LETTER TO HONORABLE LIONEL OLMER FROM WILLIAM J. CASEY

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP84B01072R000300020023-0
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
C
Document Page Count: 
27
Document Creation Date: 
December 20, 2016
Document Release Date: 
February 22, 2007
Sequence Number: 
23
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
July 1, 1982
Content Type: 
LETTER
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP84B01072R000300020023-0.pdf1.3 MB
Body: 
Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 LIKITEE06 OFFICIAL USE Big Four: Growing Divergence in Financial Capital Costs LIMITED OFFICIAL USE Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84B01072R000300020023-0 LIMITED OFFICIAL USE Big Four: Growing Divergence in Financial Capital Costs Foreword Analysts frequently argue that high financing costs put US firms at a disadvantage compared with companies operating in other major countries, lessening the ability of US firms to aggressively pursue new investment strategies or to improve existing facilities. The past surge in US interest rates has widened this financial gap, particularly vis-a-vis Japan, and enhanced, some argue, other relative advantages held by foreign competitors. This report examines general trends in financial capital costs through 1981 and analyzes some of the elements responsible for existing differences in Japan, France, West Germany, and the United States. The estimates cut across industries and thus are not applicable to international comparisons for any given industry. Firms facing higher financial capital costs, moreover, are not necessarily less likely than their competitors to undertake a particular investment; capital costs are only one element in corporate investment decisions, which must also take account of overall corporate goals, the cost of physical capital, cash flow, depreciation regulations, expected returns to investment, inflation and exchange rate changes, and the availability of long-term funds. LIMITED OFFICIAL USE Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84B01072R000300020023-0 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 The cost of. capital for corporations in the United States, Japan, West Germany, and France has risen rapidly during the last decade, but the rise has been smallest in Japan. In 1981, Japanese industrial corporations on average faced financial capital costs only about half as high as US firms--roughly 9 percent vs. almost 17 percent. The cost for West German firms was close to that in Japan; the cost for French firms was higher but still below that in the United States. The spread is considerably greater now than it was throughout most of the 1970s. Thus, US firms are more than ever disadvantaged relative to their foreign competitors. Specifically, o The range of profitable investments is narrower for US than foreign companies. The higher capital costs faced by US corporations increase both the absolute investment threshold and the uncertainty attached to a firm's ability to recover investment costs. o US corporations require higher profit margins for capital-intensive products than . their foreign competitors. In markets characterized by strong price competition, this disadvantage may deter *US investors from going head to head against foreign firms or substantially limit, if not eliminate, their profits should they decide to compete. Capital costs for Japanese, West German, and French firms have traditionally been lower largely because of institutional factors. o Foreign lenders charge a lower Risk Premium on business loans, in part because corporate earnings are less variable than in the United States. o Japanese and West German firms benefit from close and sustained ties to their banks. French firms similarly benefit from substantial support by government-backed banks. These relationships, in turn, have allowed foreign firms to rely much more heavily on debt finance and thus to gain substantially from the tax deductibility of interest payments. Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84B01072R000300020023-0 The capital cost gap between the United States and Japan and West Germany has widened in recent years because of the greater return demanded by US lenders to compensate for the higher rate of inflation in the United States. The.gap would have been even greater., however, if foreign governments had not matched a portion of the inflation-induced rise in US rates to quell the flight-of interest-sensitive funds. Greater internal competition for funds from the West German and Japanese Governments also played a role in raising interest rates in these two countries. LIMITED OFFICIAL USE 3' Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84B0l072R000300020023-0 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 Cost of Capital to Corporate Borrowers Firms in the four major industrial countries--the United States, Japan, West Germany, and France--are paying record or near record rates for money at a time when recession and political uncertainties have dampened investor expectations for returns to investment. The weighted after-tax cost of capital for industry in these four countries soared to an average of almost 12 percent last yea17 nearly double rates that prevailed in the mid-to-early 1970s.