00 NOTE: The "trust-fund ratio" is the ratio of the balance in the OASDI Trust Funds on a particular date to the outgo in the next 12 months. NOTE: The figures in this table do not include the repayment of the loan from the HI Trust Fund to the OASI Trust Fund in 1982 (about $5 billion). NOTE: The figures do take into account the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248). Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 N cMOt00iN.Lnt0 t0 C.JC')N(VMI+)qr N 69 N OOr)() -ct C)0 O1 N N .-I '-I .--i 01 69 .--1 C) +3 4-3 C) a 4- 0 .C 0+J M tp (V ON Cr Cr N ?. N N N CV N m RI-r O 4-) C 64 N fo ?~ S- C .--+ O 2 N C) 'O - C i-) LL- E to 0 U +3 S- N N 4- LL S- I-. C O ?- C fo L'I CJ ? a - O +J C 0 cu 4- - Cr 0.- W 4-3 - +-) ?r X C ? C -0 to r N t C) n I -- C) +- a) U C to -= c 0 a, 41 4-3 to E W 3 L 0 4- to N - 0 C) to -C - +d +. U WOO 4Q)- -0 Cl 4-O 3 .-?.I C) cr U C C) I C??- to ?r +- CI +J C 4-) 0 3 C J O C W 3 a) m 00- = 4-) 04-) U ~ 4- 3 ?O N U O ?P- C) (1) I-- to N 0 001 _C .0 +~r a-) O O 4-) 4-) (0 fo -?ti 4-) Un Q N O C, ?.- O C) d j S- C) t () -N 4- to u +-) +-) .C +-J Q -0 to 4J 0 N. n CO CO CO 01 64 ^ C 0 4- S- C O +) 0 -C -' ?r 1 fo (A N +) r- C) 10 (L) ?r N 3 S- C S- U 3 3 3 ?r ?r 4.3 4-) O) LL- ?r- Q) N ?i c S- 4- 4-) 4- 0 fo N C1 C) t n t S- C C) O I?- fo I?- I- I- C) Rgr Ln to f. 0 01 OOOOOOCO 010)01010)0)0) C") Co C1 W W W .~ .--1 .--I .?--1 .-1 .-4 .--I .--1 F- I - I I C) C) CD Appendix J, page 19 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 COMPARISON OF ADDITIONAL FUNDS NEEDED TO BUILD UP FUND RATIO FOR OASDI PROGRAM (in billions) Calendar Year Alternative III Estimate Revised Pessimistic Estimate Commerce Alternative 2 Estimate 1983 $26 $23 $23 1984 26 26 22 1985 20 20 15 1986 25 23 23 1987 30 26 41 1988 34 26 39 1989 40 29 41 1983-89 201 173 205 Appendix J, page 20 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Accordingly, two sets of revised economic assumptions have been prepared. In the first set, the CPI increases in Alternative II-B have been assumed to apply for what might be referred to as the "revised pessimistic" cost estimate, because these CPI increases seem reasonable in light of current conditions (although they may be a little on the high side). It has been assumed that the real-wage differential of Alternative III is then applicable on top of these CPI increases, and from these two elements, the wage increases have been determined. The second set has been prepared by the Department of Commerce at the request of the National Commission. The resulting cost estimates of the additional resources needed are shown in Table 4c. The result under the "revised pessimistic" cost estimate is that $173 billion in additional resources would be necessary in 1983-89 in order to have a viable program and to attain a fund ratio of 15% at the beginning of 1988 and thereafter. Under the Alternative 2 (or pessimistic) estimate of the Department of Commerce, the corresponding figure is $205 billion, which is almost exactly the same as that under the SSA Alternative III estimate. Thus, it may be seen that this is another justification of the $150-200 billion amount agreed to by the National Commission. Long-Range Cost Situation The long-range financial status of the OASDI program will first be considered by looking at the estimated cost rates as compared with the combined Appendix J, page 21 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 employer-employee tax rates, on a year-by-year basis. The National Commission has agreed that the long-range costs to be considered should be based on the intermediate cost estimate. The other cost estimates are discussed here so as to indicate the possible effect of alternative conditions. Under the intermediate cost estimate, beginning in 1990 (when the OASDI tax rate is scheduled to increase significantly, and when a period of favorable demographic conditions is almost certain to occur8/), the cost rates are smaller than the combined employer-employee tax rates (see Table 5). This situation continues for about the next two decades, with the excess generally ranging from about 1% to 12% of taxable payroll. This period has been widely referred to as one when the program will be running large excesses of income over outgo and, as a result, building up large trust-fund balances. A quite different picture is shown for the 1990s and early 2000s under the pessimistic cost estimate. The OASDI tax rate during the 1990s and early 2000s falls short of the cost rate each year by about 2% of taxable payroll (see Table 5). Corresponding figures for the optimistic (Alternative I) estimate are not shown in Table 5 on a year-by-year basis, but they are shown for 25-year periods in Table 6; under this estimate, the OASDI tax rate during the 1990s and early 2000s exceeds the cost rate each year by about 3% of taxable payroll. Appendix J, page 22 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 ESTIMATED COST RATES OF OASDI PROGRAM UNDER ALTERNATIVES II-B AND III AND COMPARISON WITH TAX RATES, 1982-2055 (as percent of taxable payroll) OASDI Alternative II-B Alternative III Calendar Tax Cost Cost Year Ratea/ Rate Differenceb/ Rate Differenceb/ 1982 10.80% 11.78% -.98% 11.83% -1.03% 1985 11.40 11.70 -.30 12.40 -1.00 1990 12.40 11.64 +.76 12.85 -.45 1995 12.40 11.42 +.98 12.97 -.57 2000 12.40 11.03 +1.37 12.82 -.42 2005 12.40 10.95 +1.45 12.97 -.57 2010 12.40 11.53 +.87 13.92 -1.52 2015 12.40 12.82 -.42 15.76 -3.36 2020 12.40 14.44 -2.04 18.17 -5.77 2025 12.40 15.97 -3.57 20.70 -8.30 2030 12.40 16.83 -4.43 22.63 -10.23 2035 12.40 17.02 -4.62 23.94 -11.54 2040 12.40 16.80 -4.40 24.80 -12.40 2045 12.40 16.66 -4.26 25.80 -13.40 2050 12.40 16.72 -4.32 26.93 -14.53 2055 12.40 16.81 -4.41 27.87 -15.47 Averages 1982-2006 12.01 11.37 +.64 12.73 -.72 2007-31 12.40 14.08 -1.68 17.84 -5.44 2032-56 12.40 16.81 -4.41 25.66 -13.26 1982-2056 12.27 14.09 -1.82 18.74 -6.47 a/ For employer and employee combined. b/ Tax rate minus cost rate. Positive differences are referred to as cash-flow surpluses, and negative differences as deficits. NOTE: These estimates do not take into account the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248). If this had been done, the cost rates would have been slightly lower. SOURCE: Tables 27 and 29 of the 1982 OASDI Trustees Report. Appendix J, page 23 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 COMPARISON OF ESTIMATED AVERAGE COST RATE WITH AVERAGE TAX RATE BY ALTERNATIVE AND TRUST FUND [As percent of taxable payroll) Estimated average cost rate by alternative Difference by alternative OAST: 1982.2006..... 9.93 8.64 9.31 10.14 11.37 1.29 0.63 -0.21 -1.44 2007-31......... 10.20 9.84 11.58 12.43 15.83 .36 -1.38 -2.23 -5.63 2032-56......... 10.20 10.58 14.11 15.20 23.60 -.38 -3.91 -5.00 -13.40 19822056... 10.11 9.69 11.66 1259 16.93 .42 -1.55 .2.48 -6.82 Di 1982.2006..... 2.07 1.11 1.16 1.23 1.36 .97 .92 .85 .72 200'-31 2.2C 1.45 1.57 1_65 2.00 75 .63 .55 .20 2032.56..._.... ? 2.20 1.30 1.54 1.61 207 .90 .66 .59 13 1982-2056..... 2.16 1.29 1.42 1.50 1.81 .87 .73 .66 .35 Total 1982-2006..... 12.01 9.75 10.46 11.37 12.73 2.26 1.55 .64 -.72 22007-31......... 12.40 11.30 1315 14.06 17.64 1.10 -75 -1.66 -5.44 2032-56......_. 12.40 11.88 15.65 16.81 25.66 .52 -3.25 -4.41 -13.26 1982-2056..... 12.27 10.98 13.09 14.09 18.74 1.29 -.82 .1.82 -6.47 Note. The definitions of alternatives I. II-A, 11-B. and III, cost rate. tax rate, and taxable payroll are presen.ed in the text. Totals do not necessarily equal the sum of rounded components. ACTUARIAL BALANCE OF THE HOSPITAL INSURANCE PROGRAM, UNDER ALTERNATIVE SETS OF ASSUMPTIONS a/ (Percent of Taxable Payroll) Average contribution rate, scheduled under present law b/ Average cost of the program, for expenditures and for trust fund maintenance c/ Actuarial balance I II-A II-B III 2.86% 2.86% 2.86% 2.86% 3.72 a/ 4.49 a/ 4.93 a/ 6.59 a/ -0.86 -1.63 -2.07 -3.73 a/ Does not reflect the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248). When the effect of this legislation is taken into account, the average 25-year cost exclusive of trust-fund building and maintenance under Alternative II-B is 4.34% of taxable payroll (as contrasted with the comparable figure of 4.83% before enactment of such legislation). b/ Average for the 25-year period, 1982-2006. c/ Average for the 25-year period, 1982-2006, expressed as a percentage of taxable payroll. NOTE: Taxable payroll is adjusted to take into account the lower contribution rates on self-employment income, on tips, and on multiple-employer "excess wages" as compared with the combined employer-employee rate. SOURCE: 1982 OASDI-HI Trustees Report. Appendix J, page 24 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 In the period following 2010, under the intermediate cost estimate, the OASDI tax rate tends to fall short of the cost rate by an increasing margin -- beginning in 2030, by almost 42% of taxable payroll. Under the pessimistic cost estimate, the excess of the cost rate over the tax rate steadily increases, until it reaches somewhat over 15% of taxable payroll. On the other hand, under the optimistic cost estimate, the OASDI tax rate exceeds the cost rate until about 2025; it is lower for the next 10 years, but once again is higher (by about 1% of taxable payroll at the end of the 75-year valuation period). Over the entire 75-year valuation period, the average OASDI cost rate exceeds the average combined employer-employee tax rate by 1.82% of taxable payroll in the intermediate cost estimate of the 1982 Trustees Report (see Table 6).9/ It may be noted that 1.82% of the total taxable payroll in 1982 was about $25 billion per year. The long-range actuarial imbalance is almost 62% of taxable payroll under the pessimistic cost estimate. The optimistic cost estimate (Alternative I) shows a favorable actuarial balance of 1.29% of taxable payroll, while the more optimistic of the two intermediate cost estimates (Alternative II-A) shows an actuarial deficiency of .82% of taxable payroll. When successive 25-year periods are considered, the intermediate cost estimate for the OASDI program shows a small positive balance (.64% of taxable Appendix J, page 25 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 payroll) for the first period. This occurs because the "deficits" of income over outgo in the 1980s are more than offset by the "surpluses" following 1990 (and up through 2006). Increasingly larger deficits are shown for the next two 25-year periods -- 1.68% of taxable payroll for the second period and 4.41% of taxable payroll for the third period. The deficit in the second period is 12% of the average cost rate (which means that, if benefit. outgo were to be decreased sufficiently to be financed by the average tax rate, a reduction of 12% would be necessary). The deficit for the third period is 26% of the average cost rate. When the first 50-year period is considered as a whole, there is a "deficit" of income over outgo of .52% of taxable payroll for the OASDI program, according to the intermediate cost estimate. The corresponding figure for the pessimistic cost estimate is a "deficit" of 3.08% of taxable payroll, while under the optimistic estimate, there is a "surplus" of 1.68% of taxable payroll. It is important to note that, if an economic stabilizing mechanism (such as is described in Chapter 2) were in effect in the 1990s and after, then the adverse results shown for present law under the pessimistic cost estimate would not occur. Rather, there would be excesses of tax income over outgo for benefit payments and administrative expenses throughout the period. The estimated significant annual excesses of the OASDI tax rate over the cost rate in the 1990s and early 2000s result in a sizable build-up of Appendix J, page 26 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 trust-fund assets under the intermediate cost estimate (assuming that, in the 1980s, the deficits occurring then were financed in some manner, even though they might be repaid later). Table 7 indicates that a fund ratio of about 180% is estimated to occur between 2010 and 2015, but thereafter it decreases rapidly until the fund would be exhausted shortly after 2025. Under the pessimistic cost estimate, the OASDI fund ratio would never become positive, because the cost rates always exceed the tax rates. Quite naturally, under the more optimistic of the cost estimates, the cost rates are lower than the tax rates in almost all years after 1990, and so the fund ratio increases steadily over the 75-year valuation period. Effect of the Real-Wage Differential Perhaps the most significant economic factor affecting costs in the actuarial estimates for the OASDI program is the real-wage differential, which is (1) the annual percentage increase in wages and salaries in covered employment, minus (2) the annual percentage increase in the CPI(W). The assumptions for the differential are based primarily on a projection of historical trends, which in turn reflect productivity gains and the factors that link such gains with the real-wage differential. Such differential has a direct effect on the cost estimates, but the associated assumptions for productivity gains and the factors linking such gains with the real-wage differential (as discussed in the next paragraph) do not have a direct effect on the long-range cost estimates expressed as a percentage of taxable payroll. Appendix J, page 27 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 7 ESTIMATED TRUST FUND RATIOS BY ALTERNATIVE AND TRUST FUND, CALEN- DAR YEARS 1982-2060 1982_ ................. 15 16 15 15 16 15 15 16 15 15 16 15 1983............ _...... 10 8 10 10 8 10 11 8 10 11 8 11 1984 .................... 1 48 6 (') 47 4 (') 43 3 (') 39 1 1985 .................... -7 98 4 -11 93 (') (9 84 -4 (') 71 (9 1986 .................... -10 178 9 -18 169 (') (') 148 -7 (') 125 (+) 1987 .................. -10 265 17 -24 253 3 (') 217 -10 (') 181 (9 1988 .................... -9 359 27 -28 342 8 (') 288 -13 (') 239 (') 1989 ................... -6 464 40 -30 432 15 (') 361 -16 (') 297 (9 1990 .................... (') 567 56 -32 524 22 (') 436 -19 (9 356 (9 e=1 ._._ ............. 15 696 82 -26 642 39 (') 536 -13 (') 436 (') 1992.........__....... 31 811 110 -18 753 58 (9 631 -7 ('l 509 (') 1993 .................... 47 934 138 -10 859 77 (') 723 (') (') 577 (9 1994 .................... 65 1,041 167 (') 961 97 (') 812 7 (') 643 (') 1995 .................... 84 1,137 197 8 1,054 116 19 895 15 (+) 705 (9 1996 .................... 104 1,208 228 18 1,122 136 (') 959 23 (+j 755 (9 1997 .................... 127 1,278 260 29 1,187 157 (+) 1,019 32 (9 799 (') 1998 .................... 150 1,345 293 41 1,247 178 (9 1.076 42 (') 837 (') 1999_ .................. 175 1,411 326 52 1,317 200 (') 1,130 53 (') 871 (') 2000 .................... 202 1,468 362 67 1,369 223 (9 1,178 64 1') 900 (') 2001 .................... 232 1,532 400 82 1,421 247 (9 1,227 76 (') 927 (9 2002 .................... 262 1,589 438 99 1,467 271 (9 1.270 89 19 951 (+) 2003 .................... 293 1,630 474 116 1,502 295 (9 1.303 102 (') 967 (') 2004 .................... 324 1,656 510 133 1,526 317 (9 1,327 115 (') 977 (') 2005 .................... 354 1,656 542 149 1,531 338 (9 1,332 128 19 976 (9 2006 .................... 384 1,702 576 165 1,568 358 (+) 1,366 140 (') 991 ('1 201D.. .................. 485 1,797 684 216 1,645 419 (+) 1,435 177 (') 1,005 (') 2015 .................... 539 1,967 745 224 1,779 434 (') 1,549 177 (+) 1,033 (') 2020 .................... 520 2,198 739 168 1,962 387 (9 1,703 125 (+) 1,076 (9 2025 .................... 457 2,549 698 67 2,240 300 (') 1,938 31 (') 1,162 (') 2030 .................... 386 3,000 662 (9 2,595 196 (') 2,241 (') (') 1,287 (') 2035 .................... 332 3,410 651 (') 2,902 89 (9 2,504 (') 1') 1,390 (9 2040 ................... 304 3,735 675 (+) 3,123 (') (') 2,693 (9 (') 1,456 (') 2045 .................... 298 4,031 719 (') 3,295 (') ('1 2,837 (') (') 1,515 (') 2050 .................... 301 4,443 766 (9 3,558 (+) (9 3,061 (') (') 1,619 (9 2055 .................... 305 4,942 811 (') 3,873 (') (9 3,330 (') (9 1,758 (') 2060 .................... 311 5,435 860 (9 4,168 (9 (9 3,582 (9 (') 1,910 (9 Trust fund is projected to be firs, ex- hausteo in:...... 1983 (4) 1983 1983 (4) 1983 1983 (9 1983 1983 (') 1983 !Between -0.5 percent and zero. 'The fund is projected to be exhausted and not to recover before the end of the projection period. 'Between zero and 0.5 percent. 'The fund is not projected to be exhausted within the projection period. Note: The ratios shown after the year in which a given fund is projected to be exhausted are theoretical and are shown for informational purposes only. In addition, the ratios for the total of the OASI and DI Trust Funds after 1982 are theoretical, because under the current law after 1982, the assets of one fund cannot be borrowed by another fund. The money assumed to be borrowed by the OASI Trust Fund in December 1982 is assumed to be repaid in 1992 under Alternative Is in 1998 under Alternative II-A, and not at any time in the long-range projection period under Alternatives II-B and III, although interest is assumed to be paid on a current basis. The assets used to compute the fund ratios are the gross assets, before taking into account the loans which occurred in 1982. If that had been done (i.e., considering the het assets), the OASI fund ratios would have been smaller, and the DI and HI fund ratios would have been larger. Note: These estimates do not take into account the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248). If this had been done, the fund ratios would have been slightly higher. Source: Table 32 in 1982 OASDI Trustees Report. Appendix J, page 28 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Such assumptions for productivity gains and the related linkage factors have been used, as a subsidiary procedure, to obtain estimates of the Gross National Product. Then, the long-range OASDI costs have then been expressed as a percentage of GNP. However, for the purpose of planning the financing of the OASDI program, by far the most important and critical measure is the relationship with taxable earnings, because the tax rates which finance the program are applied to such earnings. The most important linkage factors between real-wage growth and productivity are the following: (1) relative growth of nontaxable fringe benefits as a proportion of total compensation, (2) the average number of hours worked per week, and (3) the average number of weeks worked per year. In the intermediate cost estimate (Alternative II-B), when GNP was estimated from the primary assumptions as to real-wage differentials, the result of the linkages was an ultimate (1992 and after) rate of productivity gains of 2.2% per year. This figure was derived from the real-wage differential of 1.5% per year by increasing it by .4% for the relative annual growth of fringe benefits, by .2% for the average number of hours worked per week, and by .1% for the average number of weeks worked per year (the net effect of other linkage factors than the three which were used was considered to be negligible). Consideration of these two figures can lead to greatly different conclusions. On the one hand, it could be argued that the difference of .7% between productivity gains and real-wage growth is too large and that, Appendix J, page 29 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 therefore, the real-wage differential used should be higher than 1.5% -- which would produce a considerably more favorable financial picture for the OASDI program than is currently estimated. On the other hand, it could be argued that the assumed ultimate productivity rate of 2.2% is too high and that then either (1) the several linkage factors are overstated, and the real-wage differential of 1.5% is satisfactory, or (2) the linkage factors are appropriate, but the real-wage differential should be lower than 1.5% -- which would produce a considerably less favorable financial picture for the OASDI program than is currently estimated. The estimates of GNP that have been derived from the basic actuarial cost estimates expressed as percentages of taxable payroll can be used to compare the cost of the OASDI system with GNP. According to the intermediate cost estimate, such cost is currently about 5.2% of GNP and will decrease slowly for the next 20 years, reaching a low of about 4.4%. It will increase to 6.1% in 2030, and then again decline slowly, to about 5.5% at the end of the 75-year valuation period. Under the pessimistic estimate, the cost of the OASDI program as a percentage of GNP remains relatively level at slightly more than 5% for the next 25 years, but it continuously increases thereafter to about 8.6% at the end of the valuation period. On the other hand, under the optimistic cost estimate (Alternative I), such ratio decreases slowly in the next few years, reaching a minimum of slightly less than 4% of GNP after 20 years and then slowly rises to Appendix J, page 30 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 somewhat more than 5% in the 2020s; thereafter, it decreases to somewhat less than 43'2% ultimately. FINANCIAL STATUS OF HI TRUST FUND This section will briefly examine the financial status of the HI Trust Fund in past years, its current status, and its outlook over both the short range and the long range. Also considered will be the combined cost rates for the OASDI and HI programs over the 75-year OASDI valuation period. Past Operations The balance of the HI Trust Fund has built up steadily over the years and was almost $21 billion at the end of October 1982 (see Table 1). At times (such as in 1970-72 and 1975-77), the balances were relatively level, as a result of the offsetting effects of periodic increases in the tax rates and the continuous increases in hospital costs. Since 1970, the trust-fund ratio for the HI program has generally been between 50% and 70% (see Table 2). During December 1982, the HI Trust Fund loaned a significant amount to the OASI Trust Fund (for the reasons described earlier). Such loans are, of course, part of the assets of the HI Trust Fund, even though they are not immediately available to meet outgo, and should be so considered in analyses of its financial condition. Appendix J, page 31 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Short-Range Cost Situation Under the intermediate cost estimate, the balance in the HI Trust Fund is estimated to increase for several years -- in large part because of the tax-rate increase in 1981 and the increases that are scheduled for 1985 and 1986. However, under this estimate, beginning in 1988, the balance will begin to fall, and in 1991 it will be exhausted.10/ Under the pessimistic cost estimate, the fund balance will remain relatively level during 1983-86, but will then decrease rapidly and will be exhausted in 1988. Long-Range Cost Situation Table 8 compares the estimated cost rates of the HI program with the combined employer-employee tax rates over the next 75 years, according to the intermediate cost estimate.il/ After the relatively favorable situation in the next few years, the cost rate increasingly exceeds the tax rate. About 50 years from now, the differential is somewhat more than 8% of taxable payroll -- or, in other words, the cost rate at that time is almost four times as high as the combined employer-employee tax rate. In the 25-year valuation period used for the HI program, the excess of the cost rate over the tax rate is about 1z% of taxable payroll. Table 6 presents the actuarial balances of the HI program over its 25-year valuation period for the several alternative cost estimates. The actuarial Appendix J, page 32 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 8 Calendar Year 1982 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 Averages 1982-2006 2007-31 2032-56 1982-2056 ESTIMATED COST RATES OF HI AND OASDI-HI PROGRAMS UNDER ALTERNATIVE II-B AND COMPARISON WITH TAX RATES, 1986-2055* (as percent of taxable payroll) HI Program OASDI-HI Program Cost Tax Cost Tax Rate!/ Rateb/ Differencec/ Rate Rateb/ Difference/ 2.97% 2.60% -.37% 14.75% 13.40% -1.35% 2.74 2.70 -.04 14.44 14.10 -.34 3.51 2.90 -.61 15.15 15.30 +.15 4.47 2.90 -1.57 15.89 15.30 -.59 5.38 2.90 -2.48 16.41 15.30 -1.11 6.29 2.90 -3.39 17.24 15.30 -1.94 7.20 2.90 -4.30 18.73 15.30 -3.43 7.94 2.90 -5.04 20.76 15.30 -5.46 8.89 2.90 -5.99 23.33 15.30 -8.03 9.93 2.90 -7.03 25.90 15.30 -10.60 10.76 2.90 -7.86 27.59 15.30 -12.29 11.17 2.90 -8.27 28.19 15.30 -12.89 11.29 2.90 -8.39 28.09 15.30 -12.79 11.21 2.90 -8.31 27.87 15.30 -12.57 11.19 2.90 -8.29 27.91 15.30 -12.61 11.17 2.90 -8.27 27.98 15.30 -12.68 4.34 2.86 -1.48 15.71 14.87 -.84 8.78 2.90 -5.88 22.86 15.30 -7.56 11.19 2.90 -8.29 28.00 15.30 -12.70 8.10 2.89 -5.21 22.19 15.16 -7.03 !/ These cost rates do not include any allowance for building up and maintaining the trust-fund ratio at 50% (which would require an additional .10% of taxable payroll in 1982-2006). For employer and employee combined. Tax rate minus cost rate. Positive differences are referred to as cash-flow surpluses, and negative differences as deficits. NOTE: These estimates for OASDI do not take into account the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248), but those for HI do take this legislation into account. If this had been done, the cost rates for OASDI-HI would have been slightly lower. SOURCE: Table 27 of the 1982 OASDI Trustees Report and Table 8 of the 1982 HI Trustees Report (extended beyond 2005 by Health Care Financing Administration under assumption that, then, hospital costs rise at the same rate as wages), in all cases reduced to allow for the effect of P.L. 97-248 (a reduction of about 10/% in all years after 1982). * See views of Commissioners Ball, Keys, Kirkland, Moynihan, and Pepper as to the undesirability of cost estimates for the HI program going further than 25 years into the future, in Chapter 4. Appendix J, page 33 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 imbalance of about 12% of taxable payroll according to the intermediate cost estimate can be compared with a figure of about 3% under the pessimistic estimate (after allowance has been made in each case for the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982, whose effect is not included in Table 6) -- or, similarly, of about 2% of taxable payroll under the more optimistic cost estimate. Cost Rates for Combined OASDI-HI Programs Table 8 shows the year-by-year cost rates and combined employer-employee tax rates on a year-by-year basis for the OASDI and HI programs combined, according to the intermediate cost estimate. In almost all years in the 75-year period considered, the cost rate exceeds the tax rate -- and by increasing amounts following 1990. This deficit levels off at about 122% of taxable payroll, beginning some 50 years hence. In this ultimate situation, the cost rate is about 80% higher than the combined employer-employee tax rate. FINANCIAL STATUS OF SMI TRUST FUND This section will examine briefly the financial status of the SMI Trust Fund in past years and its current status. No discussion will be given as to its long-range future outlook, because its financing basis is essentially on a "one-year term" basis, and its benefit provisions are not automatically adjusted Appendix J, page 34 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 for changing economic conditions -- as are many of the provisions of the OASDI and HI programs. In the past, some of the benefit provisions of the SMI program have been adjusted on an ad hoc basis. The balance in the SMI Trust Fund increased from a relatively small amount in 1970 to almost $6 billion at present (see Table 1). As of June 30, 1981, the total assets of the SMI Trust Fund amounted to $3.8 billion, as compared with estimated liabilities for the cost of the benefits incurred in the past and still payable (but then unpaid) and the associated administrative expenses of $4.0 billion. This small deficiency of $200 million represented only 1% of the estimated total incurred expenditures for the following year. It is estimated that, as of June 30, 1982, the assets on hand exceeded the incurred liabilities by about $800 million, or 4% of the estimated total incurred expenditures for the next 12 months. Accordingly, it can properly be stated that the actuarial status of the SMI Trust Fund in recent years and currently is satisfactory under any standard considered (i.e., both on a cash basis and, more importantly, on an accrual basis). Appendix J, page 35 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 FOOTNOTES 1/ For example, non-insured persons who were aged 65 or over at the inception of the HI program (who were "blanketed-in" for such benefits) and certain persons who were aged 72 or over before the mid-1970s (who were "blanketed-in" for monthly benefits at a uniform rate). (Not included in this context as payments from the General Fund of the Treasury are the matching employer contributions or similar payments for members of the armed forces and certain Federal civilian employees, because they are more properly considered as employer taxes.) 2/ Occasionally, a retrospective fund ratio is used, which is based on the outgo in the preceding 12 months, so as to utilize actual data for both 3/ Actually, slightly less than such amount would be sufficient, because the payroll-tax receipts in the first few days of the month would be available. 4/ The HI program has financial patterns within the calendar year. Outgo tends to be lower in the early part of the year, because of the effect of the initial deductible and because of the effect of the increasing trend of hospital costs over the years. There are other offsetting factors such as higher hospital utilization in winter months than in the remainder of the year. However, any seasonal outgo effects are more than offset by Appendix J, page 36 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 the relatively larger income in the early months of the year than in the later months, for the same reasons as is the case for the OASDI Trust Funds. 5/ Adjustment is made for such factors as that the self-employed pay less than the combined employer-employee tax rate. 6/ Such consideration of the two trust funds combined can be interpreted as there being either (1) permanent interfund borrowing permitted or (2) a reallocation of the OASDI tax rate which would increase the portion thereof assignable to the OASI Trust Fund. It would seem that, because the DI program appears to have more than sufficient financing, not only in the recent past, but also for the long-range future, such a reallocation of the OASDI tax rate is both feasible and desirable. 7/ Such analysis is performed by considering the combined OASDI Trust Funds. This is done because it may be desirable that the estimated future overfinancing of the DI program shown by the current cost estimates should be diverted to the OASI program (by increasing the proportion of the OASDI tax rates which is allocated to OASI), so that they are on a comparable financing basis. 8/ At that time, those reaching retirement age will be the survivors of those born in the late 1920s and the 1930s, when the numbers of births per year Appendix J, page 37 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 were lower than before 1925 or after 1939. At the same time, the post-World War II baby boom population will be at the working ages. 9/ This actuarial deficiency has currently been revised downward -- to 1.80% of taxable payroll -- when account was taken of (a) the actual benefit increase for June 1982 (which was slightly smaller than that estimated in the Trustees Report) and (b) the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248). 10/ It should be noted that the financial outlook for the HI Trust Fund as discussed here is somewhat more favorable than shown in the 1982 HI Trustees Report. This is the result of including in the data discussed here the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982, which significantly improved the short-run financial situation of the HI program (by covering Federal employees and restricting the reimbursements somewhat). 11/ As previously mentioned, such long-range estimates are more subject to variation for the HI program than for the OASDI program. The valuation period used for the HI system in the 1982 HI Trustees Report is 25 years. Appendix J, page 38 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Appendix K Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance and Hospital Insurance Programs (Revised Version) Actuarial Cost Estimates for OASDI and HI and for Various Possible Changes in OASDI Historical Data for OASDI and HI National Commission on Social Security Reform Washington, D.C. December 1982 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction Cost Analysis of Various Possible Changes A. Coverage B. Tax Rates C. Alternative Sources of Revenues D. Cost-of-Living Adjustments for Benefits in Payment Status E. Level of Primary Benefits F. Retirement Age G. Disability Benefits H. Proposals Affecting Primarily Women I Other Options Regarding Benefit Changes J. Taxation of Benefits K. Other Issues Tables of Historical Data NOTE: Pages are numbered successively within each lettered section for the various possible changes. Appendix K, page 1 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 INTRODUCTION This background book was originally prepared for the meeting of the National Commission on Social Security Reform on November 11-13, 1982. The present version has been revised to reflect certain additional information that became available after the meeting and to correct a few minor errors. It presents actuarial cost estimates, for various possible changes in the Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance program. The changes presented are intended to represent an objective selection which covers all of the major options open for resolving the short-range and long-range financing problems of the OASDI program. Quite naturally, there are many permutations and combinations of the several options -- varying by effective dates, benefit percentages, normal retirement ages, etc. However, it is believed that the changes presented are reasonably representative. The effect of different proposals than these can usually be seen from the data presented here. Also presented are a number of tables which show the past experience of the OASDI and Hospital Insurance programs and their estimated future experience. Attention is particularly directed to Tables 5 and 10, which address the short- range problem, and to Tables 6, 7, and 8, which address the long-range problem. The various cost estimates presented were prepared in most cases by the Office of the Actuary, Social Security Administration. The long-range cost effects of the various possible changes considered are expressed as percentages of taxable payroll -- which makes them comparable with payroll tax rates. For example, a long-term cost of +.38% of taxable payroll means that, if this were to be financed by a level tax rate in all future years, then a combined employer-employee rate of .38% would be required. This is done rather than expressing them in terms of dollars, because of the difficulty of expressing costs over long future periods of years in such terms when assumptions of continuously rising wages and prices are involved. The taxable payroll in 1982 is about $1.4 trillion (so that 1% of payroll would be $14 billion). Notes: (1) Increased cost is indicated by a plus (+) sign. 2) Cost reduction is indicated by a minus (-) sign. (3) All estimates are on the basis of calendar years. (4) All estimates are for the OASDI Trust Funds only, unless otherwise indicated. (5) A "0" means that the cost effect for the year is zero, while a ".0" means that it is less than $50 million. (6) References to "long-term" mean the years 1982-2056. (7) Long-term estimates are on the basis of the Alternative II-B assumptions of the 1982 OASDI Trustees Report. (8) When all of the short-term cost figures are zero, no short-term cost table is presented. Appendix K, page 2 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUMMARY OF SECTION A - COVERAGE Option No. Description A-1 Cover all Federal, State and local, and nonprofit employees. A-2 Cover all Federal and nonprofit employees. A-3 Cover all nonprofit employees and all new Federal employees. A-4 Cover all new State and local employees. A-5 Prohibit withdrawal from coverage by State and local governments and by nonprofit organizations by not permitting notices to be filed after 1983. A-6 Prohibit withdrawal from coverage by State and local governments and by nonprofit organizations by providing that any notice of termination filed after 9/30/82 is invalid. A-7 Eliminate windfall benefits for persons with pensions from noncovered employment. A-8 Cover all nonprofit employees, -26 -29 -.31 all new Federal employees, and all present Federal employees with less than 5 years of service. Note: Long-term costs are presented as a percentage of taxable payroll, for OASDI only. * Less than $500 million savings. Appendix K, page 3 OASDI Cost 1983-89 (billions) Long- Term II-B III Cost -$110 -$117 -.53% -62 -68 -.31 -19 -21 -.30 -13 -14 -.24 +50 +53 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 A. COVERAGE Present law. OASDI coverage now applies to almost all types of employment. The principal types of employment not covered are the following: (1) employees of nonprofit organizations which have not elected such coverage (about 15% of such employees), (2) permanent civilian employees of the Federal government, and (3) employees of State and local governments which have not elected coverage (about 30% of such employees). Options. A-1 Extend coverage to all Federal employees, State and local employees, and employees of nonprofit organizations*, effective in 1984.** Cost (in billions of dollars Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B, OASDI 0 -14.0 -16.7 -18.0 -19.3 -20.6 -22.0 -110.5 III, OASDI 0 -14.2 -17.0 -18.7 -20.5 -22.4 -24.4 -117.2 II-B, HI 0 -1.6 -2.0 -2.3 -2.5 -2.7 -2.9 -14.2 III, HI 0 -1.6 -2.0 -2.4 -2.6 -2.8 -3.1 -14.5 25-Year Cost, OASDI: -.70% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost, OASDI: -.64% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost, OASDI: -.53% of taxable payroll 25-Year Cost, HI: -.25% of taxable payroll Such organizations which have religious principles against any form of government insurance would be permitted to opt out on a permanent basis. ** If the effective date were later than 1984, the long-term cost effect would be about the same as shown. The short-term cost effects would be zero, of course, for years before the effective date and about the same as shown for the effective year and thereafter. Appendix K, page 4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 A-2 Extend coverage to all Federal employees and all employees of nonprofit organizations*, effective in 1984.** Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B, OASDI 0 -8.1 -9.2 -9.9 -10.7 -11.4 -12.2 -61.5 III, OASDI 0 -8.4 -9.8 -10.7 -11.8 -12.9 -14.1 -67.6 II-B, HI 0 -.2 -.3 -.3 -.3 -.3 -.4 -1.8 III, HI 0 -.2 -.3 -.3 -.3 -.4 -.4 -1.9 25-Year Cost, OASDI: -.40% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost, OASDI: -.37% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost, OASDI: -.31% of taxable payroll 25-Year Cost, HI: -.02% of taxable payroll A-3 Extend coverage to all employees of nonprofit organizations* and all new Federal employees, effective in 1984.** Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B, OASDI 0 -1.2 -2.1 -2.7 -3.4 -4.2 -5.0 -18.6 III, OASDI 0 -1.2 -2.2 -2.9 -3.7 -4.7 -5.8 -20.6 II-B, HI 0 -.2 -.3 -.3 -.3 -.3 -.4 -1.8 III, HI 0 -.2 -.3 -.3 -.3 -.4 -.4 -1.9 25-Year Cost, OASDI: -.25% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost, OASDI: -.34% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost, OASDI: -.30% of taxable payroll 25-Year Cost, HI: -.02% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 5 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 198x198 1986 1987 1989 1983-89 II-B, OASDI 0 -.3 -1.1 -1.8 -2.6 -3.3 -4.2 -13.3 III, OASDI 0 -.3 -1.0 -1.8 -2.6 -3.5 -4.5 -13.7 II-B, HI 0 -.1 -.2 -.5 -.7 -.9 -1.1 -3.5 III, HI 0 -.1 -.2 -.5 -.7 -.9 -1.1 -3.5 25-Year Cost, OASDI: -.23% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost, OASDI: -.28% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost, OASDI: -.24% of taxable payroll 25-Year Cost, HI: -.23% of taxable payroll A-5 Prohibit opting out of coverage of employees of State and local governments and employees of nonprofit organizations by not permitting withdrawal notices to be filed after 1983. Cost (in billions of dollars)*** Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B, OASDI 0 +.5 +4.0 +9.6 +11.2 +12.1 +13.1 +50.5 III, OASDI 0 +.5 +4.0 +9.8 +11.6 +12.6 +14.1 +52.6 *** It is estimated that such a provision would result in increased costs over the short run, because the actuarial cost estimates assume that many more entries would feel constrained to withdraw at once, before they would no longer have the opportunity to do so. Long-term cost data are not available, due to the diverse effects possible. Appendix K, page 6 A-4 Extend coverage to all new State and local employees, effective 1984.** Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 A-6 Prohibit opting out of coverage of employees of State and local governments and employees of nonprofit organizations by providing that any notice of termination filed after September 30, 1982 is invalid.**** A-7 Eliminate "windfall" old-age and disability benefits for persons with pensions from noncovered employment, effective for those becoming first eligible after 1983 (in the absence of changes which would result in universal coverage being applicable). Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.1 -.1 -.2 III 0 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.1 -.1 -.2 25-Year Cost: -.00% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.03% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.09% of taxable payroll A-8 Extend coverage to all employees of nonprofit organizations*, to all new Federal employees, and to all present Federal employees with less than 5 years of service, as of January 1, 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 98~ 5 1986 1987 1988 1989 -1983-89 II-6 0 2.4 3.2 4.0 4.7 5.5 6.3 26.2 III 0 2.5 3.5 4.3 5.3 6.2 7.3 29.0 25-Year Cost: -.25% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.36% of taxable payroll Long-Term cost: -.31% of taxable payroll Cost estimates for the savings involved are not available, because the actuarial cost estimates for the present program assume that no withdrawals will occur. Obviously, this proposal will have significant cost savings if it is enacted. Appendix K, page 7 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUMMARY OF SECTION B - TAX RATES Option No. Description B-1 Accelerate the 1990 OASDI tax to 1984. B-2 Accelerate the 1985 OASDI tax to 1984. B-3 Accelerate the 1985 and 1986 OASDI-HI tax rates to 1984. B-4 Increase the OASDI-HI tax rate for self-employed persons to the combined employer-employee rate. B-5 Reduce the 1990 OASDI tax rate from 6.2% to 6.0% for 1990-2009. B-6 Move the 1985 OASDI tax rate to 1984; for 1985-87, such rate would be mid-way between the 1985 and 1990 tax rates in present law; for 1988 and after, such rate would be the 1990 rate in present law. B-7 Increase the OASDI tax rate on employers and employees each by 1% in 2020. B-8 Increase the OASDI tax rate on employers and employees each by 1.25% in 2030. B-9 Remove the taxable earnings base for employers only. B-10 Set a limit of 25% of total compensation as to the amount of fringe benefits not subject to payroll tax. Tax-exempt fringes in excess of such limit would be subject to OASDI-HI tax on only the employer and would not be counted as creditable wages for benefit purposes. B-11 Maintain a constant OASDI tax rate on total compensation, effective 1990. B-12 Make wages deferred under Section 401(k) (salary reduction plans) be subject to OASDI-HI tax. n.a. = Not available. OASDI Cost 1983-89 (billions) Long- Term II-B III Cost -$133 -$135 -.09% -10 -10 -.01 -19 -18 -.02 -18 -17 -.19 0 0 +.11 -86 -89 -.05 0 0 -.99 0 0 -.90 -41 -42 -.56 n.a. n.a. -.73 0 0 -1.56 n.a. n.a. n.a. Appendix K, page 8 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 B. TAX RATES Present law. See Table 2 for schedule of OASDI-HI tax rates under present law. Options. B-1 Accelerate the 1990 OASDI tax rate to 1984.* Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 -25.1 -18.7 -19.7 -21.3 -23.1 -24.9 -132.8 III 0 -24.3 -18.4 -19.8 -21.8 -24.1 -26.4 -134.8 25-Year Cost: -.26% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.13% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.09% of taxable payroll B-2 Accelerate the 1985 OASDI tax rate to 1984. Cost On billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 -9.4 -.6 0 0 0 0 -10.0 III 0 -9.1 -.6 0 0 0 0 -9.7 25-Year Cost: -.02% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.01% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.01% of taxable payroll * In conjunction with this proposal, a portion of the OASDI-HI tax could be made deductible for income-tax purposes or a tax credit provided -- the portion would be such that the reduction in personal income taxes would equal the additional OASDI-HI taxes paid by workers and employers. Thus, there would be no effect on the overall Federal budget deficit. Appendix K, page 9 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 B-3 Accelerate the 1985 and 1986 OASDI-HI tax rates to 1984.** Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B, OASDI 0 -9.4 -.6 0 0 0 0 -10.0 III, OASDI 0 -9.1 -.6 0 0 0 0 -9.7 II-B, HI 0 -4.9 -3.8 -.2 0 0 0 -8.8 III, HI 0 -4.7 -3.8 -.2 0 0 0 -8.7 25-Year Cost, OASDI: -.02% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost, OASDI: -.01% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost, OASDI: -.01% of taxable payroll 25-Year Cost, HI: -.02% of taxable payroll B-4 Increase the OASDI-HI tax rate for self-employed persons to the combined employer-employee rate, effective in 1984.*** Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 i 9 II-B, OASDI 0 -.9 -2.8 -3.1 -3.4 -3.6 -3.8 -17.5 III, OASDI 0 -.8 -2.6 -3.0 -3.3 -3.6 -3.9 -17.3 II-B, HI 0 -.4 -1.3 -1.5 -1.7 -1.8 -2.0 -8.7 III, HI 0 -.4 -1.2 -1.5 -1.7 -1.8 -2.0 -8.6 25-Year Cost, OASDI: -.15% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost, OASDI: -.17% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost, OASDI: -.19% of taxable payroll 25-Year Cost, HI: -.14% of taxable payroll The figures shown assume that the taxes resulting from the 1986 increase in the HI portion of the tax rate would go into the HI Trust Fund. It would be possible to keep the HI tax rate under the proposal at the same level in 1984-85 as under present law and to reallocate the increase in the OASDI-HI rate entirely to the OASDI Trust Funds; then, the cost effect for the OASDI Trust Funds would be approximately the sum of the figures shown for OASDI and HI. *** In conjunction with this proposal, a refundable tax credit for the self- employed equal to 25% of the self-employment tax could be provided. Alternatively, 50% of the payroll tax paid by the self-employed could be made tax deductible as a business expense. Appendix K, page 10 396-938 0 - 83 - 14 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 B-5 Reduce the 1990 OASDI tax rate from 6.2% on the employer and employee, each, to 6.0% for 1990-2009. Return to the 6.2% rate in 2010. 25-Year Cost: +.27% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: +.16% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: +.11% of taxable payroll B-6 Move the 1985 OASDI tax rate to 1984; increase the 1985-87 OASDI tax rate to mid-way between the 1985 and 1990 tax rates in present law; and for 1988 and after, increase the OASDI tax rate to the tax rate for 1990 in present law. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1~1~19871988 1~-1983-89 II-B 0 -9.4 -9.1 -9.8 -10.7 -22.5 -24.9 -86.4 III 0 -9.1 -9.0 -9.9 -10.9 -23.4 -26.4 -88.7 25-Year Cost: -.16% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.08% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.05% of taxable payroll B-7 Increase OASDI tax by 1% on employers and employees each, effective in 2020. Long-Term Cost: -.99% of taxable payroll B-8 Increase OASDI tax rate by 1.25% on employers and employees each, effective in 2030. Long-Term Cost: -.90% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 11 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 B-9 Remove the taxable earnings base for employers only, effective in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 19 7 1988 1989 1983-89' II-B, OASDI 0 -5.9 -6.7 -6.8 -7.0 -7.2 -7.3 -40.9 III, OASDI 0 -5.8 -6.7 -6.8 -7.2 -7.5 -7.6 -41.6 II-B, HI 0 -1.5 -1.6 -1.8 -1.8 -1.9 -1.9 -10.5 III, HI 0 -1.5 -1.6 -1.8 -1.8 -2.0 -2.0 -10.7 25-Year Cost, OASDI: -.43% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost, OASDI: -.50% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost, OASDI: -.56% of taxable payroll 25-Year Cost, HI: B-10 Set a limit of 25% of total compensation as the amount of non-taxable fringe-benefit compensation that can be provided without being subject to the payroll tax. Tax-exempt fringes in excess of the 25% limit would become subject to OASDI-HI tax only for the employer and would not be counted as creditable wages for benefit purposes, effective in 19-85. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 i 1986 1987 1988 1989 II-B, OASDI III, OASDI II-B, HI III, HI 25-Year Cost, OASDI: -.07% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost, OASDI: -.32% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost, OASDI: -.73% of taxable payroll 25-Year Cost, HI: Appendix K, page 12 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 B-11 Maintain, in effect, constant OASDI tax rate on total compensation, effective in 1990. If the "cash earnings plus taxable fringe benefits" portion of total compensation decreases, the tax rate on covered wages would increase so as to maintain a constant tax rate on total compensation, using 1990 as the base year. 25-Year Cost: -.25% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.87% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -1.56% of taxable payroll B-12 Make wages deferred under Section 401(k) of the Internal Revenue Code (salary reduction plans) be subject to the OASDI-HI tax. Long-Term Cost: Cannot be estimated, because no experience data are available. However, the loss of revenues to the OASDI and HI Trust Funds, without this change, may become substantial in future years. Appendix K, page 13 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUMMARY OF SECTION C - ALTERNATIVE SOURCES OF REVENUES Option No. Description C-1 Reallocate 50% of HI tax rate to the OASDI Trust Funds. C-2 Same as C-1, except that effective date is 1990. C-3 Allow OASDI Trust Funds to borrow from General Fund whenever the combined fund ratio is below 15%. C-4 Impose a new inheritance tax earmarked for OASI Trust Fund. C-5 Impose a surtax on gasoline, earmarked for OASI Trust Fund. C-6 Impose a 5% surcharge on individual income tax, earmarked for OASI Trust Fund. C-7 Increase excise tax on alcohol and tobacco, earmarked for DI or HI Trust Funds. C-8 Credit OASDI Trust Funds with total unreimbursed cost for military-service wage credits based on service before 1957. C-9 Credit OASDI Trust Funds with excess of past benefit payments over past reimbursements for military-service wage credits based on service before 1957. C-10 Pay OASDI taxes for current military-service gratuitous wage credits. C-11 Credit OASDI Trust Funds for OASDI checks that have gone uncashed for 1 or more years, effective.in 1983. C-12 Provide that OASDI administrative expenses be paid from general revenues. C-13 Provide a general-revenue con- tribution, in a given month, equal to excess of the unemployment rate over 6%, times total OASDI taxes. * Amount borrowed from General Fund in period. ** Less than $500 million. n.a. = Not available. OASDI Cost 1983-89 (billions) Long- Term II- III Cost -$174 -$177 -1.42% 0 0 -1.30 75* 201* n.a. -22 -22 n.a. -23 -23 -.02 -134 -134 -.09 -14 -14 -.01 -3 n.a. .00 -2 -2 -.01 -1 -1 .00 -19 -19 -.15 -16 -30 -.05 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 C. ALTERNATIVE SOURCES OF REVENUES Present law. Income to the OASDI and HI Trust Funds comes from the payroll tax which is paid by employers, employees, and the self-employed. (In addition, there are certain payments to the trust funds from the General Fund of the Treasury to cover the cost of certain transitional benefits for closed groups of persons and military-service wage credits.) Options. C-1 Reallocate 50% of the employer-employee HI tax rates to the OASDI Trust Funds, and make up this loss to the HI Trust Fund by payments from the General Fund of the Treasury, effective in 1984 (with corresponding treatment for the self-employed rate). OASDI Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 -20.4 -24.4 -28.5 -30.9 -33.5 -36.1 -173.8 III 0 -19.7 -24.1 -28.6 -31.7 -34.9 -38.3 -177.3 25-Year Cost: -1.33% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -1.39% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -1.42% of taxable payroll C-2 Same as Option C-1, except effective in 1990. 25-Year Cost: -.99% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -1.23% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -1.30% of taxable payroll C-3 Allow the OASDI Trust Funds to borrow from the General Fund of the Treasury whenever their combined balance (assuming interfund borrowing between them) is lower than 15% of the next year's outgo, effective in 1983. The amounts would be paid back to the General Fund, with interest, when the combined OASDI Trust Fund ratios reach 50%. If necessary, the OASDI tax rate would be increased to assure pay-back. Amount Borrowed from General Fund in Year (in billions of dollars)* Estimate 198x1984 1985 1986 1997 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 22 15 7 8 8 8 7 75 III 26 26 20 25 30 34 ,40 201 Appendix K, page 15 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 C-4 Impose a new inheritance tax, which would apply only if there is no surviving spouse. It would exclude the first $100,000 in the estate. The next $100,000 would be taxed at a 10% rate, and the third $100,000 would be taxed at a 15% rate, effective for 1985. After 1989, the thresholds for taxation would be indexed by the CPI increases. The proceeds of the tax would be earmarked for the OASI Trust Fund. Cos n billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 9 8 1989 - 0 0 -3.6 -3.9 -4.3 -4.7 -5.1 -21.6 Long-Term Cost: Cannot be determined. C-5 Impose a surcharge of 3 cents a gallon on gasoline, which would be earmarked for the OASI Trust Fund, effective for 1983-89. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1871988 1989 -3.3 -3.3 -3.3 -3.3 -3.3 -3.3 -3.3 -23.1 Long-Term Cost: -.02% of taxable payroll C-6 Impose a 5% surcharge on individual income taxes in 1983-89, the proceeds from which would be earmarked for the OASI Trust Fund. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1989 1983-89 -14.9 -15.8 -17.3 -18.8 -20.6 -22.4 -24.4 -134.2 Long-Term Cost: -.09% of taxable payroll Interest that would a accumu ating on the amounts borrowed is not shown. Only one estimate is available. It is based on data provided by the Joint Committee on Taxation and the Congressional Budget Office. Appendix K, page 16 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 C-7 Impose increased excise taxes on alcohol and tobacco in 1983-89 -- increases of 25% over present rates. The proceeds would be earmarked for either the DI or HI Trust Fund. Cost (in billions of dollars Estimate 1983 I9-84--1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 -2.0 Long-Term Cost: -.01% of taxable payroll C-8 Credit to the OASDI Trust Funds, as a lump sum, the present value of the additional cost of OASDI benefits for those military-service wage credits based on service before 1957, effective in 1983. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B -5.8 +.6 +.5 +.5 +.5 +.5 +.5 -2.6 Long-Term Cost: Negligible C-9 Credit to the OASDI Trust Funds, as a lump sum, the excess of past benefit payments over past reimbursement payments (including interest) for the cost of additional OASDI benefits for those military-service wage credits based on service before 1957. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 98~ 3-89 I I -B -.9 +.r_ +.1 +.T_ T_ -.9 +.1 +.1 +.1 +.1 +.1 +.1 -.3 Long-Term cost: Negligible *** Only one estimate is available. Any such estimate is subject to a wide variation, because it depends greatly on future conditions. Appendix K, page 17 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 C-10 Pay OASDI taxes for current military-service gratuitous wage credits as the service is rendered, effective in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars Estimate 1983 19841985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B III -.3 -.3 Long-Term Cost: Negligible -.3 -.3 -.3 -.3 -.3 -.3 C-11 Credit to the OASDI Trust Funds the OASDI checks which have not been cashed for at least 1 year, effective in 1983. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 19861987 1988 1989 -- fig II-B -.3 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.5 III -.3 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.5 Long-Term Cost: Negligible Estimate _1W 1985 19861987 1983 II-B -2.2 -2.3 -2.5 -2.6 -2.8 III -2.2 -2.3 -2.5 -2.7 -2.9 25-Year Cost: -.13% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.14% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.15% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 18 C-12 Provide that the administrative expenses of the OASDI program be paid from the General Fund of the Treasury. Cost (in billions of dollars) 1988 1989 1983-89 -2.9 -3.1 -18.5 -3.1 -3.3 -18.9 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 C-13 Provide a payment from the General Fund of the Treasury equal, for each month, to (a) the excess (if any) of the unemployment rate over 6%, multiplied by (b) the total OASDI tax receipts, effective in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 79-86---7987 1988 198 1983-89 II-B 0 -2.8 -3.5 -3.2 -2.8 -2.2 -1.5 -16.1 III 0 -5.0 -5.7 -5.4 -5.2 -4.7 -4.1 -30.1 25-Year Cost: -.07% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.06% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.05% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 19 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUMMARY OF SECTION D - COST-OF-LIVING OASDI ADJUSTMENTS Cost 1983-89 Long- (billions) Term Option No. Description II-B III Cost D-1 Delay COLA by one month per -$20 year for 3 years. D-2 Delay the effective date for -23 the cost-of-living adjustment for 3 months. D-3 Provide for no COLA for 1983. -94 Resume present procedure thereafter. D-4 Provide guaranteed COLA of 4% -100 for 1983 and 1984; thereafter, the COLA would equal the annual increase in wages, minus 12 percentage points. D-5 Provide guaranteed benefit -96 increase of 4% or $14 (whichever is higher) for 1983 and 1984; Thereafter, the COLA would equal the annual increase in wages, minus 12 percentage points. D-6 Provide COLAs equal to 75% of -88 what the benefit increases would be under present law. D-7 Provide COLAS equal to increase -103 in the CPI, minus 2 percentage points. D-8 Provide COLA equal to present-law -66 increase, minus 2 percentage points for 1983 and 1984; thereafter present-law procedure would resume. D-9 Same as D-8 for 1983 and 1984; -75 thereafter, COLAS would be equal to the annual increase in wages, minus 1/ percentage points. D-10 Provide COLAs equal to annual * percentage increase in wages, minus "X" percentage points. The value of "X" could be 1, 1/, or 2. D-11 Provide COLAs based on lesser of -1 increase in wages or prices, with a "catch-up" provision. D-12 Provide COLAs based on lesser of -4 increase in wages or prices, with no "catch-up" provision. -$31 -.14% -35 -.14 -119 -.13 -180 -.16 -176 -.15 -128 -1.45 -113 -2.58 -72 -.07 -97 -.11 * * -60 -.06 -66 -.43 Various alternatives are considered (see subsequent pages for details). Appendix K, page 20 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 D. COST-OF-LIVING ADJUSTMENTS FOR BENEFITS IN PAYMENT STATUS Present law. Benefits are increased each year when the annual increase in the Consumer Price Index (CPI) is 3% or more. The amount of the benefit increase is equal to the increase in the CPI from the first quarter of one year to the first quarter of the next year. The benefit increase is effective for June, and is first reflected in the check sent in early July. Options. D-1 Delay the cost-of-living adjustment by one month per year for 3 years, effective in 1983, so that, in 1985 and after, the benefit increase would be effective at the beginning of the fiscal year. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 98~ 9 983 89 II-B -1.0 -2.3 -3.4 -3.3 -3.3 -3.4 -3.5 -20.2 III -1.2 -2.9 -4.8 -5.1 -5.5 -5.8 -6.1 -31.4 25-Year Cost: -.12% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.13% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.14% of taxable payroll D-2 Delay the effective date for the cost-of-living adjustment for 3 months, effective in 1983. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B -3.0 -3.4 -3.4 -3.3 -3.3 -3.4 -3.5 -23.3 III -3.6 -4.4 -4.8 -5.1 -5.5 -5.8 -6.1 -35.3 25-Year Cost: -.12% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.13% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.14% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 21 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 D-3 Provide no cost-of-living adjustment for 1983.* Resume present-law benefit increases in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-13 -6.2 -12.9 -13.8 -14.5 -15.0 -15.4 -15.7 -93.5 III -7.3 -15.4 -16.8 -18.1 -19.3 -20.5 -21.5 -118.9 Long-Term Cost: -.13% of taxable payroll D-4 Provide a guaranteed benefit increase of 4% for 1983 and 1984, regardless of the change in the CPI.* In 1985 and thereafter, the annual benefit increase would equal the annual percentage increase in wages, minus 1/ percentage points. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 198419851986 1987 1988 191983-89 II-B -2.9 -9.3 -14.0 -16.2 -18.1 -19.5 -20.4 -100.4 III -4.0 -13.4 -22.1 -27.8 -32.8 -37.7 -42.3 -180.1 Long-Term Cost: -.16% of taxable payroll D-5 Same as Option D-4, except that the benefit increase in 1983-84 would not be less than that resulting from an increase of $14 in the PIA.** Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 91 838 II-13 -2.7 -8.8 -13.3 -15.5 -17.4 -18.8 -19.7 -96.2 III -3.8 -12.9 -21.4 -27.1 -32.1 -37.0 -41.5 -175.8 Long-Term cost: -.15% of taxable payroll * A parallel change could be made in the indexing of the bend points in the PIA benefit formula (which is based on wage changes). This would be done so as to prevent "notch" situations from occurring as between persons first becoming eligible in the year of the revised benefit increase and those first becoming eligible in the next year. Such a change would have relatively little cost effect in the short run, but would have a significant effect over the long run. ** The $14 increase would not be applicable for very low PIAs, which instead would have a 10% increase be applicable. Appendix K, page 22 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 D-6 Provide benefit increases equal to 75% of what the benefit increases would be under present law (i.e., 75% of the CPI increase), effective in 1983.* Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B -1.6 -5.0 -8.7 -12.5 -16.3 -20.1 -24.0 -88.2 III -1.8 -6.0 -11.2 -17.1 -23.6 -30.5 -38.0 -128.2 Long-Term Cost: -1.45% of taxable payroll D-7 Provide benefit increases equal to the increase in the CPI, minus 2 percentage points, effective in 1983.* Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B -1.7 -5.2 -9.3 -13.9 -18.9 -24.2 -30.0 -103.2 III -1.7 -5.3 -9.6 -14.7 -20.5 -27.1 -34.4 -113.3 Long-Term Cost: -2.58% of taxable payroll D-8 Same as option D-7, except effective only for 1983-84.* Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 159F --1987 1988 1989 198383 II-B -1.7 -5.2 -9.3 -11.8 -12.3 -12.7 -13.0 -66.1 III -1.7 -5.3 -9.6 -12.5 -13.4 -14.3 -15.1 -72.0 Long-Term Cost: -.07% of taxable payroll D-9 Same as Option D-8, except that benefit increases after 1984 would be based on annual percentage increases in wages, minus 1/ percentage points (instead of on annual CPI increases).* Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B -1.7 -5.2 -9.3 -12.5 -14.3 -15.6 -16.5 -75.2 III -1.7 -5.3 -9.6 -14.0 -18.2 -22.2 -26.3 -97.3 Long-Term Cost: -.11% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 23 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 D-10 Provide benefit increases equal to the annual percentage increase in wages, minus "X" percentage points, beginning in 1983. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 8~ 9 1983-89 Based on X Being 1% II-B -1.1 -2.8 - IT- - 4. 5 -4.8 -4.6 -3.9 -25.5 III -2.6 -8.3 -13.9 -18.1 -21.3 -24.2 -26.8 -115.2 Long-Term Cost: +.68% of taxable payroll Based on X Being 111% II-B -1.5 -4.1 -6. -8.0 -9.6 -10.7 -11.5 -51.5 III -3.0 -9.6 -16.3 -21.6 -26.2 -30.7 -35.1 -142.5 Long-Term Cost: -.09% of taxable payroll Based on X Being 2% II-B -1.9 -5.4 -8.5 -11.4 -14.2 -16.8 -19.0 -77.2 III -3.4 -10.9 -18.6 -25.1 -31.0 -37.0 -43.1 -169.1 Long-Term Cost: -.80% of taxable payroll Based on X Being .3% in 1983-85, 1% in 1986-88 and Thereafter*** II-B -.5 -.9 -.5 -.4 -.5 -.1 +.1 -2.8 III -1.9 -6.4 -10.6 -13.9 -16.8 -19.5 -22.6 -91.7 Long-Term Cost: Negligible Based on X Being .3% in 1983-85 1% in 1986-88, in 1989-2019, and Thereafter II-B -.5 -.9 -.5 -.4 +.1 -2.8 III -1.9 -6.4 -10.6 -13.9 -16.8 -19.5 -22.6 -91.7 Long-Term Cost: -.38%.of taxable payroll * These values of "X" approximate the real-wage differentials in the Alternative II-B estimate in the 1982 Trustees Report. Appendix K, page 24 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 D-11 Provide benefit increases based on the lesser of the annual percentage increase in wages or the.annual percentage increase in prices, beginning in 1983. Include a "catch-up" provision, so that in times of a healthy economy (when wages rise faster than prices), benefits will be increased by wages if they had previously been increased by less than the full CPI -- until any deficit relative to CPI rises is made up (so as to bring benefit levels up to the point where they are actually keeping up with inflation).**** -- - Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 F97 19 5 98~ 6 1987 1988 98~ 9 1983-89 II-B -.2 -.3 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.0 -.6 III -1.7 -5.7 -9.2 -10.9 -11.2 -11.0 -10.2 -59.9 Long-Term Cost: -.06% of taxable payroll D-12 Same as Option D-11, except that there would be no "catch-up" provision.**** Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1961987 198 1989-1 -89 II-B -.2 -.5 -.6 -.6 -.6 -.6 -.7 -3.8 III -1.7 -5.7 -9.2 -11.0 -11.8 -12.6 -13.7 -65.7 Long-Term Cost: -.43% of taxable payroll **** To further stabilize the financing of the program, this proposal could be combined with an automatic-adjustment mechanism for the payroll tax rate and/or payments (or loans) from the General Fund of the Treasury based on either the combined OASDI Trust Fund or the level of unemployment. Appendix K, page 25 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUMMARY OF SECTION E - LEVEL OF PRIMARY BENEFITS OASDI Cost 1983-89 (billions) Long- Term II-B III Cost -$3 -$3 -1.08% * * -1.01 0 0 -.80 0 0 -.60 0 0 -.37 -1/4 -1/4 -.22 -3 -3 -.25 -3 -3 -1.08 0 0 -.95 0 0 -.50 0 0 -.95 Option No. Description E-1 Increase "bend points" by 75% of the increase in wages until they are 80% of what they would have been under 100% wage indexing, effective 1984. E-2 Same as E-1, except effective date is 1987. E-3 Same as E-1, except effective date is 2000. E-4 Same as E-1, except effective date is 2010. E-5 Same as E-1, except effective date is 2020. E-6 Index "bend points" by 75% of increase in wages for 3 years, beginning 1987. E-7 Change computation point for determining Average Indexed Monthly Earnings from age 62 to age 65. E-8 Reduce percentages in PIA benefit formula gradually over time, by 10% relatively, effective in 1984. E-9 Same as E-8, except effective in 1990. E-10 Same as E-9, except 5% reduction. E-11 Same as E-9, except no reduction on first percentage and larger reductions on other two percentages. * Savings of less than million.- Appendix K, page 26 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 E. LEVEL OF PRIMARY BENEFITS Present law. The Primary Insurance Amount, which is the benefit payable to a worker retiring at age 65 (and also to a disabled worker) is determined from a formula based on Average Indexed Monthly Earnings. This formula involves three different percentages which are applied to different levels of the AIME (as separated by the "bend points"), so as to give relatively higher benefits to lower-earnings persons than to higher-earnings persons. Options. E-1 Increase the "bend points" in the PIA benefit formula by 75% of the increase in wages (rather than by 100% as under present law) for "X" years (until such bend points are 80% of what they would have been under 100% wage indexing), effective in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 .0 -.1 -.2 -.5 -.8 -1.3 -2.9 III 0 .0 -.1 -.2 -.6 -.9 -1.4 -3.2 25-Year Cost: -.28% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.79% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -1.08% of taxable payroll E-2 Same as Option E-1, except effective in 1987. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 9883899 II-B 0 0 0 0 -.0 -.1 -.2 -.3 III 0 0 0 0 -.0 -.1 -.3 -.4 Long-Term Cost: -1.01% of taxable payroll E-3 Same as Option E-1, except effective in 2000. 25-Year Cost: -.01% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.40% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.80% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 27 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 E-4 Same as Option E-1, except effective in 2010. 25-Year Cost: None 50-Year Cost: -.17% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.60% of taxable payroll E-5 Same as Option E-1, except effective in 2020. 25-Year Cost: None 50-Year Cost: -.03% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.37% of taxable payroll E-6 Index the "bend points" by 75% of the increase in wages for 3 years, effective in 1987. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 0 0 0 -.0 -.1 -.2 -.3 III 0 0 0 0 -.0 -.1 -.3 -.4 Long-Term Cost: -.22% of taxable payroll E-7 Change computation point for determining Average Indexed Monthly Earnings from age 62 to age 65 (so that, for retirement cases, 3 more computation years would be required in determining the AIME), phased in beginning with workers who attain age 62 in 1984. Cost in billions of dollars) - Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1 6 198 19881989 1983-89 II-B 0 .0 -.2 -.4 -.6 -.8 -1.0 -3.0 III 0 .0 -.2 -.4 -.7 -.9 -1.1 -3.3 Long-Term Cost: -.25% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 28 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 E-8 Reduce the percentages in the PIA benefit formula -- 90%, 32%, and 15% -- by 10% relatively, over a 15-year period (1984-98), so that they would ultimately be 81.0%, 28.8%, and 13.5%. This would have the effect ultimately of reducing benefits in all cases (regardless of earnings history) by 10%. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 -.0 -.1 -.2 -.4 -.8 -1.2 -2.8 III 0 -.0 -.1 -.2 -.5 -.9 -1.3 -3.0 Long-Term Cost: -1.08% of taxable payroll E-9 Same as Option E-8, except begin the reductions in 1990 (instead of 1984). Long-Term Cost: .95% of taxable payroll E-10 Same as Option E-9, except reduce the percentage factors by 5% relatively over an 8-year period. Long-Term Cost: .50% of taxable payroll E-11 Same as Option E-9, except that the 90% factor would not be reduced, and the 32% factor would be lowered to 25%, and the 15% factor would be lowered to 13%. Long-Term Cost: .95% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 29 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Option No. Description F-1 Increase "normal" retirement age to 66 in 1999, beginning phase-in in 1990. F-2 Increase "normal" retirement age to 66 in 2014, beginning phase-in in 2005. F-3 Increase "normal" retirement age to 66 in 2024, beginning phase-in in 2015. F-4 Increase "normal" retirement age to 67 in 2012, beginning phase-in in 2000. F-5 Increase "normal" retirement age to 67 in 2022, beginning phase-in in 2010. F-6 Increase "normal" retirement age to 67 in 2032, beginning phase-in in 2020. F-7 Increase "normal" retirement age to 68 in 2017, beginning phase-in in 2000. F-8 Increase "normal" retirement age to 68 in 2027, beginning phase-in in 2010. F-9 Increase "normal" retirement age to 68 in 2037, beginning phase-in in 2020. F-10 Increase "normal" retirement age to 69 in 2022, beginning phase-in in 2000. F-11 Increase "normal" retirement age to 69 in 2054, beginning phase-in in 2000. F-12 Increase "normal" retirement age to 66 in 2002, beginning phase-in in 1995, and thereafter, adjust according to changes in longevity. OASDI Cost 1983-89 (billions) Long- Term II-B III Cost $0 $0 -.52% 0 0 -.86 0 0 -.69 0 0 -.48 0 0 -1.22 0 0 -.95 0 0 -.63 0 0 -1.53 0 0 -.96 0 0 -1.68 Appendix K, page 30 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 F. RETIREMENT AGE Present law. Unreduced retirement benefits are available to insured workers, spouses, and widows and widowers at age 65 (the "normal" retirement age). Actuarially reduced benefits are available at age 62 for insured workers and spouses and at age 60 for widows and widowers (age 50 if disabled). For insured workers who delay receipt of benefits beyond age 65, retirement benefits are increased by 3% for each year of delay (for persons attaining age 65 after 1981). See table at bottom of this page for actuarial benefit factors under present law and under each option as to normal retirement age. Options. F-1 Gradually increase the "normal" retirement age to 66 in 1999, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 1990.* 25-Year Cost: -.14% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.38% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.52% of taxable payroll F-2 Gradually increase the "normal" retirement age to 66 in 2014, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 2005.* 25-Year Cost: -.00% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.23% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.41% of taxable payroll * Early-retirement benefits would continue to be available beginning at age 62 for insured workers and spouses and at age 60 for widows and widowers, but the actuarial benefit factors would be made smaller. The minimum age for eligibility for Medicare benefits would continue to be the "normal" retirement age for OASDI benefits. Disability benefits would be available to those disabled between age 65 and the increased "normal" retirement age, under the more lenient definition now applicable at ages 60-64. The age at which the earnings test no longer applies would be left at age 70 (if such age were increased in tandem with the increase in the normal retirement age, the reduction in cost would be somewhat larger). Normal Actuarial Benefit Factors Retirement Worker, Spouse, Widow, Disabled Ti ow, Age Age 62 Age 62 Age 60 Age 50 65 80.0% 75.0% 71.5% 50.0% 66 75.0 70.0 66.5 50.0 67 70.0 65.0 61.5 50.0 68 65.0 60.0 56.5 50.0 69 60.0 55.0 51.5 50.0 Appendix K, page 31 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 F-3 Gradually increase the normal retirement age to 66 in 2024, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 2015.* 25-Year Cost: None 50-Year Cost: -.12% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.31% of taxable payroll F-4 Gradually increase the "normal" retirement age to 67 in 2012, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 2000.* 25-Year Cost: -.03% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.54% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.86% of taxable payroll F-5 Gradually increase the "normal" retirement age to 67 in 2022, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 2010.* 25-Year Cost: None 50-Year Cost: -.32% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.69% of taxable payroll F-6 Gradually increase the "normal" retirement age to 67 in 2032, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 2020.* 25-Year Cost: None 50-Year Cost: -.09% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.48% of taxable payroll F-7 Gradually increase the "normal" retirement age to 68 in 2017, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 2000.* 25-Year Cost: -.03% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.72% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -1.22% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 32 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 F-8 Gradually increase the "normal" retirement age to 68 in 2027, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 2010.* 25-Year Cost: None 50-Year Cost: -.40% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.95% of taxable payroll F-9 Gradually increase the "normal" retirement age to 68 in 2037, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 2020.* 25-Year Cost: None 50-Year Cost: -.09% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.63% of taxable payroll F-10 Gradually increase the "normal" retirement age to 69 in 2022, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 2000.* 25-Year Cost: -.03% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.88% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -1.53% of taxable payroll F-11 Gradually increase the "normal" retirement age to 69 in 2054, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 2000.* 25-Year Cost: -.01% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.36% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.96% of taxable payroll F-12 Gradually increase the "normal" retirement age to 66 in 2002, beginning the phase-in with those who attain age 62 in 1995. Beginning with those who attain age 62 in 2002, automatically adjust such age (on a phased-in basis) so that the ratio of the retirement-life expectancy to the potential working-lifetime (from age 20 to the "normal" retirement age) remains the same over the years. The age at which early- retirement benefits are first payable and the age at which the earnings test no longer applies would be increased in tandem with the increase in the normal retirement age. Long-Term Cost: -1.68% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 33 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUMMARY OF SECTION G - DISABILITY BENEFITS Option No. Description G-1 Use medical-only definition of disability. G-2 Apply disability eligibility criteria under present law for persons aged 60-64, to persons aged 55 and over. G-3 Increase disability waiting period from 5 months to 6 months. G-4 Require prognosis of 24 months of disability. G-5 Change requirement for disability-insured status by increasing recency-of-work test to 30 quarters of coverage in last 40 quarters (rather than 20 out of 40). G-6 Change requirement for disability-insured status by eliminating the test of 20 quarters of coverage out of the last 40 quarters. OASDI Cost 1983-89 (billions) Long- Term II-B III Cost -$10 -$11 -.06% +1 +2 +.04 -2 -2 -.03 -4 -5 -.06 Appendix K, page 34 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 G. DISABILITY BENEFITS Present law. Benefits are available to insured workers who meet the statutory definition of disability, with a waiting period of 5 full calendar months before the first month of eligibility. Options. G-1 Establish a medical-only definition of disability (so that non-medical factors -- such as age, education, and work experience -- would no longer be considered in determining disability), effective for benefits for months after 1983 based on disabilities which begin after June 1983. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 -.2 -.6 -1.3 -2.0 -2.7 -3.4 -10.2 III 0 -.2 -.7 -1.4 -2.2 -3.1 -3.8 -11.4 Long-Term Cost: -.06% of taxable payroll G-2 Apply disability eligibility criteria under present law for persons aged 60-64, to persons aged 55 and over, effective in 1985. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 0 +.1 +.2 +.3 +.4 +.4 +1.4 III 0 0 +.1 +.2 +.3 +.4 +.5 +1.5 25-Year Cost: +.03% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: +.04% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: +.04% of taxable payroll G-3 Increase waiting period to 6 months (instead of 5 months, as at present), effective for benefits for months after 1983 based on disabilities which begin after June 1983. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 -.1 -.3 -.3 -.3 -.3 -.4 -1.6 III 0 -.1 -.2 -.3 -.3 -.4 -.4 -1.8 Long-Term Cost: -.03% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 35 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 G-4 Require prognosis of at least 24 months of disability (instead of 12 months, as at present), effective for benefits for months after 1983 based on disabilities which begin after June 1983. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 -.1 -.4 -.6 -.8 -.9 -1.0 -3.8 III 0 -.1 -.5 -.7 -1.0 -1.1 -1.2 -4.6 Long-Term Cost: -.06% of taxable payroll G-5 Increase requirement for disability-insured status by requiring 30 Quarters of Coverage in the last 40 Quarters (instead of 20 QC out of 40), effective for benefits for months after 1983, based on disabilities which begin after June 1983. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 -.1 -.3 -.7 -1.0 -1.4 -1.7 -5.2 III 0 -.1 -.3 -.7 -1.1 -1.6 -2.0 -5.8 Long-Term Cost: -.25% of taxable payroll G-6 Change the requirement for disability-insured status by eliminating the test of 20 QC out of the last 40 quarters, effective in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 +2.0 +3.3 +3.5 +3.6 +3.7 +3.9 +20.0 III 0 +2.0 +3.5 +3.7 +3.9 +4.2 +4.5 +21.8 Long-Term Cost: +.24% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 36 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUMMARY OF SECTION H - PROPOSALS AFFECTING PRIMARILY WOMEN OASDI Cost 1983-89 Long- (billions) Term Option No. Description II-B III Cost H-1 Divorced and disabled widow(er)'s benefits not to be terminated upon remarriage. H-2 Provide benefits of 71.5% of +$1 +$1 +.01% deceased worker's PIA to disabled widow(er)s claiming benefits at ages 50-59. H-3 Provide benefits of 100% of +6 +6 +.03 the deceased worker's PIA to disabled widow(er)s claiming benefits at ages 50-64. H-4 Permit widow(er)s to rescind an early-retirement decision in certain cases by counting the reduction in the widow(er)'s benefit as "repayment" of the early-retirement benefits paid. H-5 Provide indexing of earnings records for purposes of deferred survivor benefits by wages instead of by prices. H-6 Permit a divorced spouse to receive benefits regardless of whether the insured former spouse has retired. * Less than $/ billion or less than .005% of payroll (as the case may be). The costs of each of these alternatives are shown on subsequent pages. Appendix K, page 37 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUMMARY OF SECTION H - CONTINUED Option No. Description H-7 Change special-minimum benefit to allow credit for 10 childcare years; increase number of years countable toward the special-minimum benefit from 30 to 35 years. H-8 Allow up to 3, 5, or 10 childcare drop-out years in computing the average earnings. H-9 Adopt comprehensive earnings sharing, with 80% inheritance of earnings credits. H-10 Adopt earnings sharing with 100% inheritance of earnings credits. H-11 Adopt limited earnings sharing at divorce, and inheritance of earnings credits. H-12 Adopt the HHS development of the recommendations of the 1979 Advisory Council regarding earnings sharing. Appendix K, page 38 OASDI Cost 1983-89 (billions) Long- Term II-B III Cost +15 +16 +.14 n.a. n.a. n.a. -.06 n.a. n.a. +.35 n.a. n.a. +.07 n.a. n.a. +.12 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 H. PROPOSALS AFFECTING PRIMARILY WOMEN Widow(er)'s Benefits Present law. Benefits for widow(er)s who are divorced spouses and for disabled widow(er)s terminate when the beneficiary remarries. Option. H-1 Do not terminate such benefits upon remarriage, effective in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 98~ 5 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.1 III 0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.1 Long-Term Cost: Negligible Disabled Widow(er)'s Benefits Present law. Reduced benefits for widow(er)s without dependent children are available at ages 60-64 (712% of PIA at age 60), and 100% of the PIA is available at an 65. Disabled widow(er)s are eligible for reduced benefits at ages 50-59 0% of PIA at age 50). Option. H-2 Provide benefit of 71.5% of PIA (same as widow(er)'s benefits at age 60) to disabled widow(er)s claiming benefits at ages 50-59, effective in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 +.2 +.2 +.2 +.2 +.3 +.3 +1.4 III 0 +.2 +.2 +.2 +.2 +.3 +.3 +1.4 Long-Term Cost: +.01% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 39 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 H-3 Provide benefit of 100% of PIA to disabled widow(er)s aged 50-64, effective in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 198 1983-99 II-B 0 +.8 +.8 +.9 +1.0 +1.0 +1.1 +5.6 III 0 +.8 +.8 +.9 +1.0 +1.1 +1.2 +5.8 Long-Term Cost: +.03% of taxable payroll Limit on Widow(er)'s Benefits Present law. There is an over-riding limit which is only applicable when the deceased worker had received early-retirement benefits; then, the widow's benefit cannot exceed the larger of the early-retirement benefit or 82.5% of the PIA. This maximum is applicable only when the widow is at least age 62 and has the most effect when the woman was older than her husband. Option. H-4 When such limit on widow(er)'s benefits is applicable, and the retired worker dies before age 65, the widow(er) may "rescind" the early- retirement decision by counting the reduction in the widow(er)'s benefit resulting from such limit as "repayment" of the early- retirement benefits paid (including any auxiliary benefits). The period of repayment should be determined from the amounts payable to the beneficiaries who are eligible as of the date of the worker's death. Long-Term Cost: Negligible Computation of Deferred Widow(er)'s Benefits Present law. If a worker dies before reaching age 62, benefits for the widow(er) are based on the worker's earnings, as indexed to average wage levels in the second year preceding death; the benefit is indexed in and after the year of death to reflect changes in the CPI. Appendix K, page 40 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Option. H-5 Index earnings records for purposes of deferred survivor benefits (e.g., a woman widowed at age 55 is first eligible for widow's benefits at age 60) through the earlier of (1) the year that the worker would have reached age 60, or (2) two years before the survivor becomes eligible for aged widow's benefits at age 60, effective in 1985. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1982-89 II-B 0 0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.1 +.1 +.2 III 0 0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.1 +.1 +.2 Long-Term Cost: +.05% of taxable payroll Divorced Persons Present law. A divorced spouse cannot receive spouse's benefits until the former spouse begins to receive benefits. Option. H-6 A divorced spouse (divorced at least 3 years) would be able to receive benefits if he or she meets the age requirements for eligibility, regardless of whether or not the insured former spouse, aged 62 or over, has retired (the earnings test would apply to each independently), effective in 1984.* Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.1 III 0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.0 +.1 Long-Term Cost: Negligible As an alternative, the option could provide for a 1-year divorce requirement, instead of a 3-year requirement. Appendix K, page 41 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Childcare Credits Present law. To compute the Average Indexed Monthly Earnings of retired workers, the 5 lowest years of indexed earnings are dropped from the appropriate averaging period. For workers attaining age 62 in 1991 or later, retirement benefits will be based on the highest 35 years of indexed earnings. Present law also provides a special minimum benefit as an alternative computation based on the worker's "years of coverage", which is designed for long-service workers with earnings at approximately the Federal minimum-wage level. Options. H-7 Change provisions for special-minimum benefit so as to allow credit for up to 10 childcare years (in which the worker had a child age 6 or under and did not earn enough to gain a year of coverage). Increase the number of years countable toward the special minimum benefit from 30 to 35, effective in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 19831984-198b198619871988 1989 -5 II-B 0 +1.8 +2.1 +2.4 +2.6 +2.9 +3.2 +15.0 III 0 +1.8 +2.2 +2.5 +2.8 +3.2 +3.6 +16.1 Long-Term Cost: +.14% of taxable payroll H-8 Allow up to (alternatively) 3, 5, or 10 childcare drop-out years in computing Average Indexed Monthly Earnings for the purpose of calculating benefits under the regular benefit formula for each year the worker had a child under age 7 and did not earn more than half of the average wage of all covered workers during the year, effective in 1984.** Long-Term Cost for Allowing up to 3 Years: +.21% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost for Allowing up to 5 Years: +.36% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost for Allowing up to 10 Years: +.60% of taxable payroll Cost data for the short-term period are not available, but relatively little increase in cost would be involved during 1983-89. Appendix K, page 42 396-938 0 - 83 - 16 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Earnings Sharing Proposals H-9 Comprehensive "No-Cost" Plan. The DREW report, "Social Security and the Changing o es of en and Women", presented a comprehensive earnings-sharing proposal, within a "no cost" framework. Under the proposal, a person's Social Security protection would be based on her or his earnings when unmarried and, when married, on one-half of the total earnings credits of the married couple. A couple's annual earnings would be divided equally during years of marrriage. The earnings would be split equally on divorce or when one spouse reaches age 62. Such split would not apply under certain conditions: (1) on death of a spouse, 80% of total earnings would be inherited, but not less than 100% of the earnings of the higher earner; (2) for purposes of benefits for young survivors, earnings would not be transferred between spouses with regard to a marriage in effect at time of death; and (3) for purposes of disability benefits, earnings would not be shared with regard to a marriage in effect at time of disability. The proposal did not include any transitional proposals. Long-Term Cost: -.06% of taxable payroll H-10 Plan for Earnings Sharing and Inheritance of Earnings Credits considered but not recommended by 1979 Adv-sory Council). Credits earned during years of marriage would be divided equally between spouses. Benefits for each person would be based upon earnings before and after the marriage, plus half the couple's earnings during the marriage. Earnings would be shared only for years after 1980. If the higher-earner retired or became disabled before the lower-earner, he or she would receive benefits based on the higher-earner's full earnings, rather than half of the couple's combined earnings. Under a transitional provision (phased out by 2020), couples would receive the higher of the benefit calculated under earnings sharing or the benefit calculated under a transitional formula assuring the same purchasing power as under present law. A survivor would inherit the earnings credits of a deceased spouse acquired during the marriage. The survivor would receive 100% of the couple's combined earnings credits, plus any credits which the survivor had earned before or after the marriage. Long-Term cost: +.35% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 43 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 H-11 1979 Advisory Council Recommendation for Inheritance of Earnings Credits at Death of Spouse and Limited Earnings Sharing at Divorce. A survivor could inherit the earnings credits of a deceased spouse from work that occurred during their marriage. At ages 60-61, reduced widow(er)'s benefits would be calculated only from inherited earnings credits. At age 62, the individual would be eligible for retired worker's benefits based on inherited earnings credits combined with own earnings credits. Inheritance would also eliminate disabled widow(er)'s benefits, because eligibility for DI could be established through inheritance. Upon request by either partner in a marriage of at least 10 years that ended in divorce, earnings credits would be split, for purposes of calculating retirement benefits only. Long-Term Cost: +.07% of taxable payroll, without hold-harmless provision* H-12 HHS Development of the Recommendations of the 1979 Advisory Council. Either partner, at time of divorce, could apply to have earnings credits shared for years during a marriage. Disability benefits would be calculated based on shared earnings, but entitlement to disability could not be gained therefrom. Credits acquired during years of marriage would be credited to the earnings record of the surviving spouse. Inherited credits would substitute for all present-law benefits payable to aged and disabled widow(er)s. Benefits for surviving children, widowed mothers and fathers, and children of retired or disabled workers would not be affected. Under the transition provision, those reaching age 62 before 2010 would be eligible for the new basis, but would continue to be eligible for auxiliary and survivor benefits if higher. Long-Term cost: +.12% of taxable payroll * The Advisory Council did not recommend a hold-harmless provision, which would provide present benefits for aged and disabled widow(er)s forever, if higher. With such a provision, the estimated long-term cost of this proposal is +.22% of taxable payroll. Appendix K, page 44 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUMMARY OF SECTION I - OTHER OPTIONS FOR BENEFIT CHANGES Option No. Description I-1 Eliminate child's benefits for early-retirement cases. 1-2 Eliminate all auxiliary benefits for early-retirement cases. 1-3 Apply same Maximum Family Benefit for OASI cases as currently used for DI cases. 1-4 Phase out retirement earnings test for persons aged 65 and over in 1988, with annual exempt amount increasing in 1985-87. I-5 Maintain age 72 as age at which earnings test does not apply. 1-6 Increase delayed-retirement credit from 3% to 6% for each year that retirement is postponed past age 65. I-7 Provide partial refundable income tax credit at ages 65 and over when benefits are withheld under the earnings test. 1-8 Provide 10% benefit increase for beneficiaries when they reach age 80, gradually phased in. Appendix K, page 45 OASDI Cost 1983-89 (billions) II-B III Long- Term Cost -$3 -$3 -.02% -6 -7 -.02 -4 -4 -.10 +15 +17 +.14 -5 -6 -.03 +1 +1 +.07 0 0 0 +6 +7 +.25 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 I. OTHER OPTIONS REGARDING BENEFIT CHANGES I-1 Eliminate benefits for children of retired workers who have not attained age 65, effective for persons attaining age 62 in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1988 89 II-B 0 -.1 -.2 -.4 -.6 -.7 -.8 -2.8 III 0 -.1 -.2 -.4 -.7 -.8 -.9 -3.1 Long-Term Cost: -.02% of taxable payroll 1-2 Eliminate all auxiliary benefits for early-retirement cases, effective for persons attaining age 62 in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 198619871988 1989 -198'3 II-B 0 -.1 -.4 -.8 -1.4 -1.7 -1.8 -6.2 III 0 -.1 -.4 -.9 -1.6 -1.9 -2.0 -6.9 Long-Term Cost: -.02% of taxable payroll 1-3 Apply same Maximum Family Benefit for OASI cases as is currently used for DI cases, effective for persons attainin age 62 after 1983 and for deaths before age 62 occurring after 1983. (In DI cases, family benefits are limited to the lesser of 85% of AIME or 150% of PIA, but never less than 100% of PIA.) Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 98~ 6 1987 981 8 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 -.1 -.3 -.5 -.7 -1.0 -1.3 -3.9 III 0 -.1 -.3 -.5 -.8 -1.1 -1.4 -4.2 Long-Term Cost: -.10% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 46 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 1-4 Phase out retirement earnings test for beneficiaries aged 65 and over, with annual exempt amount increasing to $10,000 in 1985, $15,000 in 1986, and $20,000 in 1987, and with elimination of test in 1988. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 0 +.8 +1.6 +2.4 +5.1 +5.5 +15.4 III 0 0 +.8 +1.7 +2.7 +5.8 +6.4 +17.4 Long-Term Cost: +.14% of taxable payroll 1-5 Maintain age 72 as age at which earnings test no longer applies. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B -.6 -.6 -.7 -.7 -.8 -.9 -.9 -5.2 III -.6 -.6 -.7 -.8 -.9 -1.0 -1.1 -5.7 25-Year Cost: -.02% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: -.03% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: -.03% of taxable payroll 1-6 Increase the delayed-retirement credit from 3% to 6% for each year that receipt of benefits is postponed past age 65 up until age 70, beginning in 1983. Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 198 988 1989 1983-89 II-B +.0 +.0 +.0 +.1 +.2 +.4 +.6 +1.3 III +.0 +.0 +.0 +.1 +.2 +.4 +.7 +1.4 25-Year Cost: +.02% of taxable payroll 50-Year Cost: +.05% of taxable payroll Long-Term Cost: +.07% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 47 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 1-7 Provide a partial refundable income tax credit for persons aged 65 and over who do not receive benefits because of the earnings test (recommendation of 1981 National Commission on Social Security), effective in 1983. No short-term or long-term cost to trust funds 1-8 Provide a 10% increase in benefit amounts for beneficiaries when they attain age 80, phased in over a 10-year period (i.e., a 1% increase during 1984, rising to 10% during 1993 and after). Cost (in billions of dollars) Estimate 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 II-B 0 +.2 +.5 +.9 +1.3 +1.6 +2.0 +6.5 III 0 +.2 +.5 +1.0 +1.5 +1.8 +2.3 +7.3 Long-Term Cost: +.25% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 48 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUMMARY OF SECTION J - TAXATION OF BENEFITS Option No. Description J-1 Include 50% of OASDI benefits in adjusted gross income for income-tax purposes, with the proceeds credited to the OASDI Trust Funds. J-2 Same as Option J-1, except that 100% of OASDI benefits would be included in adjusted gross income. J-3 Include OASDI benefits in adjusted gross income for purposes of the income tax in the same manner as are unemployment benefits, with the proceeds being credited to the OASDI Trust Funds. J-4 Include all OASDI benefits in adjusted gross income as soon as such benefits first exceed the total employee OASDI taxes paid, with the proceeds being credited to the OASDI Trust Funds. J-5 Consider OASDI benefits as "income" for purposes of determining marginal income tax rates applicable to other income (OASDI benefits would not be taxable), with the proceeds being credited to the OASDI Trust Funds. J-6 Include 50% of OASDI benefits in adjusted gross income, phased-in over 40 years, with the proceeds being credited to the OASDI Trust Funds. Also, there would be a phased-in exclusion of the employee OASDI taxes from such gross income. J-7 Same as Option J-6 except that 100% of benefits would be included in adjusted gross income. Note: See subsequent pages for cost data, which are not summarized here because of the diverse nature of the estimates for the various proposals. Note: The short-range cost estimates presented here were prepared by the staff of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, Department of Health and Human Services. The staff of the Joint Committee on Taxation, U.S. Congress, has also made estimates of this type, and these tend to be higher than those shown in this Section (e.g., for Option J-3, the total savings for 1983-89 shown here as $29 billion are $46 billion according to the Joint Committee estimate). Appendix K, page 49 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 J. TAXATION OF BENEFITS* Present law. OASDI benefits are not subject to income tax. Options. J-1 Include 50% of OASDI benefits in adjusted gross income for Federal income-tax purposes, with the proceeds credited to the OASDI Trust Funds, effective in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) 1989 1983-89 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 Long-Term Cost: -.6% of taxable payroll J-2 Same as Option J-1, except that 100% of OASDI benefits would be included in adjusted gross income. Cost (in billions of dollars) 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 0 -17.7 -19.5 -21.4 -23.3 -25.3 -27.4 -134.6 Long-Term Cost: -1.4% of taxable payroll All proposals in this section assume that the tax credit for persons aged and over is eliminated. Such elimination provides most of the additional revenue in the early years for proposals J-3, J-4, J-6, and J-7. Appendix K, page 50 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 J-3 If benefits plus other income exceed $12,000 for single persons or $18,000 for married couples, then include $1 of OASDI benefits for each $2 of income above the respective thresholds in adjusted gross income for Federal income tax purposes, up to a maximum of 50% of OASDI benefits. (Unemployment benefits are currently treated somewhat in this manner.) The proceeds would be credited to the OASDI Trust Funds, effective in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 0 -3.4 -3.9 -4.5 -5.1 -5.7 -6.4 -29.0 Long-Term Cost: .5% of taxable payroll if dollar figures remain unchanged over the long-range (or .3% of taxable payroll if they are indexed to wage changes). J-4 Include the amount of OASDI benefits paid after 1983, after recovery of employee contributions, in adjusted gross income for Federal income tax purposes. The proceeds would be credited to the OASDI Trust Funds, effective in 1984. Short-Term Cost: Little effect in the first few years. Ultimately, the effect would be similar to Option J-2. Long-Term Cost: -1.2% of taxable payroll J-5 Consider OASDI benefits as "income" for purposes of determining the marginal Federal income tax rates applicable to other income, but continue to exclude OASDI benefits from such taxation. The additional proceeds resulting from such changed procedure would be credited to the OASDI Trust Funds, effective in 1984. Cost (in billions of dollars) 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1983-89 0 -13.1 -14.4 -15.7 -17.0 -18.3 -19.7 -98.1 Long-Term Cost: n.a. n.a. = not available Appendix K, page 51 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 J-6 Include 50% of OASDI benefits in adjusted gross income for Federal income-tax purposes, phased in over 40 years, with the proceeds being credited to the OASDI Trust Funds, effective in 1984. At the same time, there would be a phased-in exclusion of the employee OASDI taxes from such gross income (the resulting loss in tax revenues would not be taken from the OASDI Trust Funds). Short-Term Cost: Little effect in the early years. Long-Term Cost: -.4% of taxable payroll J-7 Same as Option J-6, except that 50% of OASDI benefits would be included in such adjusted gross income in 1984, with increases over 40 years so that ultimately 100% would be so included. Short-Term Cost: Little effect in the early years. Long-Term Cost: -1.20% of taxable payroll Appendix K, page 52 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 SUMMARY OF SECTION K - OTHER ISSUES Option No. Description K-1 Trust-fund investment procedures. K-2 Social Security and the unified budget. K-3 Social Security Administration to become an independent agency. K-4 Benefits to certain overseas beneficiaries. K-5 Eliminate mandatory retirement. K-6 Require continued accrual of pensions. K-7 Encourage employment of low-income older workers. Appendix K, page 53 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 K. OTHER ISSUES K-1 Trust-Fund Investment Procedures Present law. The OASI, DI, HI, and SMI Trust Funds are invested in U.S. Government obligations, primarily in special issues, but also in publicly available obligations of the Federal government or certain Federal agencies. Maturity dates for the special issues are intended generally to be spread in equal amounts over the next 15 years. The interest rate for new special issues is equal to the average market- yield rate on all marketable government obligations that are not due or callable for at least 4 years. Option. Revise the investment procedures of the four trust funds in the following manner -- (1) in the future, all special issues would be invested on a month-to-month basis, at an interest rate based on the average market rate of all public-debt obligations outstanding, exclusive of "flower" bonds; (2) all present special issues would be redeemed; (3) all "flower" bonds would be redeemed at their current market values (not their face or maturity values); and (4) all other current holdings would be held until maturity. K-2 Social Security and the Unified Budget Present law. The operations of the OASI, DI, HI, and SMI Trust Funds are included in the Unified Budget. Option. Remove the operations of the four trust funds from the Unified Budget. K-3 Social Security Administration to Become Independent Agency Present law. The Social Security Administration is under the jurisdiction of the Department of Health and Human Services. Option. Establish an independent Social Security agency, removed from the Department of Health and Human Services, and reporting directly to the President. This agency would be headed by a board, which might consist of three members appointed by the President, with Senate confirmation (e.g., the Chairman would have a term corresponding with that of the President, while the other two members would have to be of different political parties, with 4-year terms expiring at the end of 1986, 1990, etc.). Appendix K, page 54 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 K-4 Benefits to Certain Overseas Beneficiaries Present law. OASDI benefits are payable outside of the United States -- whether to citizens or non-citizens -- on exactly the same basis as in the United States, except when the individual is a non- citizen and had only a short period of coverage, or when the individual is a citizen of a country which does not pay benefits to U.S. citizens under parallel circumstances, or when the individual is residing in a country where there is no reasonable assurance that checks can be cashed at full value. Option. Prohibit benefit eligibility for auxiliary benefits for spouses and children of beneficiaries living abroad when such auxiliary beneficiary had not resided in the U.S. for at least 5 years and when such auxiliary beneficiary continues to reside abroad. Long-Term Cost: -.01% of taxable payroll K-5 Eliminate Mandatory Retirement Amend the Age Discrimination in Employment Act to remove the upper age limit of 70, thereby eliminating mandatory retirement at any age. Long-Term Cost: -.03% of taxable payroll K-6 Require Continued Accrual of Pensions Amend the Employee Retirement Income Security Act to require employers to continue accruing pensions for workers after age 65. Long-Term Cost: n.a. K-7 Encourage Employment of Low Income Older Workers Amend the Targeted Jobs Tax Credit to include low income older workers (age 62+). Long-Term Cost: n.a. Appendix K, page 55 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 LIST OF TABLES 1. Summary of current Social Security information. 2. Past and future OASDI-HI tax rates and taxable earnings bases (Table A -- employer and employee, each; Table B -- employer and employee combined; Table C -- self-employed). 3. Growth of OASDI-HI programs, selected years 1940-81 and estimated future operations during CY 1982-86 under Alternatives II-A and II-B. (Tables A-C refer to OASDI and Table D refers to HI.) 4. Historical trust-fund ratio levels for OASDI, DI, and HI Trust Funds, 1950 to present. 5. Estimated operations of the OASI, DI, and HI Trust Funds in the short range, Alternatives I, II-A, II-B, and III. 6. Long-range status of the OASDI-HI Trust Funds under Alternatives I, II-A, II-B, and III. 7. Estimated cost rates of the OASDI-HI system under Alternatives II-A, II-B, and III and comparison with tax rates, 1982-2060. (Tables A, B, and C) 8. Estimated OASI and DI Trust Fund ratios under Alternatives I, II-A, II-B, and III, 1982-2060. 9. Estimated cost of OASDI and HI systems as percent of Gross National Product, 1982-2060. (Tables A and B) 10. Additional resources required under present law in near term to bring OASDI reserves up to certain levels (trust fund ratios of 15%, 25%, 50%, and 75%) under Alternatives II-B and III. (Tables A-D) 11. Comparison of OASDI beneficiaries and covered workers; includes worker to beneficiary ratios, historical and projected under Alternatives I, II-A, II-B, and III, 1945-2060. 12. Demographic data -- historical and assumptions under Alternatives I, II-A, II-B, and III regarding total fertility rate and life expectancy (at birth and at age 65), 1940-2060. 13. Economic data -- historical and assumptions under Alternatives I, II-A, II-B, and III, 1960-2060. 14. Comparison of estimated and actual key economic indicators -- 1972 and 1977 forecasts. 15. Social Security coverage (includes information on percentage of workers covered, percentage of earnings covered and taxable payroll). 16. Social Security taxes paid by workers at Federal minimum, average, and maximum wage levels, 1937-90 (employees and the self-employed). 17. Historical comparison of average wage increases and increase in the CPI to Social Security benefit increases. (Tables A and B) Appendix K, page 56 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 1 SUMMARY OF CURRENT SOCIAL SECURITY INFORMATION 1. Retirement Test (Annual Exempt Amounts in 1982): Age 65 and over - $6,000 Under age 65 - $4,440 2. SMI Premium: $12.20 per month (eff. 7/82) 3. SSI Payment Standard: $284.30 individual, $426.40 couple (eff. 7/82) 4. 5. Benefit Formulas for 1982 Cohort PIA Maximum Family Benefit 90% of first $230 of AIME, plus 32% of AIME over $230 thru $1,388, plus 15% of AIME over $1,388 Average Benefits in Current Pay Status: 1 / 150% of first 294 of PIA, plus 272% of PIA over $294 thru $425, plus 134% of PIA over $425 thru $554, plus 175% of PIA over $554 12/81 5/82 6/82 Retired worker alone 3 7 $378 0-6 Retired couple 643 647 695 Aged widow or widower 349 351 377 Young survivor family 858 851 914 Disabled worker alone 397 398 428 Disabled worker and family Benefit Examples: 802 793 851 Long-Range Constant Replacement Retired Worker Age 65 in 1983 Rate Under Decoupled System 1/83 PIA Fed. min. wage earner $368.70 Fed. minimum wage earner 55% Average earner 552.50 Average earner 42 Maximum earner 709.50 Maximum earner 28 7. Poverty Level: 1980 1981 1982 (actual) (preliminary) (projected) Aged individual $3,949 $4,360 4,680 Couple, aged head 4,983 5,500 5,900 Family of four 8,414 9,290 9,970 Office of the Actuary, Social Security Administration 2/ Office of Research and Statistics, Social Security Administration Appendix K, page 57 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 2A PAST AND FUTURE TAX RATES FOR EMPLOYERS, EMPLOYEES, AND SELF-EMPLOYED PERSON OASDI HI OASDI-HI Employers and Employees, Each 1977 4.95% .90% 5.85% 1978 5.05 1.00 6.05 1979-80 5.08 1.05 6.13 1981 5.35 1.30 6.65 1982-84 5.40 1.30 6.70 1985 5.70 1.35 7.05 1986-89 5.70 1.45 7.15 1990 and after 6.20 1.45 7.65 Self-Employed Persons 1977 7.00% .90% 7.90% 1978 7.10 1.00 8.10 1979-80 7.05 1.05 8.10 1981 8.00 1.30 9.30 1982-84 8.05 1.30 9.35 1985 8.55 1.35 9.90 1986-89 8.55 1.45 10.00 1990 and after 9.30 1.45 10.75 Appendix K, page 58 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 2B PAST AND FUTURE TAX RATES AND TAXABLE EARNINGS BASES FOR EMPLOYER AND EMPLOYEE COMBINED Taxable Tax R ate Maximum Period Earnings Base OASDI a/ HI Total Employee Annual Tax 1937-49 $ 3,000 2.05 2.0% $ 30.00 1950 3,000 3.0 3.0 45.00 1951-53 3,600 3.0 3.0 54.00 1954 3,600 4.0 4.0 72.00 1955-56 4,200 4.0 4.0 84.00 1957-58 4,200 4.5(.5) 4.5 94.50 1959 4,800 5.0(.5) 5.0 120.00 1960-61 4,800 6.0(.5) 6.0 144.00 1962 4,800 6.25(.5) 6.25 150.00 1963-65 4 , 800 7.25(.5) 7.25 174.00 1966 6,600 7.7(.7) .75 8.4 277.20 1967 6,600 7.8(.7) 1.0 8.8 290.40 1968 7,800 7.6(.95) 1.2 8.8 343.20 1969 7,800 8.4(.95) 1.2 9.6 374.40 1970 7,800 8.4(1.1) 1.2 9.6 374.40 1971 7,800 9.2(1.1) 1.2 10.4 405.60 1972 9,000 9.2(1.1) 1.2 10.4 468.00 1973 10,800 9.7(1.1) 2.0 11.7 631.80 1974 13,200 9.9(1.15) 1.8 11.7 772.20 1975 14,100 9.9(1.15) 1.8 11.7 824.85 1976 15,300 9.9,(1.15) 1.8 11.7 895.05 1977 16,500 9.9(1.15) 1.8 11.7 965.25 1978 17 , 700 10.1(1.55) 2.0 12.1 1,070.85 1979 22,900 10.16(1.50) 2.1 12.26 1,403.77 1980 25,900 10.16(1.12) 2.1 12.26 1,587.67 1981 29,700 10.7(1.30) 2.6 13.3 1,975.05 1982 32.400 10.8(1.65) 2.6 13.4 2.170.80 1983 35,700 10.8(1.65) 2.6 13.4 2,391.90 1984 38,100 b/ 10.8(1.65) 2.6 13.4 2,552.70 1985 41,100 b/ 11.4(1.90) 2.7 14.1 2,897.55 1986-89 b/ 11.4(1.90) 2.9 14.3 b/ 1990 and after 12.4(2.20) 2.9 15.3 b/ a/ Figures in parentheses are portion of total OASDI tax which is allocated to DI. b/ Base is subject to automatic adjustment after 1981. Figures for 1984-85 are based on the 1982 Trustees Report (intermediate assumptions -- Alternative II-B). Note: Cumulative employee taxes at maximum wages are $14,765.69 for 1937-81 and $14,330.69 for 1951-81. Appendix K, page 59 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 2C PAST AND FUTURE TAX RATES AND TAXABLE EARNINGS BASES FOR SELF-EMPLOYED Taxable Tax Rate Earnings Base OASDIa/ HI Total Maximum Annual Tax 1951-53 $ 3,600 2.25% 2.25% $ 81.00 1954 3,600 3.00 3.00 108.00 1955-56 4,200 3.00 3.00 126.00 1957-58 4,200 3.375(.375) 3.375 141.75 1959 4,800 3.75(.375) 3.75 180.00 1960-61 4,800 4.50(.375) 4.50 216.00 1962 4,800 4.70(.375) 4.70 225.60 1963-65 4,800 5.40(.375) 5.40 259.20 1966 6,600 5.80(.525) .35 6.15 405.90 1967 6,600 5.90(.525) .50 6.40 422.40 1968 7,800 5.80(.7125) .60 6.40 499.20 1969 7,800 6.30(.7125) .60 6.90 538.20 1970 7,800 6.30(.825) .60 6.90 538.20 1971 7,800 6.90(.825) .60 7.50 585.00 1972 9,000 6.90(.825) .60 7.50 675.00 1973 10,800 7.00(.795) 1.00 8.00 854.00 1974 13,200 7.00(.815) .90 7.90 1,042.80 1975 14,100 7.00(.815) .90 7.90 1,113.90 1976 15,300 7.00(.815) .90 7.90 1,208.70 1977 16, 500 7.00(.815) .90 7.90 1,303.50 1978 179700 7.10(1.0900) 1.00 8.10 1,433.70 1979 22,900 7.05 (1.0400) 1.05 8.10 1,854.90 1980 25,900 7.05(.7775) 1.05 8.10 2,097.90 1981 29,700 8.00(.9750) 1.30 9.30 2,762.10 1982 32,400 8.05(1.2375) 1.30 9.35 3,029.40 1983 35,700 8.05(1.2375) 1.30 9.35 3,337.95 1984 38,100 b/ 8.05(1.2375) 1.30 9.35 3,562.35 1985 41,100 b/ 8.55(1.4250) 1.35 9.90 4,068.90 1986-89 b/ 8.55(1.4250) 1.45 10.00 b/ 1990 and after b/ 9.30(1.6500) 1.45 10.75 F1 a/ Figures in parentheses are portion of total OASDI tax which is allocated to DI. b/ Base is subject to automatic adjustment after 1981. Figures for'1984-85 are based on 1982 Trustees Report (intermediate assumptions -- Alternative II-B). Note: Cumulative self-employed taxes at maximum earnings are $19,847.10 for 1951-81 Appendix K, paqe 60 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 OPERATIONS OF THE OASI AND DI TRUST FUNDS, COMBINED, DURING SELECTED CALENDAR YEARS 1960-81 AND ESTIMATED FUTURE OPERATIONS DURING CALENDAR YEARS 1982-86 UNDER THE INTERMEDIATE SETS OF ASSUMPTIONS [In millions] Payments to non- Noncon- insured tributory persons Contribu- credits for aged 72 Interest on Lions, less military and invest- Calendar year Total refunds service over manta Reimbursements from the general fund of Treasury for costs of- Pant 1 ......................... $12,445 $11,876 - - $569 1965 ......................... 17,857 17,205 - - 651 1970 ......................... 36,993 34,737 $94 $371 1,791 1975 ......................... 67,640 64,259 247 268 2,866 1976 ......................... 75,034 71,595 481 236 2,722 1977 ......................... 81,982 78,710 513 228 2.531 1978 ......................... 91,904 88,883 526 230 2,264 1979 ......................... 105,864 103,034 511 164 2,155 1980 ......................... 119,712 116,711 521 150 2,330 1981 ......................... 142,438 139,364 703 140 2,231 Estimated future experience: Alternative II-A: 1982 ................. -152976 976 149528 716 139 1,814 1983 ................. 165, 754 183, 924 727 125 978 1984 ................. 178,896 178,195 735 109 -143 1985 ................. 205,535 205,329 743 92 -629 1986 ................. 225,099 224,744 521 78 -243 Alternative II-B: 1982 ................. 1154,093 146,300 1983 ................. 163,129 161,969 1984 ................. 178,640 178,861 1985 ................. 204,476 205,702 1986 ................. 222,467 224.449 716 139 1,625 727 126 308 736 108 -1,065 747 92 -2.065 608 78 -2,888 'Adjusted to exclude benefits for December 1981 that were paid on December 31, 1981 rather than January 3, 1982 which was a Sunday. These benefits are included in the 1982 figure so that amounts for 1981 and 1982 each reflect 12 months of benefit payments and are comparable to figures for other calendar years. 'Less than $500,000. 'Includes $779 million assumed to be borrowed from the HI Trust Fund under the interfund borrowing provisions. Payments for vocational Transfers rehabili- Admirrstra- to Railroad Net Funds at Benefit tation five Retirement increase and of Total payments services expenses Account in funds period $11,798 $11,245 - $240 $314 $647 $22,613 19,187 18,311 - 418 459 -1,331 19,841 33,108 31,863 $20 635 589 3,886 38,068 69,184 66,923 99 1,152 1,010 -1,544 44,342 78,242 75.665 95 1,244 1,239 -3.209 41,133 87,254 84,576 92 1,379 1,208 -5,272 35,861 96,018 92,865 95 1.439 1,618 -4,115 31,746 107,320 104,263 96 1,483 1,477 -1,456 30,291 123,550 120,512 86 1,522 1,430 -3,838 26,453 144,352 '140.996 (1) 1,742 1,614 -1,914 24,539 160,287 156,135 167 1,984 2,001 -7,311 17,228 174,633 170,175 12 2,232 2,214 -8,879 8,349 188,942 184,268 14 2.276 2,384 -10,046 -1,697 203,146 198,273 12 2,383 2,479 2,389 691 217,743 212,735 10 2,542 2,456 7,357 8,048 180,279 156,127 167 1,984 2,001 -6,186 18,353 175,465 170,983 12 2,232 2,238 -12,336 6.017 193,282 188,537 14 2,317 2.414 -14,642 -8,624 212,518 207,478 12 2,486 2,542 -8,042 -16,667 231.387 226,125 10 2,623 2,630 -8,920 -25,587 'Includes $5,313 million assumed to be borrowed from the HI Trust Fund under the interfund borrowing provisions. DOTE: Projections do mt reflect the effects of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L.97-248) --see Table 5 for summarized cost estimates including such effects. SOURCE: Table 24 in 1982 OASDI Trustees Report Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 W z? SH W2- cr W h wz z Q N 0 zz z 0 a 0 &-&PHUMHHV 900,24 MU Nnm-NN~eN9lo eo e7NNNN b RAY VeV Nl~n pm n- n :MM aeon eV ~NYN~~ eD f00Of7 vaNNN 11OPM uw Yc1 *; $~~3e NS w3 ~~--.-- -NNNN -NNNN I NalDaaama NNNN_ eVNNN NNMO fDlolp0 ?ODS HcRi s- Neo00~Yf aD eqm ~iO~m~ nfD NlnDO n2OID P M~g ;08%9 ;Spa Mu wu -NNNN--N - CI - e7uiW 11111151H.UF$ anQ~oo NPD a Na foNOan 'an IIxI11. MRA x'Mi R'SM n ~napp e7 n~((IpDpD m~nc~yN-a~(~pDqn WNn n eY~m (Y~ /D1~ONompIpePe~oIlriaa:eof~ey WpIp~OappOpNN NN.-.-O NIO--I~ID fD aaDr- QN Neo ID^O ~N~~N fap RU n O N tO N pyyp~~Q t7 N pn i .nQ- fD Vg QONH r ONRI-fONW Na. N le;.an C')( aon~nn8b'N M."62 eoearo9 '-- Appendix K, page 62 oil 3 3 I1a a o 3 sI I 3 s s 3P3 3~3? O^-yY r - D 5, 111 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 0 n ? ? W ? i m 0 M i.'0 d1 ? 0 I. Y M W ? M ~.. N ."."N.. -C .4-S d ddd 0 000 000 0 V. Y .".~.~.".4 N NNN NNN ,4 00 ^ e ? V) Y 06 P. 4) 0 Y ? W w M 0 Nw1n O.NM.D00N nd O .... .+.-4 N NMd H 0 0 .O .4 N n Cl Cl .I ." .4 ... 0 Cl 00ODd P. o. M?? NO N.".0000 N n N 0 M O. M ^ 0 0 N Cl c lc 00 Cl M d d .0 00 .0 4- .0 .0 0 i 0 Y N ./ N W M 4 M 0. M ? d N 0 0 000 1. 40 Q a a I. ""1 40 O14 1 ' . M O M C ? %4 00 14 0 ? 00 ? O /+ '.~ Y O 1.yi u0 On O 0 Y 'O N vs 4.4 Y W Y Y w 0 .0 Y O 01 Y S. 0 41 0 0 Y Y v u? r' Y M Y 1. Y 0 '."1 '0 Y W Y 0 ~ 0 0 ~ ii 14 0^ W 14 M1 r W N l?1 dd O' Y.4 Y Y 14 YY ? .1) a" M w1 . ? 00 410 P. a 0) O bC :u Y. 0LY S"" O nUI1 0 U) W u y V '0 Y 0% m0 e o 44 0 14 A ? r ~. ~' X. n S; .. a [7S N Ob 00n 0b 03n ? " y.~ a 4j 11 0) D., ~4 '0 0 0 0~ Y Y i 0 N FA cq Y n a nw '.?1w M ,1 4 r .i ? rl i N ? w a Id MM ? '9 V 404 M -e C4 go WN eq MMM /d?1MM O. '.4.14 ti 0~C0 "Oa O N.2.1 U) N Go 40 0 . Y b 0 'O '.?. O~ 0 ?.~i O N lO .1 M w u O / y~ ~ ? ?? m N M 0 Y 0. H r-'1 d?f w1 00 NM10 M '4 yq '4 ? 0^~ 0 ? 2 -2 ~^1'' u d O. N n d 10 r. d u Y? Y N N va O~ O Y! H .On0D M 0. 0.1 N Md w1 'O n 000. 0 .1 Y NMd w NMd H r y0 u M 4 0 0? .D .O '0 .O n n n n n r n r' n 00 00 "-1 Y 00 CO 00 Y 00 00 co 01 O. 0. O. 0. 0. 0. O. 0. 0. 0. 0. O. 0. O. 0. 0 N O. 0. 0. u 0. 0. 0. .+ ." ." .w ." ." .r ." ." .+ ." .~ .~ .~ .1 .1 -. .~ .~ .1 .1 .a .~ .ti ?i -41 NI NI ~1 +I Appendix K, page 64 .Odd d .0.O Cl 0. N 0 M 0 d- 10 ."d .1.0.0.0.00. M Md .40..4 n .1 .-..-. N .?. N N 01 00 N .O M .1 ." .. d d N P, ?Q d 0D 00 0. ? 31 w1 .-IP40pNMd?00N.. N.O..00 w% vy 00 .".-1d 00 o.na ao wln." MnaDO. Cf .i . .iaaa wi 0~0I N 4 . n "N N 14 N'1 g: Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 4 HISTORICAL LEVELS OF TRUST-FUND RATIOS FOR OASI, DI, AND HI TRUST FUNDS ASSETS AT THE BEGINNING OF THE YEAR AS A PERCENTAGE OF EXPENDITURES DURING THE YEAR, FOR THE OASDI PROGRAM, BY TRUST FUND, FOR SELECTED CALENDAR YEARS 1950-81 OASI and DI Trust Funds, combined OASI Trust Fund DI Trust Fund 1950 ........................................................ 1,156 1,156 1955 ........................................................... 405 405 1960 ........................................................... 186 180 304 1965 ........................................................... 110 109 121 1970 .................................................... . 103 101 126 1975 ..... . ........................................................... 66 63 92 1976 ........................................................... 57 54 71 1977 ........................................................... 47 47 48 1978 ........................................................... 37 39 26 1979 ........................................................... 30 30 30 1980 ........................................................... 25 23 35 1981 ........................................................... 18 18 21 RATIO OF ASSETS IN THE FUND AT THE BEGINNING OF THE YEAR TO DISBURSEMENTS DURING THE YEAR FOR THE HOSPITAL INSURANCE TRUST FUND (In percent) Calendar Year Ratio 1967 28% 1968 25 1969 43 1970 47 1971 54 1972 47 1973 40 1974 69 1975 79 1976 77 1977 66 1978 57 1979 54 1980 52 1981 45 SOURCE: Table 16 in 1982 OASDI Trustees Report and Table 7 in 1982 HI Trustees Report Appendix K, page 65 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Estimated operations of the OASI, DI, and HI Trust Funds index the program as modified by the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982, an the basis of the 1982 Trustees Report alternative II-B assumptions, calendar years 1981-91 year QASI DI O MI HI Total QASI DI Q4SDI HI Total 1981 $125.4 $17.1 $142.4 $35.7 $178.2 $126.7 $17.7 $144.4 $30.7 $175.1 1982 137.7 16.6 154.3 32.6 187.0 141.9 18.1 160.0 35.6 195.6 1983 136.5 26.1 162.6 44.0 206.6 156.5 19.0 175.5 40.8 216.3 1984 149.2 29.6 178.8 48.4 227.2 173.0 19.9 192.9 46.3 239.2 1985 167.3 37.5 204.8 54.5 259.3 190.9 21.3 212.2 51.9 264.1 1986 180.9 42.0 222.9 63.2 286.1 208.5 22.7 231.2 58.8 290.0 1987 194.5 46.5 241.0 68.5 309.5 226.3 24.2 250.6 66.9 317.5 1988 209.1 51.3 260.4 73.8 334.2 244.5 25.8 270.3 76.0 346.4 1989 223.9 56.5 280.4 78.9 359.3 263.2 27.6 290.8 86.1 376.9 1990 257.0 69.6 326.7 83.8 410.5 282.2 29.4 311.6 %.8 408.4 1991 275.7 76.7 352.4 88.5 440.9 300.8 31.4 332.1 108.7 440.8 Net increase Finds at end Assets at beginning of year as a in funds of year percentage of outgo during year QASI DI QASDI HI Total OAST DI (14S)I HI Total Q4SI DI QASDI HI Total 1981 -$1.3 -$).6 -$1.9 $5.0 $3.1 $21.5 $3.0 $24.5 $18.7 $43.3 18% 21% 18% 45% 23% 1982 -4.2 -1.5 -5.7 -3.0 -8.6 17.3 1.6 18.9 15.8 34.6 15 17 15 53 22 1983 -20.0 7.1 -12.8 3.2 -9.6 -2.6 8.7 6.1 19.0 25.0 11 8 11 39 16 1984 -23.8 9.7 -14.1 2.1 -12.0 -26.4 18.4 -8.0 21.0 13.0 -2 44 3 41 10 1985 -23.6 16.2 -7.4 2.6 -4.8 -50.0 34.6 -15.4 23.6 8.2 -14 86 -4 41 5 1986 -27.6 19.2 -8.4 4.4 -3.9 -77.6 53.8 -23.8 28.0 4.3 -24 152 -7 40 3 1987 -31.8 22.2 -9.6 1.6 -7.9 -109.4 76.1 -33.4 29.7 -3.7 -34 222 -9 42 1 1988 -35.4 25.5 -9.9 -2.3 -12.2 -144.9 101.6 -43.3 27.4 -15.9 -45 294 -12 39 -1 1989 -39.3 28.9 -10.4 -7.2 -17.7 -184.2 130.4 -53.7 20.2 -33.6 -55 368 -15 32 -4 1990 -25.1 40.2 15.1 -13.0 2.1 -209.3 170.6 -38.7 7.2 -31.5 -65 443 -17 21 -8 1991 -25.1 45.4 20.3 -20.2 .1 -234.4 216.0 -18.4 -13.0 -31.4 -70 544 -12 7 -7 Notes: 1. The income figures for 1982, and the end-of-year asset figures for 1982 ad later, reflect the transfer of funds from the DI and HI Trust Funds to the OASI Trust Fund under the interfuzd borrowing authority provided by Public Law 97-123. ihder this set of assumptions, a total of $11.6 billion would be transferred to QGSI in 1982, $6.2 billion from DI and $5.5 billion from HI. 2. The estimated operations for OASI, Q4SDI, and OASDI and HI combined in 1983 and later are theoretical since, following the expiration of the present law interfund borrowing authority, the OASI Trust F1nd would became depleted in July 1983 when assets would became insufficient to pay benefits when due. Similarly, the HI Trust Fund operations in 1991 are theoretical, since the fund would be depleted in 1991 under this set of assumptions. Appendix K, page 66 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Estimated operations of the QASI, DI, and HI Trust Funds under the program as modified by the Tat Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982, an the basis of the 1982 Trustees Report alternative III assumptions, calendar years 1981-91 1982 138.4 16.6 155.1 31.8 186.9 141.9 18.1 160.0 35.6 195.6 1983 133.3 25.6 158.9 43.0 201.9 157.7 19.1 176.8 40.8 217.6 1984 142.9 28.7 171.6 47.0 218.6 177.2 20.3 197.5 46.7 244.2 1985 .162.3 37.1 199.4 53.7 253.2 199.8 22.2 222.0 54.2 276.3 1986 177.3 42.4 219.7 63.1 282.8 224.0 24.3 248.3 63.7 312.0 1987 192.6 48.0 240.6 69.3 309.9 250.2 26.5 276.6 75.2 351.9 1988 208.8 54.0 262.8 75.3 338.2 277.7 28.9 306.6 88.7 395.3 1989 225.6 60.6 286.2 81.1 367.3 306.8 31.6 338.4 104.2 442.6 1990 262.5 76.1 338.5 86.5 425.0 337.5 34.4 372.0 121.7 493.6 1991 285.0 85.6 370.5 91.5 462.0 369.4 37.6 406.9 142.0 548.9 Net increase Funds at end Assets at beginning of year as a in funds of year percentage of outgo during year OASI DI OASDI HI Total QQSI DI QASDI HI Total QASI DI QkSDI HI Total 1982 -3.5 -1.5 -5.0 -3.8 -8.7 18.0 1.6 19.6 15.0 34.5 15 17 15 53 22 1983 -24.4 6.5 -17.9 2.2 -15.6 -6.4 8.1 1.7 17.2 18.9 11 8 11 37 16 1984 -34.3 8.4 -25.9 .2 -25.7 -40.7 16.4 -24.3 17.5 -6.8 -4 40 1 37 8 1985 -37.5 14.9 -22.6 -.5 -23.1 -78.2 31.4 -,46.8 17.0 -29.9 -20 74 -11 32 -2 1986 -46.7 18.2 -28.5 -.6 -29.1 -124.9 49.5 -75.4 16.4 -59.0 -35 129 -19 27 -10 1987 -57.6 21.5 -36.1 -5.9 -42.0 -182.5 71.0 -111.4 10.5 -101.0 -50 187 -27 22 -17 1988 -68.9 25.1 -43.8 -13.3 -57.1 -251.3 %.1 -155.2 -2.9 -158.1 -66 246 -36 12 -26 1989 -81.2 29.0 -52.2 -23.1 -75.3 -332.6 125.1 -207.4 -26.0 -233.4 -82 305 -46 -3 -36 1990 -75.1 41.6 -33.5 -35.2 -668.6 -407.6 166.8 -240.9 -61.1 -302.0 -99 363 -56 -21 -47 1991 -84.4 48.0 -36.4 -50.5 -87.0 -492.0 214.8 -277.3 -111.7 -389.0 -110 444 -59 -43 -55 Notes: 1. The income figures for 1982, and the end-of-year asset figures for 1982 and later, reflect the transfer of funds from the DI and HI Trust Funds to the OASI Trust Fund under the interfund borrowing authority provided by Public lap 97-123. Under this set of assumptions, a total of $12.4 billion would be transferred to OASI in 1982, $6.1 billion from DI and $6.3 billion from HI. 2. The estimated operations for QA.SI, QASDI, and QASDI and HI combined in 1983 and later are theoretical since, following the expiration of the present law interfurd borrowing authority, the OASI Trust Find would become depleted in July 1983 when assets would become insufficient to pay benefits when due. Similarly, the HI Trust Fund operations in 1988 and later are theoretical, since the fund would be depleted in 1988 under this set of assumptions. Appendix K, page 67 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 -Estimated operations of the OASI and DI Trust Funds under the program as modified by the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982, on the basis of the 1982 Trustees Report alternative I assumptions, calendar years 1981-91 Income year OASI DI OASDI 1981 $125.4 $17.1 $142.4 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 136.2 16.6 152.9 140.1 26.6 166.7 154.5 30.2 184.8 175.4 38.4 213.8 191.2 43.0 234.2 207.6 47.6 255.2 224.4 52.4 276.8 241.4 57.3 298.7 274.9 69.7 344.6 296.7 76.5 373.2 Net increase Funds at end in funds of year OASI DI OASDI OASI DI OASI DI OASDI $126.7 $17.7 $144.4 141.8 18.1 160.0 155.2 18.8 174.1 168.3 19.4 187.6 181.1 20.3 201.4 193.5 21.3 214.7 206.0 22.3 228.4 218.2 23.5 241.7 227.1 24.4 251.5 238.8 25.7 264.6 250.9 27.3 278.2 Assets at beginning of year as a percentage of outgo during year OASDI OAS I DI OASDI 1981 -$1.3 -$0.6 -$1.9 $21.5 $3.0 $24.5 18% 1982 -5.6 -1.5 -7.1 15.1 1983 -15.1 7.8 -7.3 .8 1984 -13.7 10.9 -2.9 -13.0 1985 -5.7 18.2 12.5 -18.6 1986 -2.2 21.7 19.5 -20.9 1987 1.6 25.3 26.9 -19.3 1988 6.2 28.9 35.0 -13.1 1989 14.3 32.9 47.2 1.2 1990 36.1 44.0 80.0 37.3 1991 45.8 49.2 95.0 83.1 1.6 17.5 15 17 15 9.4 10.1 10 8 10 20.2 7.3 (1/) 48 5 38.4 19.8 -7 100 4 60.1 39.2 -10 180 9 85.4 66.1 -10 269 17 114.2 101.1 -9 363 27 147.1 148.3 -6 468 40 191.1 228.4 1 572 56 240.3 323.4 15 701 82 1/ Between 0.0 percent and 0.5 percent. Notes: 1. The income figures for 1982, and the end-of-year asset figures for 1982 and later, reflect the transfer of funds from the DI and HI Trust Funds to the OASI Trust Fund under the interfund borrowing authority provided by Public Law 97-123. Under this set of assumptions, a total of $9.6 billion would be transferred to OASI in 1982, $6.2 billion from DI and $3.4 billion from HI. 2. The estimated operations for OASI and OASI and DI combined in 1983 and later are theoretical since, following the expiration of the present law interfund borrowing authority, the OASI Trust Fund would become depleted in July 1983 when assets would become insufficient to pay benefits when due. Note: Health ('are Financing A%?ministxation ,.na'-le to supply L?I cost estinatPs. Appendix K, page 68 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 5D --Estimated operations of the OASI and DI Trust Funds under the program as modified by the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982, on the basis of the 1982 Trustees Report alternative II-A assumptions, calendar years 1981-91 year OASI DI OASDI OASI DI OASDI 1981 $125.4 $17.1 $142.4 $126.7 $17.7 $144.4 1982 136.6 16.7 153.2 141.9 18.1 160.0 1983 138.3 26.5 164.9 155.7 18.9 174.6 1984 148.9 29.8 178.7 169.1 19.5 188.6 1985 167.4 38.0 205.4 182.4 20.4 202.9 1986 182.0 43.0 225.0 196.1 21.5 217.6 1987 198.0 48.0 246.1 210.6 22.8 233.3 1988 215.2 53.2 268.3 225.6 24.2 249.8 1989 232.4 58.5 290.9 241.2 25.8 267.0 1990 268.3 71.9 340.2 256.8 27.5 284.3 1991 289.0 78.9 367.9 271.9 29.3 301.2 Net increase Funds at end Assets at beginning of year as a percentage in funds of year of outgo during year OASI DI OASDI OASI DI OASDI OASI DI OASDI 19b2 -5.3 -1.5 -6.8 16.2 1.6 17.8 15 17 15 1983 -17.4 7.7 -9.8 -1.2 9.2 8.0 10 8 10 1984 -20.3 10.3 -10.0 -21.5 19.5 -2.0 -1 47 4 1985 -15.1 17.6 2.5 -36.5 37.1 .6 -12 96 -1 1986 -14.1 21.5 7.4 -50.6 58.6 8.0 -19 172 (1/) 1987 -12.5 25.3 12.7 -63.2 83.9 20.7 -24 258 3 1988 -10.5 29.0 18.5 -73.6 112.8 39.2 -28 347 8 1989 -8.8 32.7 23.9 -82.4 145.5 63.1 -31 438 15 1990 11.6 44.4 56.0 -70.9 189.9 119.1 -32 529 22 1991 17.1 49.6 66.6 -53.8 239.5 185.7 -26 647 40 l/ Between 0.0 percent and 0.5 percent. Notes: 1. The income figures for 1982, and the end-of-year asset figures for 1982 and later, reflect the transfer of funds from the DI and HI Trust Funds to the OASI Trust Fund under the interfund borrowing authority provided by Public Law 97-123. Under this set of assumptions, a total of $10.0 billion would be transferred to OASI in 1982, $6.2 billion from DI and $3.7 billion from HI. 2. The estimated operations for OASI and OASI and DI combined in 1983 and later are theoretical since, following the expiration of the present law interfund borrowing authority, the OASI Trust Fund would become depleted in July 1983 when assets would become insufficient to pay benefits when due. Note: Health Care Financing Administration was unable to supply HI cost estimates. Appendix K, page 69 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 LONG-RANGE STATUS OF OASDI-HI TRUST FUNDS COMPARISON OF ESTIMATED AVERAGE COST RATE WITH AVERAGE TAX RATE BY ALTERNATIVE AND TRUST FUND IAs percent of taxable wry Esam1W awra9s Cost rote by $lt.rnstne Utterance by allemsew OASI: 1992.2006..-. 9.93 8.64 9.31 10.14 11.37 1.29 0.63 -021 -1.44 2007-31.-._.. 1020 9.64 11.55 12.43 15.63 .36 -1.36 -223 -5.63 2032.56......... 10.20 10.56 14.11 1520 23.60 -.36 -3.91 ?5.00 -13.40 Dl: 1962.2056..... 10.11 9.69 11.66 12.59 16.93 .42 -1.55 ?2.46 -6.92 1962.2006._. 2.07 1.11 1.16 123 1.36 .97 .92 .65 .72 2607.31.... .. 220 1.45 1.57 1.65 2.00 .76 .63 .5S 20 2032.56....._. 9 2.20 1.30 1.54 1.61 2.07 .90 .66 .59 .13 62.2056-_ Total: 1 2.16 129 1.42 1.50 1.61 .87 .73 .66 .35 1962.2006.._ 12.01 9.75 10.46 11.37 12.73 2.26 1.55 .64 ?.72 2007.31..._. 12.40 11.30 13.15 14.06 17.64 1.10 -.7S ?1.66 ?5.44 2032.56..... 12.40 11.66 15.65 16.61 25.66 .52 -325 -4.41 ?1326 1962-2056..-. 12.27 10.96 13.09 14.09 18.74 129 -.62 ?1.62 -047 Note: The ditionc of ahernativet 1. 11-A. II-H, and 111. Cost rate. tax rate, and usable payroll a presented a the tau Tomb do= semrrily equal the clan of rounded oompooents, ACTUARIAL BALANCE OF THE HOSPITAL INSURANCE PROGRAM, UNDER ALTERNATIVE SETS OF ASSUMPTIONS a/ (Percent of Taxable Payroll) Alternative I II-A I-B I Average contribution rate, scheduled under present law b/ 2.86% 2.86% 2.86% 2.86% Average cost of the program, for expenditures and for trust fund maintenance c/ 3.72 a/ 4.49 a/ 4.93 a/ 6.59 a/ Actuarial balance -0.86 -1.63 -2.07 -3.73 a/ Does not reflect the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248). When the effect of this legislation is taken into account, the average 25-year cost exclusive of trust-fund building and maintenance under Alternative II-B is 4.34% of taxable payroll (as contrasted with the comparable figure of 4.83% before enactment of such legislation). b/ Average for the 25-year period, 1982-2006. c/ Average for the 25-year period, 1982-2006, expressed as a percentage of taxable payroll. NOTE: Taxable payroll is adjusted to take into account the lower contribution rates on self-employment income, on tips, and on multiple-employer "excess wages" as compared with the combined employer-employee rate. SOURCE: 1982 OASDI-HI Trustees Report. Appendix K, page 70 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 7A ESTIMATED COST RATES OF THE OASDI SYSTEM UNDER ALTERNATIVES II-A AND II-B AND COMPARISON WITH TAX RATES, CALENDAR YEARS 1982-2060 [As percent of taxable payroll] Alternative 11-A: 1982 ................................................... 1983 ................................................... 1984 ................................................... 1985 ................................................... 1986 ................................................... 1987 ................................................... 1988 ................................................... 1989 ................................................... 1990 ................................................... 1991 ................................................... 1992 ................................................... 1993 ................................................... 1994 ................................................... 1995 ................................................... 1996 ................................................... 1,997 ................................................... 1998 ................................................... 1999 ................................................... 2000 ................................................... 2001 ................................................... 2002 ................................................... 2003 ................................................... 2004 ................................................... 2005 ................................................... 2006 ................................................... 2010 ................................................... 2015 ................................................... 2020 ................................................... 2025 ................................................... 2030 ................................................... 2035 ................................................... 2040 ................................................... 2045 ................................................... 2050 ................................................... 2055 ................................................... 2060 ................................................... 25-year averages: 10.18 10.21 10.22 10.07 9.91 9.75 9.63 9.53 9.45 9.38 9.35 9.33 9.29 9.25 9.15 9.07 9.00 8.92 8.82 8.73 8.68 8.66 8.65 8.68 8.72 9.17 10.35 11.88 13.36 14.22 14.39 14.12 13.93 13.98 14.10 14.12 1.33 1.25 1.19 1.13 1.09 1.06 1.03 1.02 1.01 1.01 1.03 1.04 1.05 1.07 1.10 1.13 1.16 1.18 1.20 1.23 1.25 1.28 1.32 1.37 1.39 1.52 1.61 1.65 1.61 1.53 1.50 1.52 1.56 1.55 1.53 1.52 11.51 11.46 11.41 11.20 11.00 10.81 10.66 10.55 10.47 10.39 10.37 10.37 10.35 10.32 10.25 10.20 10.15 10.10 10.03 9.96 9.93 9.94 9.97 10.06 10.11 10.69 11.96 13.53 14.96 15.75 15.89 15.64 15.48 15.53 15.63 15.63 10.80 10.80 10.80 11.40 11.40 11.40 11.40 11.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 12.40 -0.71 -.66 -.61 .20 .40 .59 .74 .85 1.93 2.01 2.03 2.03 2.05 2.08 2.15 2.20 2.25 2.30 2.37 2.44 2.47 2.46 2.43 2.34 2.29 1.71 .44 -1.13 -2.56 -3.35 -3.49 -3.24 -3.08 -3.13 -3.23 -3.23 1982-2006 .................................. 9.31 2007-2031 .................................. 11.58 2032-2056 .................................. 14.11 1.16 1.57 1.54 10.46 13.15 15.65 12.01 12.40 12.40 1.55 -.75 -3.25 75-year average: 1982-2056 .................................. 11.66 1.42 13.09 12.27 -.82 Alternative II-B: 1982 ................................................... 10.42 1.36 11.78 10.80 -0.98 1983 ................................................... 10.38 1.27 11.65 10.80 -.85 1984 ................................................... 10.42 1.21 11.63 10.80 -.83 1985 ................................................... 10.52 1.18 11.70 11.40 -.30 1986 ................................................... 10.55 1.16 11.71 11.40 -.31 1987 ................................................... 10.57 1.14 11.71 11.40 -.31 1988 ................................................... 10.56 1.12 11.68 11.40 -.28 1989 ................................................... 10.55 1.11 11.66 11.40 -.26 1990 ................................................... 10.54 1.10 11.64 12.40 .76 1991 ................................................... 10.49 1.10 11.59 12.40 .81 1992 ................................................... 10.43 1.11 11.54 12.40 .86 1993 ................................................... 10.39 1.12 11.51 12.40 .89 1994 ................................................... 10.33 1.13 11.46 12.40 .94 1995 ................................................... 10.27 1.14 11.42 12.40 .98 1996 ................................................... 10.18 1.17 11.35 12.40 1.05 1997 ................................................... 10.07 1.20 11.27 12.40 1.13 1998 ................................................... 9.96 1.23 11.19 12.40 1.21 1999 ................................................... 9.85 1.25 11.10 12.40 1.30 2000 ................................................... 9.75 1.28 11.03 12.40 1.37 2001 ................................................... 9.66 1.30 10.96 12.40 1.44 2002 ................................................... 9.58 1.32 10.90 12.40 1.50 2003 ................................................... 9.52 1.35 10.87 12.40 1.53 2004 ................................................... 9.48 1.39 10.87 12.40 1.53 2005 ................................................... 9.50 1.44 10.95 12.40 1.45 2006 ................................................... 9.53 1.46 10.99 12.40 1.41 2010 ................................................... 9.94 1.59 11.53 12.40 .87 2015 ................................................... 11.12 1.69 12.82 12.40 -.42 2020 ................................................... 12.72 1.73 14.44 12.40 -2.04 2025 ................................................... 14.29 1.68 15.97 12.40 -3.57 2030 ................................................... 15.23 1.60 16.83 12.40 -4.43 2035 ................................................... 15.45 1.57 17.02 12.40 -4.62 2040 ................................................... 15.20 1.59 16.80 12.40 -4.40 2045 ................................................... 15.03 1.63 16.66 12.40 -4.26 2050 ................................................... 15.09 1.63 16.72 12.40 -4.32 2055 ................................................... 15.21 1.60 16.81 12.40 -4.41 2060 ................................................... 15.22 1.59 18.81 12.40 -4.41 25-yearaverages: 1982-2006 .................................. 2007-2031 .................................. 10.14 12.43 1.23 1.65 11.37 14.08 12.01 12.40 .64 -1.68 2032-2056 .................................. 15.20 1.61 16.81 12.40 -4.41 75-year average: 1982-2056 .................................. 12.59 1.50 14.09 12.27 -1.82 'The tax rate minus the OASDI cost rate. Positive differences are referred to as surpluses, and negative differences, as deficits. NOTE: These estimates do not take into account the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248). If this had been done, the cost rates would have been slightly lower. SOURCE: Table 27 of 1982 OASDI Trustees Report Appendix K, page 71 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Calendar Year 1982 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 Averages 1982-2006 2007-31 2032-56 1982-2056 ESTIMATED COST RATES OF HI AND OASDI-HI PROGRAMS UNDER ALTERNATIVE II-B AND COMPARISON WITH TAX RATES, 1986-2055 (as percent of taxable payroll) HI Program OASDI-HI Program Cost Rate!/ Tax Rate./ Differences/ Cost Rate Tax Rateb/ Differences/ 2.97% 2.60% -.37% 14.75% 13.40% -1.35% 2.74 2.70 -.04 14.44 14.10 -.34 3.51 2.90 -.61 15.15 15.30 +.15 4.47 2.90 -1.57 15.89 15.30 -.59 5.38 2.90 -2.48 16.41 15.30 -1.11 6.29 2.90 -3.39 17.24 15.30 -1.94 7.20 2.90 -4.30 18.73 15.30 -3.43 7.94 2.90 -5.04 20.76 15.30 -5.46 8.89 2.90 -5.99 23.33 15.30 -8.03 9.93 2.90 -7.03 25.90 15.30 -10.60 10.76 2.90 -7.86 27.59 15.30 -12.29 11.17 2.90 -8.27 28.19 15.30 -12.89 11.29 2.90 -8.39 28.09 15.30 -12.79 11.21 2.90 -8.31 27.87 15.30 -12.57 11.19 2.90 -8.29 27.91 15.30 -12.61 11.17 2.90 -8.27 27.98 15.30 -12.68 4.34 2.86 -1.48 15.71 14.87 -.84 8.78 2.90 -5.88 22.86 15.30 -7.56 11.19 2.90 -8.29 28.00 15.30 -12.70 8.10 2.89 -5.21 22.19 15.16 -7.03 a/ These cost rates do not include any allowance for building up and maintaining the trust-fund ratio at 50% (which would require an additional .10% of taxable b/ payroll in 1982-2006).. For employer and employee combined. Tax rate minus cost rate. Positive differences are referred to as cash-flow surpluses, and negative differences as deficits. NOTE: These estimates for OASDI do not take into account the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248), but those for HI do take this legislation into account. If this had been done, the cost rates for OASDI-HI would have been slightly lower. SOURCE: Table 27 of the 1982 OASDI Trustees Report and Table 8 of the 1982 HI Trustees Report (extended beyond 2005 by Health Care Financing Administration under assumption that, then, hospital costs rise at the same rate as wages), in all cases reduced to allow for the effect of P.L. 97-248 (a reduction of about 102% in all years after 1982). Appendix K, page 72 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 7C ESTIMATED COST RATES OF OASDI PROGRAM UNDER ALTERNATIVES II-B AND III AND COMPARISON WITH TAX RATES, 1982-2055 (as percent of taxable payroll) OASDI Alternative II-B Alternative III Calendar Tax Cost Cost Year Ratea/ Rate Differenceb/ Rate Difference/ 1982 10.80% 11.78% -.98% 11.83% -1.03% 1985 11.40 11.70 -.30 12.40 -1.00 1990 12.40 11.64 +.76 12.85 -.45 1995 12.40 11.42 +.98 12.97 -.57 2000 12.40 11.03 +1.37 12.82 -.42 2005 12.40 10.95 +1.45 12.97 -.57 2010 12.40 11.53 +.87 13.92 -1.52 2015 12.40 12.82 -.42 15.76 -3.36 2020 12.40 14.44 -2.04 18.17 -5.77 2025 12.40 15.97 -3.57 20.70 -8.30 2030 12.40 16.83 -4.43 22.63 -10.23 2035 12.40 17.02 -4.62 23.94 -11.54 2040 12.40 16.80 -4.40 24.80 -12.40 2045 12.40 16.66 -4.26 25.80 -13.40 2050 12.40 16.72 -4.32 26.93 -14.53 2055 12.40 16.81 -4.41 27.87 -15.47 Averages 1982-2006 12.01 11.37 +.64 12.73 -.72 2007-31 12.40 14.08 -1.68 17.84 -5.44 2032-56 12.40 16.81 -4.41 25.66 -13.26 1982-2056 12.27 14.09 -1.82 18.74 -6.47 a/ For employer and employee combined. b/ Tax rate minus cost rate. Positive differences are referred to as cash-flow surpluses, and negative differences as deficits. NOTE: These estimates do not take into account the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248). If this had been done, the cost rates would have been slightly lower. SOURCE: Tables 27 and 29 of the 1982 OASDI Trustees Report. Appendix K, page 73 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 ESTIMATED TRUST FUND RATIOS BY ALTERNATIVE AND TRUST FUND, CALEN- DAR YEARS 1982-2060 1982 .................... 15 16 15 15 16 15 15 1983 .................... 10 8 10 10 8 10 11 1984 .................... 1 48 6 (') 47 4 V) 1985 .................... -7 98 4 -11 93 ( ) V) 1986 .................... -10 178 9 -18 169 (') () 1987 .................... -10 265 17 -24 253 3 (') 1988 ................... -9 359 27 -28 342 8 () 1989 .................... -6 464 40 -30 432 15 (2) 1990 .................... (') 567 56 -32 524 22 (') 1991 .................... 15 696 82 -26 642 39 (9 1992 .................... 31 811 110 -18 753 58 1993 .................... 47 934 138 -10 859 77 (1) 1994 .................... 1995 65 1,041 167 (') 961 97 (') .................... 1996 .................... 84 104 1,137 1,208 197 228 8 18 1,054 1,122 116 136 (;) 1997 .................... 127 1,278 260 29 1,187 157 1998 .................... 150 1,345 293 41 1,247 178 (') 1999 .................... 175 1,411 326 52 1,317 200 (') 2000 ................... 202 1,468 362 67 1,369 223 2001 .................... 232 1,532 400 82 1,421 247 (1) 2002 .................... 262 1,589 438 99 1,467 271 () 2003 .................... 293 1,630 474 116 1,502 295 () 2004 .................... 324 1,656 510 133 1,526 317 () 2005 .................... 354 1,656 542 149 1,531 338 () 2006 .................... 384 1,702 576 165 1,568 358 () 2010 ................... 485 1,797 684 216 1,645 419 () 2015 .................... 539 1,967 745 224 1,779 434 () 2020 .................... 520 2,198 739 168 1,962 387 () 2025 .................... 457 2,549 698 67 2,240 300 () 2030 .................... 386 3,000 662 (1) 2,595 196 () 2035 .................... 332 3,410 651 () 2,902 89 (1) 2040 .................... 304 3,735 675 () 3,123 () () 2045 .................... 298 4,031 719 () 3,295 (1) () 2050 .................... 301 4,443 766 () 3,558 (1) (') 2055 .................... 305 4,942 811 (1) 3,873 (1) () 2060 .................... 311 5,435 860 () 4,168 () () Trust fund is projected to be first ex- hausted in:...... 1983 (1) 1983 1983 (4) 1983 1983 'Between -0.5 percent and zero. 'The fund is projected to be exhausted and not to recover before the end of the projection period. 'Between zero and 0.5 percent. 'The fund is not projected to be exhausted within the projection period. Note: The definitions of alternatives I, II-A, II-B, and III, and trust fund ratio are presented in the text. The ratios shown after the year a given fund is projected to be exhausted are theoretical and are shown for informational purposes only; see the section on "Estimated Operations and Status of the Trust Funds during the Period October 1, 1981 to December 31, 1986" for further discussion. In addition, the ratios for the total of the OASI and DI Trust Funds after 1982 are theoretical, also because under the current law, after 1982, the assets of one fund cannot be borrowed by another fund. The money assumed to be borrowed by the OASI Trust Fund in December 1982 is assumed to be repaid in 1992 under alternative 1, in 1998 under alternative II-A, and not at any time in the long-range projection period under alternatives 11-B and 111. NOTE: These estimates do not take into account the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248). If this had been done, the fund ratios would have been slightly higher. SOURCE: Table 32 in 1982 OASDI Trustees Report Appendix K, page 74 16 15 15 16 15 8 10 11 8 11 43 3 84 (') 39 1 71 M 148 -7 (1) 125 () 217 -10 ' 181 (') 288 -13 361 -16 (') 2239 97 (1) 436 -19 536 -13 (') 4356 36 (') -7 631 723 (') () 577 (1) 812 7 () 643 () 895 15 () 705 (') 959 23 () 755 (1) 1,019 32 799 (1) 1,076 42 1,130 53 (') 871 () 1.178 64 1,227 76 (1) 927 900 (1) 1,270 89 () 951 () 1,303 102 () 967 () 1,327 115 (') 977 () 1,332 128 (9 976 1,366 140 () 991 (1) 1,435 177 () 1,005 (1) 1,549 177 () 1,033 () 1,703 125 () 1,076 (1) 1,938 31 () 1,162 2.241 (?) () 1,287 (1) 2,504 (1) (') 1,390 (1) 2,693 () () 1,456 () 2,837 () () 1,515 (1) 3,061 () () 1,619 3,330 (') () 1,758 (1) 3,582 () () 1,910 () (') 1983 1983 () 1983 396-938 0 - 83 - 18 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 9A ESTIMATED COST OF THE OASDI SYSTEM AS PERCENT OF GNP BY ALTERNA- TIVE, CALENDAR YEARS 1982-2060 1982 ..................................................................... 5.07 5.08 5.16 5.19 1983 ..................................................................... 4.93 4.97 5.05 5.26 1984 ..................................................................... 4.82 4.87 5.03 5.28 1985 ..................................................................... 4.72 4.78 5.05 5.28 1986 ..................................................................... 4.63 4.69 5.04 5.31 1987 ..................................................................... 4.55 4.62 5.03 5.34 1988 ..................................................................... 4.48 4.55 5.00 5.37 1989 ..................................................................... 4.35 4.51 4.97 5.38 1990 ..................................................................... 4.31 4.47 4.94 5.38 1991 ..................................................................... 4.27 4.44 4.91 5.38 1992 ..................................................................... 4.24 4.41 4.87 5.35 1993 ..................................................................... 4.25 4.39 4.84 5.34 1994 ..................................................................... 4.21 4.36 4.80 5.32 1995 ..................................................................... 4.17 4.33 4.76 5.32 1996 ..................................................................... 4.11 4.29 4.70 5.31 1997 ..................................................................... 4.07 4.25 4.65 5.27 1998 ..................................................................... 4.04 4.21 4.59 5.22 1999 ..................................................................... 4.00 4.17 4.53 5.17 2000 ..................................................................... 3.94 4.13 4.48 5.15 2001 ..................................................................... 3.89 4.08 4.44 5.12 2002 ..................................................................... 3.86 4.06 4.40 5.08 2003 ..................................................................... 3.84 4.05 4.37 5.07 2004 ..................................................................... 3.84 4.05 4.35 5.06 2005 ..................................................................... 3.86 4.08 4.36 5.09 2006 ..................................................................... 3.86 4.09 4.37 5.11 2010 ..................................................................... 4.00 4.27 4.51 5.33 2015 ..................................................................... 4.38 4.71 4.92 5.89 2020 ..................................................................... 4.83 5.25 5.44 6.63 2025 ..................................................................... 5.18 5.73 5.90 7.37 2030 ..................................................................... 5.26 5.94 6.10 7.87 2035 ..................................................................... 5.10 5.91 6.05 8.13 2040 ..................................................................... 4.82 5.74 5.86 8.23 2045 ..................................................................... 4.58 5.60 5.70 8.36 2050 ..................................................................... 4.45 5.54 5.62 8.52 2055 ..................................................................... 4.37 5.49 5.54 8.61 2060 ..................................................................... 4.28 5.42 5.44 8.60 25-year averages: 4 75 5 25 1982.2006 .................................................. 2007-2031 .................................................. 4.25 4.67 4.40 5.11 . 5.30 . 6.50 2032-2056 .................................................. 4.70 5.67 5.78 8.34 75-year average: 1982-2056 og .................................................. 4.54 5.06 5.28 6.70 SOURCE: Table 30 in 1982 OASDI Trustees Report Appendix K, page 75 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 ESTIMATED COST OF OASDI AND HI SYSTEMS AS PERCENT OF GNP UNDER ALTERNATIVE II-B, 1982-2050 Calendar Year OASDI HI OASDI-HI 1982 5.16% 1.30% 6.46% 1985 5.05 1.18 6.23 1990 4.94 1.49 6.43 1995 4.76 1.90 6.66 2000 4.48 2.19 6.67 2005 4.36 2.50 6.86 2010 4.51 2.82 7.33 2015 4.92 3.05 7.97 2020 5.44 3.35 8.79 2025 5.90 3.67 9.57 2030 6.10 3.90 10.00 2035 6.05 3.97 10.02 2040 5.86 3.94 9.80 2045 5.70 3.84 9.54 2050 5.62 3.76 9.38 2055 5.54 3.68 9.22 Averages 1982-2006 4.75 1.81 6.56 2007-31 5.30 3.30 8.60 2032-56 5.78 3.85 9.63 1982-2056 5.28 3.04 8.32 NOTE: These estimates for OASDI do not take into account the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248). If this had been done, the figures for the OASDI-HI system would have been slightly lower. SOURCE: Derived from Tables 7A, 7B, and 9A. Appendix K, page 76 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Trust Fund ESTIMATED TOTAL INCREASE IN SOCIAL SECURITY TAX INCOME REQUIRED -DURIlQG CALENDAR YEARS 1983-87 TO REACH ALTERNATIVE TARGET LEVELS OF TRUST FUND ASSETS BY BEGINNING OF 1988, UNDER ALTERNATIVES II -B AND III OF 1982 TRUSTEES REPORT (In billions) Asset Goal at Beginning of 1988 as Percentage of Expenditures in 1988 OASI $121 $140 $192 $244 DI -- -- -- -- HI -- -- 7 23 OASDI 59 81 138 196 OASDI-HI 46 74 150 222 OASI DI HI Alternative III 204 266 324 11 29 48 OASDI 126 152 217 280 OASDI-HI 133 166 245 328 Notes: 1. The above estimates are based on the assumption that the target trust fund ratio would be approached in even steps between 1983 and 1988. Other patterns are possible and would lead to somewhat different estimates of the required tax increases. 2. The effects of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248) are reflected in these estimates. 3. Where no estimate is shown, it indicates that the asset goal is exceeded under present law. Appendix K, page 77 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 ESTIMATED TOTAL REDUCTION IN SOCIAL SECURC'TY BENEFITS REQUIRED DURING CALENDAR YEARS 1983-87 TO REACH ALTERNATIVE: TARGET LEVELS OF TRUST FUND ASSETS BY THE BEGINNING OF 1988, UNDER ALTERNATIVES II -B AND III OF THE 1982 TRUSTEES REPORT (In billions) Asset Goal at Beginning of 1988 as Percentage of Lcpenditures in 1988 1/ Trust Fund 15% 25% 50% 75% OASI $116 $134 $175 $210 DI -- -- -- -- HI -- -- 6 19 OASDI 59 79 128 172 OASDI-HI 44 72 134 190 Alternative III OAS I 193 234 271 DI HI 9 24 37 OASDI 123 144 194 239 OaASDI-HI 128 154 218 275 1/ Expenditures in 1988 are assumed to be reduced by about the same percentage as in 1983-87; the amount of the 1988 reduction is not included in the total reductions shown for 1983-87. Notes: 1. The above estimates are based on the assumption that the target trust fund ratio would be approached in even steps between 1983 and 1988. Other patterns are possible and would lead to somewhat different estimates of the required benefit reductions. 2. The effects of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248) are reflected in these estimates. 3. Where no estimate is shown, it indicates that the asset goal is exceeded under present law. Appendix K, page 78 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 ESTIMATED TOTAL INCREASE IN OASDI TAX INCOME REQUIRED DURING 1983-89 TO REACH ALTERNATIVE TARGET LEVELS OF TRUST-FUND RATIOS BY BEGINNING OF 1988, UNDER ALTERNATIVES II-B AND III (IN BILLIONS) 1988 Trust-Fund Ratio of 15% 1988 Trust-Fund Ratio of 25% Calendar Year Alternative II-B Assumptions Alternative III Assumptions Alternative II-B Assumptions Alternative 17T Assumptions - 1983 $22 $26 $24 $27 1984 15 26 20 32 1985 7 20 11 25 1986 8 25 13 30 1987 8 30 14 39 0 1988 8 34 8 35 1989 7 40 8 40 1983-89 75 201 98 228 NOTE: The "trust-fund ratio" is the ratio of the balance in the OASDI Trust Funds on a particular date to the outgo in the next 12 months. NOTE: The figures in this table do not include the repayment of the loan from the HI Trust Fund to the OASI Trust Fund in 1982 (about $5 billion). NOTE: The figures do take into account the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248). Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 10D ESTIMATED TOTAL REDUCTION IN OASDI BENEFIT OUTGO REQUIRED DURING 1983-89 TO REACH ALTERNATIVE TARGET LEVELS OF TRUST-FUND RATIOS BY BEGINNING OF 1988, UNDER ALTERNATIVES II-B AND III (IN BILLIONS) 1988 Trust-Fund Ratio of 15% 1988 Trust-Fund Ratio of 25% Calendar Year Alternative II-B Assumptions Alternative III Assumptions Alternative II-B Assumptions Alternative III Assumptions 1983 $20 $23 $20 $23 1984 17 26 20 30 1985 7 22 13 26 1986 8 24 13 29 1987 8 29 14 37 1988 8 34 9 35 1989 9 44 10 46 1983-89 77 202 99 226 NOTE: The "trust-fund ratio" is the ratio of the balance in the OASDI Trust Funds on a particular date to the outgo in the next 12 months. NOTE: The figures in this table do not include the repayment of the loan from the HI Trust Fund to the OASI Trust Fund in 1982 (about $5 billion). NOTE: The figures do take into account the effect of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982 (P.L. 97-248). Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 11 COMPARISON OF OASDI BENEFICIARIES AND COVERED WORKERS BY ALTERNA- TIVE, CALENDAR YEARS 1945-2060 Covered workers' (in Calendar year thousands) Beneficia- Covered vies workers per per 100 OASDI ben- covered eficiary workers 1945 ............................................ 46,390 1,106 - 1,106 41.9 2 1950 ............................................ 48,280 2,930 - 2,930 16.5 6 1955 ............................................ 65,200 7,563 - 7,563 8.6 12 1960 ............................................ 72,530 13,740 522 14,262 5.1 20 1965 ............................................ 80,680 18,509 1,648 20,157 4.0 25 1970 ............................................ 93,090 22,618 2,568 25,186 3.6 28 1975_ ......................................... 100,200 26,998 4,125 31,123 3.2 31 1980 ............................................ '114,300 30,384 4,734 35,118 '3.3 '31 Alternative I: 1982 ................................... 116,004 31,476 4,370 35,845 3.2 31 1985 ................................... 126,557 33,028 4,047 37,075 3.4 29 1990 ................................... 137,093 36,069 4,053 40,122 3.4 29 1995 ................................... 141,637 37,609 4,249 41,858 3.4 30 2000 ................................... 146,513 38,585 4,803 43,388 3.4 30 2005 ................................... 151,749 40,066 5,506 45,572 3.3 30 2010 ................................... 155,761 43,234 6,140 49,374 3.2 32 2015 ................................... 158,066 48,449 6,552 55,001 2.9 35 2020 ................................... 159,891 54,608 6,722 61,330 2.6 38 2025- ................................. 162,842 60,782 6,612 67,394 2.4 41 2030 ................................... 167,424 64,647 6,404 71,051 2.4 42 2035 ................................... 173,020 66,058 6,419 72,477 2.4 42 2040 ................................... 178,967 65,587 6,679 72,266 2.5 40 2045 ................................... 184,936 65,452 7,045 72,497 2.6 39 2050 ................................... 191,223 66,554 7,289 73,843 2.6 39 2055 ................................... 198,021 68,258 7,451 75,709 2.6 38 2060 ................................... 205,183 69,974 7,676 77,650 2.6 38 Alternative II-A: 1982 ................................... 115,955 31,482 4,375 35,857 3.2 31 1985 ................................... 124,328 33,106 4,060 37,166 3.3 30 1990 ................................... 133,921 36,431 4,126 40,557 3.3 30 1995 ................................... 138,773 38,410 4,487 42,897 3.2 31 2000 ................................... 144,133 39,823 5,193 45,016 3.2 31 2C05 ................................... 148,771 41,745 6,031 47,776 3.1 32 2010 ................................... 151,577 45,376 6,753 52,129 2.9 34 2015 ................................... 152,296 51,070 7,205 58,275 2.6 38 2020 ................................... 152,100 57,789 7,372 65,161 2.3 43 2025 ................................... 152,505 64,578 7,218 71,796 2.1 47 2030 ................................... 154,100 69,188 6,946 76,134 2.0 49 2035 ................................... 156,276 71,317 6,894 78,211 2.0 50 2040 ................................... 158,430 71,497 7,073 78,570 2.0 50 2045 ................................... 160,219 71,893 7,316 79,209 2.0 49 2050 ................................... 162,023 73,079 7,392 80,471 2.0 50 2055 ................................... 164,080 74,378 7,377 81,755 2.0 50 2060 ................................... 166,318 75,258 7,422 82,680 2.0 50 Alternative II-B: 1982 ................................... 115,308 31,483 4,374 35,857 3.2 31 1985 ................................... 123,300 33,106 4,061 37,167 3.3 30 1990 ................................... 132,410 36,428 4,138 40,566 3.3 31 1995 ................................... 137,644 38,408 4,486 42,894 3.2 31 2000 ................................... 142,248 39,814 5,191 45,005 3.2 32 2005 ................................... 146,798 41,725 6,028 47,753 3.1 33 2010 ................................... 149,515 45,359 6,748 52,107 2.9 35 2015 ................................... 150,148 51,048 7,198 58,246 2.6 39 2020 ................................... 149,873 57,753 7,361 65,114 2.3 43 2025 ................................... 150,205 64,542 7,207 71,749 2.1 48 2030 ................................... 151,750 69,138 6,934 76,072 2.0 50 2035 ................................... 153,889 71,277 6,882 78,159 2.0 51 2040 ................................... 156,015 71,440 7,061 78,501 2.0 50 2045 ................................... 157,777 71.824 7,304 79,128 2.0 50 2050 ................................... 159,545 73,034 7,380 80,414 2.0 50 2055 ................................... 161,573 74,313 7,364 81,677 2.0 51 2060 ................................... 163,778 75,215 7,410 82.625 2.0 50 Alternative III: 1982 ................................... 115,178 31,496 4,376 35,872 3.2 31 1985 ................................... 121,330 33,255 4,079 37,334 3.2 31 1990 ................................... 130,300 37,125 4,246 41,371 3.1 32 1995 ................................... 135,944 40,013 4,714 44,727 3.0 33 2000 ................................... 140,370 42,415 5,560 47,975 2.9 34 2005 ................................... 144,254 45,360 6,510 51,870 2.8 36 2010 ................................... 145,600 50,080 7,293 57,373 2.5 39 2015 ................................... 144,295 56,934 7,759 64,693 2.2 45 2020 ................................... 141,475 64,913 7,898 72,811 1.9 51 2025 ................................... 138,631 73,154 7,683 80,837 1.7 58 2030 ................................... 136,560 79,327 7,324 86,651 1.6 63 2035 ................................... 134,724 83,133 7,172 90,305 1.5 67 2040.................................. . 132,593 84,945 7,214 92,159 1.4 70 2045 ................................... 129,844 86,866 7,252 94,118 1.4 72 2050 ................................... 126,971 89,022 7,071 96,093 1.3 76 2055 ................................... 124,339 90,398 6,796 97,194 1.3 78 2060 ................................... 121,968 90,672 6,587 97,259 1.3 80 'Workers with taxable earnings at some time during the year. 'Beneficiaries with monthly benefits in current-payment status as of June 30. 'Preliminary. Note: The definitions of alternatives 1, II-A, II-B, and 111 are presented in the text. The numbers of beneficiaries do not include certain noninsured persons aged 72 and over with less than 3 quarters of coverage, the costs for whom are reimbursable to the OAS1 Trust Fund by the general fund of the Treasury. The number of such persons is estimated to be 69,500 as of June 30, 1982, and less than 1,000 by the turn of the century. SOURCE: Table 28 in 1982 OASDI Trustees Report Appendix K, page 81 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 12 SELECTED DEMOGRAPHIC ASSUMPTIONS BY ALTERNATIVE, CALE;4DAR YEARS 1940 - 2060 Past experience: 1940 .......... 2.23 61.1 65.6 12.0 13.7 1945 .......... 2.42 62.7 68.5 12.7 14.7 1950 .......... 3.03 65.5 71.2 12.9 15.4 1955 .......... 3.50 66.7 73.0 13.2 15.9 1960 ............................. 3.61 66.7 73.4 13.0 16.1 1965 ............................. 2.88 66.8 74.1 13.0 16.6 1970 ............................. 2.43 67.1 74.9 13.2 17.2 1975 ............................. 1.77 68.7 76.5 13.7 18.1 1976 ............................. 1.74 69.0 76.7 13.8 18.1 1977 ............................. 1.79 69.3 77.1 13.9 18.4 1978 ............................. 1.76 69.5 77.2 14.0 18.4 1979 ............................. 1.81 69.8 77.7 14.3 18.7 19N. ............................ 1.84 69.8 77.7 14.3 18.7 Alternative I: 1981 ............................. 1.87 70.0 77.9 14.3 18.8 1982 ............................. 1.89 70.1 78.0 14.4 18.9 1983 ............................. 1.91 70.2 78.1 14.4 19.0 1984 ............................. 1.93 70.3 78.2 14.5 19.0 1985 ............................. 1.96 70.4 78.3 14.5 19.1 1990 ............................. 2.0, 70.9 78.9 14.8 19.4 1995 ............................. 2.18 71.2 79.2 14.9 19.7 2000 ............................. 2.29 71.4 79.4 15.0 19.8 2005 ............................. 2.40 71.5 79.5 15.1 19.9 2010 ............................. 2.40 71.6 79.6 15.2 20.0 2020 ............................. 2.40 71.8 79.9 15.3 20.2 2030 ............................. 2.40 72.0 80.1 15.5 20.4 2040 ............................. 2.40 72.2 80.3 15.6 20.6 2050 ............................. 2.40 72.4 80.6 15.7 20.8 2060 ............................ 2.40 72.6 80.8 15.9 21.0 Alternatives I II-A and I-B: 1981 ............................. 1.86 70.1 78.0 14.4 18.9 1982 ............................. 1.87 70.4 78.3 14.5 19.1 1983 ............................. 1.88 70.6 78.5 14.6 19.3 1984 ............................. 1.89 70.8 78.7 14.7 19.4 1985 ............................. 1.90 71.0 78.9 14.8 19.5 1990 ............................. 1.95 71.9 80.0 15.3 20.3 1995 ............................. 2.00 72.6 80.8 15.6 20.8 2000 ............................. 2.05 72.9 81.1 15.8 21.1 2005 ............................. 2.10 73.2 81.4 16.0 21.4 2010 ............................. 2.10 73.4 81.6 16.1 21.6 2020 ............................. 2.10 73.8 82.1 16.4 22.0 2030 ............................. 2.10 74.2 82.6 16.7 22.4 2040 ............................. 2.10 74.6 83.1 17.0 22.8 2050 ............................. 2.10 75.0 63.6 17.3 23.2 2060 ............................. 2.10 75.4 84.1 17.6 23.6 Alternative III: 1981 ............................. 1.84 70.3 78.3 14.5 19.1 1982 ............................. 1.83 70.8 78.9 14.7 19.5 1983 ............................. 1.83 71.3 79.4 14.9 19.8 1984 ............................. 1.82 71.7 79.8 15.1 20.1 1985 ............................. 1.82 72.1 80.2 15.3 20.4 1990 ............................. 1.79 74.0 82.5 16.3 22.1 1995 ............................. 1.76 75.3 84.1 17.0 23.5 2000 ............................. 1.73 75.9 84.9 17.4 24.2 2005 ............................. 1.70 76.4 85.5 17.8 24.7 2010 ............................. 1.70 76.8 86.0 18.1 25.1 2020 ............................. 1.70 77.7 87.2 18.8 26.1 2030 ............................. 1.70 78.5 68.3 19.5 27.2 2040 ............................. 1.70 79.4 89.5 20.1 28.2 2050 ............................. 1.70 80.2 90.6 20.8 29.3 2060 ............................. 1.70 81.0 91.8 21.5 30.4 'The total fertility rate for any year is the average number of children who would be born to a woman in her lifetime if she were to experience the birth rates by age observed in, or assumed for, the selected year, and if she were to survive the entire child-bearing period. 'T'he life expectancy for any year is the average number of years of life remaining to a person if that person were to experience the death rates by age assumed for the selected year. SOURCE: Table 11, 1982 OASDI Trustees Report, and Office of the Actuary, SSA Appendix K, page 82 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 13 SELECTED ECONOMIC ASSUMPTIONS BY ALTERNATIVE, CALENDAR YEARS 1960-2060 Average annual percentage increase in- Average Average wages in Average annual covered Real-wage annual in- unemploy- employ- Consumer differential' terest rate' ment rate' Calendar year Real GNP' ment price index (percent) (percent) (percent) Past experience: 1960-64 ............................. 4.0 3.4 1.3 2.1 3.7 5.7 1965-69 ............................. 4.4 5.4 3.4 2.0 5.2 3.8 1970 ................................... -.2 4.9 5.9 -1.0 7.3 4.9 1971 ................................... 3.4 4.9 4.3 .6 6.0 5.9 1972 ................................... 5.7 7.3 3.3 4.0 5.9 5.6 1973 ................................... 5.8 6.9 6.2 .7 6.6 4.9 1974_ ................................ -.6 7.4 11.0 -3.6 7.5 5.6 1975 ................................... -1.1 6.6 9.1 -2.5 7.4 8.5 1976 ................................... 5.4 '8.2 5.7 '2.5 7.1 7.7 1977 ................................... 5.5 '8.0 6.5 '1.5 7.1 7.0 1978 ................................... 4.8 8.2 7.6 '.6 8.2 6.0 1979 ................................... 3.2 '8.8 11.4 '-2.6 9.1 5.8 1980 ................................... -.2 '8.6 13.5 '-4.9 11.0 7.1 Alternative I: 1981 ................................... '2.1 8.8 10.3 -1.5 13.3 7.6 1982 ................................... 1.1 8.2 6.3 1.9 12.7 8.6 1983 ................................... 5.6 7.3 5.9 1.4 10.3 7.4 1984 ................................... 5.4 7.5 4.6 2.9 7.8 6.5 1985 ................................... 5.1 7.0 4.2 2.8 6.6 5.8 1986 ................................... 4.8 6.7 3.8 2.9 6.0 5.4 1987 ................................... 4.6 6.4 3.4 3.0 5.7 5.0 1988 ................................... 4.4 6.1 3.0 3.1 5.6 4.8 1989 ................................... 4.2 5.7 2.6 3.1 5.4 4.6 1990 ................................... 4.0 5.2 2.2 3.0 5.3 4.3 1995. .................................. 3.4 4.5 2.0 2.5 5.1 4.0 2000 8 later ...................... '3.5 4.5 2.0 2.5 5.1 4.0 Alternative II-A': 1981 ................................... '1.9 8.8 10.3 -1.5 13.3 7.6 1982 ................................... .3 8.6 6.8 1.8 13.4 8.9 1983 ................................... 5.2 6.3 6.0 .3 12.1 7.9 1984 ................................... 5.0 5.6 4.6 1.0 10.8 7.1 1985 ................................... 4.8 7.4 4.8 2.6 9.8 6.4 1986 ................................... 4.4 7.3 4.6 2.7 8.2 5.8 1987 ................................... 4.3 7.1 4.5 2.6 6.7 5.3 1988 ................................... 4.1 7.1 4.3 2.8 6.4 5.2 1989 ................................... 3.9 6.6 3.9 2.7 6.2 5.1 1990 ................................... 3.7 6.0 3.5 2.5 6.0 5.0 1995 ................................... 3.0 5.0 3.0 2.0 5.6 5.0 2000 & later ...................... '3.1 5.0 3.0 2.0 5.6 5.0 Alternative II-B: 1981 ................................... '1.8 8.6 10.3 -1.7 13.3 7.6 1982 ................................... -.8 6.6 6.9 -.3 13.0 9.1 1983 ................................... 4.2 8.1 7.9 .2 11.4 8.5 1984 ................................... 3.3 8.1 7.4 .7 9.3 8.0 1985 ................................... 3.0 6.9 6.6 .3 8.0 7.7 1986 ................................... 3.0 6.8 5.8 1.0 7.1 7.4 1987 ................................... 3.0 6.6 5.5 1.1 6.8 7.1 1988 ................................... 3.0 6.6 5.3 1.3 6.6 6.8 1989 ................................... 3.0 6.4 4.9 1.5 6.5 6.4 1990 ................................... 3.0 6.0 4.5 1.5 6.4 6.1 1995 ................................... 2.5 5.5 4.0 1.5 6.1 5.0 2000 & later. ..................... '2.6 5.5 4.0 1.5 6.1 5.0 Alternative Ill: 1981 ................................... '1.8 8.6 10.3 -1.7 13.3 7.6 1982 ................................... -1.5 6.3 7.2 -.9 13.1 9.3 1983 ................................... .6 7.3 9.6 -2.3 12.3 9.8 1984 ................................... 2.5 7.8 9.6 -1.8 10.5 9.6 1985 ................................... 3.8 9.2 9.2 .0 9.4 8.8 1986 ................................... 2.9 9.1 8.8 .3 8.8 8.4 1987 ................................... 2.7 8.7 8.4 .3 8.3 8.0 1988 ................................... 2.7 8.5 8.0 .5 8.1 7.7 1989 ................................... 2.7 8.3 7.6 .7 7.8 7.3 1990 ................................... 2.7 8.0 7.2 .8 7.6 6.9 1995 ................................... 1.8 6.2 5.2 1.0 6.7 6.0 2000 & later ...................... '2.1 6.0 5.0 1.0 6.6 6.0 'The real GNP (Gross National Product) is the total output of goods and services expressed in constant dollars. 'The difference between the percentage increase in average annual wages in covered employment and the percentage increase in the average annual CPI. 'The average of the interest rates determined in each of the 12 months of the year for special public-debt obligations issuable to the trust funds. 'The ultimate rates are adjusted by age and sex based on the total labor force aged 16 and over as of July 1, 1970. Rates shown for earlier years are civilian unemployment rates for those years. 'Preliminary. 'The actual value of the 1981 increase in real GNP was 2.0 percent. This value was not available at the time the cost estimates were prepared; the cost estimates were based on the assumed increases in real GNP shown under the four alternatives. 'This value is for the year 2000. The annual percentage increase in real GNP is assumed to continue to change after 2000 under each alternative to reflect the dependence of labor force growth on the size and age-sex distribution of the population. The percentage increases for 2060 are 3.4, 2.5, 2.1, and 1.0 for alternatives I, 11-A, II-B, and 111, respectively. 'The economic assumptions in alternative It-A for 1981-87 are identical to or derived from the assumptions underlying the President's 1983 Budget, with the exception of the assumed 1981 increases in the nominal wage and the real wage as well as the assumed 1982 increases in the real wage and the CPI, all of which have been adjusted to reflect actual experience available since the Budget assumptions were released. Source: Table 10 in 1982 OASDI Trustees Report. Appendix K, page 83 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 14 COMPARISON OF ESTIMATED AND ACTUAL KEY ECONOMIC INDICATORS, 1972-73 FORECASTS I (In pereentl Calendar year 1 In In In In 972 1973 Actual 19721 19731 In Actual 1972 In 1973 Actual 1972........ 3.3 ........ 4.0 ........ 5.6 1974........ 1 11.0 1 -3.5 1 5.6 5.6 1975........ 2 .75 3.3 9.1 2.25 2.9 -2.5 4.2 4.5 8.5 1976........ l 5.8 I 2.5 7.7 1977........ 2.75 6.5 1 0.4 7.0 1978........ 2.75 7.7 2.25 0.5 6.0 1979........ 2.75 11.5 2.25 -3.1 5.8 1980........ 2.75 13.5 2.25 -5.0 7.1 I There were a number of le islative changes made to the "automatic" provisions between Jul! 1972 and December 1973. 1 Real wage: Defined as the Increase in average nominal wages over prices. 1 Actually, the long-range trust'fund projections had a safety margin of % of a percent built Into the real wage differential. For trust fund projection purposes the average Increase In real wagpesl{was assumed to be 1% percent per year (reflected by an annual Increase In the CPI pf 3 percent). COMPARISON OF ESTIMATED AND ACTUAL KEY ECONOMIC INDICATORS, 1977 FORECAST I Real wage CPI Increase differential Unemployment rate Calendar Esti- Esti? Esti? year mated Actual mated Actual mated Actual 1977 .................... 6.0 6.5 2.4 0.4 7.1 7.0 1978 .................... 5.4 7.7 2.7 0.5 6.3 6.0 1979 .................... 5.3 11.5 2.5 -3.1 5.7 5.8 1980 .................... 4.7 13.5 2.4 -5.0 5.2 7.1 1981 .................... 4.1 ? 11.1 2.3 0-0.9 5.0 97.8 The 1977 forecast was based on the Intermediate set of assumptions In the 1977 trustees' report. 1 Estimates based on the economic assumptions under the II-e path in the 1981 trustees' report. In summary, what has occurred with respect to both the 1972-71 and 1977 Trust Fund forecasts is that the higher than projected in- flation rate caused benefits to increase far beyond expectations. nnd aggregate expenditures to do likewise, while lower real wage growth and higher unemployment caused revenues to grow at an inadequate rate. SOURCE: Staff Data and Materials Related to Social Security Financing, Senate Committee on finance, September- 1982 Appendix K, page 84 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Page 1 of 2 SOCIAL SECURITY COVERAGE INFORMATION A. Workers Covered (Estimates for 1980): Number of Persons (millions) Type of Employment Totala/ Covered- Covered Wage and Salary 108.9 97.5 89.5% Private Sector 88.0 84.5 96.0 Industry and Commerce 77.0 76.8 99.7 Farm 2.0 1.5 74.6 Domestic 1.9 .5 28.1 Nonprofit 6.5 5.1 78.8 Railroad .6 .6 100.0 Public Sector 20.9 12.9 62.0 Federal 3.7 .6 15.4 State and local 15.0 10.2 68.2 Military 2.1 2.1 100.0 Self-Employment 8.6 6.5 75.5 Total, all employment 117.4 103.9 88.5 a/ Data on total employment are based upon class of worker of longest job as reported by the individual in the Current Population Survey and total employment covers the non-nstitutionalized population age 14 and over in the 50 States and the District of Columbia as well as members of the armed forces, at home and overseas. b/ Data on covered employment are based upon class of worker of major job as determined by the highest amount of taxable wages as reported to the Social Security Administration by employers. SOURCE: Current Population Reports, series P-60, No. 118, series P-25, No. 902, and unpublished data for 1980 based upon March 1981 Current Population Survey; Railroad Retirement Board; Continuous Work History Sample, 1977. Appendix K, page 85 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Page 2 of 2 Table 15 SOCIAL SECURITY COVERAGE INFORMATION B. Information on Total Earnings in Covered Employment, Taxable Payroll and Percent Taxable of Total Earnings (Selected Years 1937-82) Calendar Earnings in Covered Employment (billions) Percent Year Total Taxable Taxable 1937 $ 32.2 $ 29.6 92.0 % 1940 35.7 33.0 92.4 1945 71.6 62.9 88.0 1950 109.8 87.5 79.7 1951 b/ 148.9 120.8 81.1 1955 196.1 157.5 80.3 1959 b/ 255.0 202.3 79.3 1960 265.2 207.0 78.0 1965 351.7 250.7 71.3 1966 b/ 390.7 312.5 80.0 1968 b/ 460.0 375.8 81.7 1970 531.6 415.6 78.2 1972 b/ 617.9 484.1 78.3 19735/ 686.7 561.8 81.8 1974 b/ 746.8 636.8 85.3 1975 787.6 664.7 84.4 1976 874.7 737.7 84.3 1977 968.1 817.3 84.4 1978 1,087.9 915.8 84.2 1979 b/ 1,217.4 1,070.7 88.0 1980 b/ 1,321.1 1,175.3 89.0 19816/ 1,448.0 1,300.8 89.8 1982E/ 1,535.2 1,385.3 90.2 at Total earnings in covered employment represents the total earnings of persons in those employments covered by the program, where such earnings are subject to the Social Security taxes (or would be excepted for the effect of the maximum taxable earnings base). b/ Year of an ad hoc increase in the taxable earnings base. c/ Estimate based on Alternative 11-B assumptions in 1982 OASDI Trustees Report. The percent taxable for future years should remain relatively stable as the taxable earnings base rises automatically based on increases in average wage levels. SOURCE: Office of Research and Statistics, Social Security Administration. Appendix K, page 86 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 OASDI-H1 TAXES PAID BY WORKERS AT FEDERAL MINIMUM, AVERAGE AND MAXIMUM WAGE LEVELS, 1937-90 Federal Minimum Wage Average Wages Masi ' '. T.xab/e E.rn nos $ase Employee Employee Employee Self-Employed Year Earnings Taxes Earnings Taxes Earnings Taxes Taxes -----------------------------HISTORICAL ------------------------------- 1937 at $ 1,137.96 $ 11.38 $ 3,000.00 $ 30.00 J 1938 ~ 87.00 I .87 1,053.24 10.53 3,000.00 30.00 1939 537.00 5.37 1,142.36 11.42 3,000.00 30.00 1940 624.00 6.24 1,195.00 11.95 3,000.00 30.00 4/ 1941 624.00 6.24 1,276.04 12.76 3,000.00 30.00 1942 624.00 6.24 1,454.28 14.54 3,000.00 30.00 J 1943 624.00 6.24 1,713.52 17.14 3,000.00 30.00 J 1944 624.00 6.24 1,936.32 19.36 3,000.00 30.00 1945 659.00 6.59 2,021.40 20.21 3,000.00 30.00 J 1946 832.00 8.32 1,891.76 18.92 3,000.00 30.00 1947 832.00 8.32 2,175.32 21.75 3,000.00 30.00 4./ 1948 832.00 8.32 2,361.64 23.62 3,000.00 30.00 !z/ 1949 832.00 8.32 2,483.20 24.83 3,000.00 30.00 Al 1950 1,499.00 22.49 2,543.96 38.16 3,000.00 45.00 Al 1951 1,560.00 23.40 2,799.16 41.99 3,600.00 54.00 ~ 81.00 1952 1,560.00 23.40 2,973.32 44.60 3,600.00 54.00 81.00 1953 1,560.00 23.40 3,139.44 47.09 3,600.00 54.00 81.00 1954 1,560.00 31.20 3,155.64 63.11 3,600.00 72.00 108.00 1955 1,560.00 31.20 3,301.44 66.03 4,200.00 84.00 126.00 1956 1,993.00 39.86 3,532.36 70.65 4,200.00 84.00 126.00 1957 2,080.00 46.80 3,641.72 81.94 4,200.00 94.50 141.75 1958 2,080.00 46.80 3,673.80 82.66 4,200.00 94.50 141.75 1959 2,080.00 52.00 3,855.80 96.39 4,800.00 120.00 180.00 1960 2,080.00 62.40 4,007.12 120.21 4,800.00 144.00 216.00 1961 2,184.00 65.52 4,086.76 122.60 4,800.00 144.00 216.00 1962 2,392.00 74.75 4,291.40 134.11 4,800.00 150.00 225.60 1963 2,461.00 89.21 4,396.64 159.38 4,800.00 174.00 259.20 1964 2,600.00 94.25 4,576.32 165.89 4,800.00 174.00 259.20 1965 2,600.00 94.25 4,658.72 168.88 4,800.00 174.00 259.20 1966 2,600.00 100.20 4,938.36 207.41 6,600.00 277.20 405.90 1967 2,886.00 126.98 5,213.44 229.39 6,600.00 290.40 422.40 1968 3,293.00 144.89 5,571.76 245.16 7,800.00 343.20 499.20 1969 3,328.00 159.74 5,893.76 282.90 7,800.00 374.40 538.20 1970 3,328.00 159.74 6,186.24 296.94 7,800.00 374.40 538.20 1971 3,328.00 173.06 6,497.08 337.85 7,800.00 405.60 585.00 1972 3,328.00 173.06 7,133.80 370.96 9,000.00 468.00 675.00 1973 3,328.00 194.69 7,580.16 443.44 10,800.00 631.80 864.00 1974 3,883.00 227.16 8,030.76 469.80 13,200.00 772.20 1,042.80 1975 4,368.00 255.53 8,630.92 504.91 14,100.00 824.85 1,113.90 1976 4,784.00 279.86 9,226.48 539.75 15,300.00 895.05 1,208.70 1977 4,784.00 279.86 9,776.44 572.10 16,500.00 965.25 1,303.50 1978 5,512.00 333.48 10,556.03 638.64 17,700.00 1,070.85 1,433.70 1979 6,032.00 369.76 11,479.46 703.69 22,900.00 1,403.77 1,854.90 1980 6,448.00 395.26 12,513.46 767.08 25,900.00 1,587.67 2,097.90 1981 6,968.00 463.37 13,594.27 904.02 29,700.00 1,975.05 2,762.10 1982 6,968.00 466.86 14,495.68 971.21 32,400.00 2,170.80 3,029.40 ---------------------------- CUMULATIVE ------------------------------- 1937-82 5,210.74 10,207.35 16,936.49 2 ;VZA.40 ' 1951-82 5,110.94 9,950.78 16,501.49 22,876.50 --------------------------- FUTURE YEARS S/ - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 1983 7,530.00 504.51 15,663.97 1,049.49 35,100.00 2,351.70 3,281.85 1984 8,137.00 545.18 16,926.39 1,134.07 37,500.00 2,512.50 3,506.25 1985 8,700.00 613.35 18,099.11 1,275.99 40,500.00 2,855.25 4,009.50 1986 9,292.00 664.38 19,329.42 1,382.05 43,800.00 3,131.70 4,380.00 1987 9,907.00 708.35 20,609.56 1,473.58 46,800.00 3,346.20 4,680.00 1988 10,560.00 755.04 21,968.32 1,570.73 50,100.00 3,582.15 5,010.00 1989 11,231.00 803.02 23,363.63 1,670.50 53,400.00 3,818.10 5,340.00 1990 11,906.00 910.81 24,767.80 1,894.74 57,000.00 4,360.50 6,127.50 at Federal minimum wage first applicable in 1938. S/ Self-employed first covered effective 1951. C/ Earnings amounts after 1982 based on Alternative II-B assumptions used in 1982 OASDI Trustees Repot. Appendix K, page 87 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Table 17A CCtIPFRISON OF OPSDI ( RPZ BENEFIT INCREASES WITH INL';F.PSES IN C ISUME_R PRICE INDEX Month When First Effective (1) Percentage Benefit Increased/ (2) Increase in CPI from Previous Effective Date (3) Column (1) minus Column (2) September 1950 77i/ 75.5SI`/ +11.5% September 1952 15C7 9.3 +5.7 September 1954 13K/ 0.5 +12.5 January 1959 7 7.9 -0.9 January 1965 7 7.9 -0.9 February 1968 13 9.3 +3.7 January 1970 15 10.8 +4.2 January 1971 10 5.2 +4.8 September 1972 20 5.9 +14.1 June 1974 l ld/ 16.4 -5.4 June 1975 8.0e/ 9.3 -1.3 June 1976 6.4e/ 5.4 +1.0 June 1977 5.9e/ 6.9 -1.0 June 1978 6.5e/ 7.3 -0.8 June 1979 9.9e/ 11.1 -1.2 June 1980 . 143!/ 14.2 + .1 June 1981 .2e/ 11 9.5 +1 7 June 1992 7.4e/ 6.9 . +0.5 at All benefit increases, except those for September 1950, 1952, and 1954, were uniform across-the-board percentage increases (at times, although not for 1965 and later, with somewhat larger proportionate increases in the minimum benefit). b/ Measured from January 1940. c/ Average increase in benefits for those then on the roll. d/ Made in two steps, with 7% being effective for March 1974. e/ Resulting from automatic-adjustment provisions. f/ Increase from January 1940. Appendix K, page 88 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4 COMPARISON OF OASDI GENERAL BENEFIT INCREASES WITH INCREASES IN AVERAGE WAGE LEVELS Period (1) OASDI Benefit Increases a/ (2) Increase in Average Wages bI (3) Column (1) Minus Column (2) January 1940-September 1950 77% 121.8% -44.8% September 1950-September 1952 15 15.8 -.8 September 1952-September 1954 13 5.9 +7.1 September 1954-January 1959 7 18.4 -11.4 January 1959-January 1965 7 22.5 -15.5 January 1965-February 1968 13 17.7 -4.7 February 1968-January 1970 15 11.3 +3.7 January 1970-January 1971 10 5.0 +5.0 January 1971-September 1972 20 13.7 +6.3 September 1972-June 1974 11 10.9 +.1 June 1974-June 1975 8.0 7.4 +.6 June 1975-June 1976 6.4 6.9 -.5 June 1976-June 1977 5.9 6.0 -.1 June 1977-June 1978 6.5 7.9 -1.4 June 1978-June 1979 9.9 8.7 +1.2 June 1979-June 1980 14.3 9.0 +5.3 June 1980-June 1981 11.2 10.0 +1.2 June 1981-June 1982 7.4 6.6c/ +.8 a/ See Table 17A. b/ Based on wages in covered employment in first quarter of year for years up through 1977, and based on total nationwide wages (in both covered and noncovered employment) for subsequent years. (Average-wage amounts used are based on the wage-indexing series developed by the Office of the Actuary, Social Security Admin- istration.) c/ Based on Alternative II-B assumptions in 1982 Trustees Report. Appendix K, page 89 Approved For Release 2008/10/02 : CIA-RDP85-00003R000200100001-4