- The combined impact of these two forces dramatically reduced the rate of capital investment in manufacturing in 1974-80 (see table 1). Average Annual Percentage Increase 1967 - 1973 1974 - 1980 United States 4.5 2.0 France 7.0 1.9 West Germany 6.2 1.5 Japan 13.5 2.3 .1 Includes housing investment. SOURCE: OECD Quarterly National Accounts Bulletin The cost of capital is a guiding element in corporate investment de~~'sions and a significant determinant of firm profitability.- A firm can undertake investments that will 11 The average weighted cost of capital includes the cost of debt and equity for nonfinancial corporations weighted by their shares in the aggregate corporate balance sheet. All cost of capital data used in this paper are calculated on an after-tax ~7sis. See Appendix A for details of the calculation. - The cost of capital concept does not refer solely to the cost of external funds for specific projects but to the opportunity cost of using funds from all sources--external or internal. The assumption is that all funds can be priced the same as the next dollar of capital raised in the market. Furthermore, the concept .assumes that a firm's debt/equity proportions will remain the Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 generate a return below its cost of capital but which will still earn adequate profits in an accounting sense. Over the long run, however, regular investments in projects below the firm's cost of capital would, ceteris paribus, drive the firm's investors to other more profitable and less risky investments. Not only do higher capital- costs thus constrain investment opportunity but they significantly increase the degree of uncertainty attached to investments. For a given project, the closer a firm's cost of capital is to the expected return from investment, the higher the probability that actual returns will not exceed capital costs. Alternatively stated, the firm with the lower cost of capital can be more certain of covering its costs for any given investment. The importanc~/ of capital costs to investment decisions varies by industry.- The capital intensity is often far greater in high-technology areas; according to industry sources, $1 of capital investment is *required for each $2.50 in annual revenues for the latest generation of 64K random access memory devices. Capital cost differentials can be striking in their impact. Last year, when US corporations typically faced a weighted cost of capital of 16.6 percent, the total cost of a $100 million investment amortized over 15 years was over $275 million. In Japan, where the weighted cost of capital was only half as high, this same investment cost $182 million or one-third less. Even allowing for differences in relative depreciation schedules, the stream of returns necessary to cover capital costs is much higher in the United States than in Japan. - Not all corporations take into account a detailed cost of capital analysis before deciding a particular course of investment action. A recent survey found that a significant number of firms did not take adequate account of inflation, for example, in projecting potential return on investment. However, the large manufacturing corporations typically do make an effort to meet or exceed their average cost of capital when weighing investment alternatives. Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 The cost of capital is an important-but not the only factor in determining the level of a nation's industrial capital formation. The latter occurs within a larger frame of reference-overall net capital formation-which is shaped by a variety of other national economic, regulatory, and behavioral char- acteristics. Net capital formation as used in the following table consists of additions to business in- ventories plus net fixed investment-additional struc- tures and equipment, including newly produced hous- ing. This concept of net capital formation depicts a nation's annual additions to its stock of real assets, a major portion of which is associated with the manu- facturing sector. As indicated in the table, the United States devotes substantially less of its gross domestic product to net capital formation than Japan, West Germany, and France. Between 1972 and 1979, Japan increased its volume of net capital formation substantially, draw- ing on a large pool of household savings. Net capital formation (as a percent of GDP) 8.2 22.1 15.9 16_L 95.3 93.0 71.6 37.1 Net personal saving 56.2 51.9 41.8 22.2 Net business saving 24.7 25.0 10.1 6.6 Net government saving 5.3 25.3 21.3 9.3 Net rest of world 9.1 -9.1 -1.6 -0.9 Net capital formation (as percent of GDP) 6.4 149.8 18.9 188.9 13.7 104.3 12.3 67.8 Sources of financing Net personal saving 86.2 Net business saving 19.8 Net government saving 24.2 24.4 15.1 7.8 Net rest of world 19.6 9.0 6.2 -0.2 a Because of rounding, components may not add to totals shown. NOTE: Derived from National Accounts ofOECD Countries, 1962- 79. non-US data converted to US dollars at 1979 exchange rates. LIMITED OFFICIAL USE Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 Cross-Country Comparisons The cost of capital facing corporations in the United States, Japan, iyest Germany and France rose substantially over the past decade.-!' With the exception of the United States costs rose in 1972-1974, fell during 1975-1977, only to rise again beginning in 1978. In the' United States there was little downward movement in 1975-1977. This resulted in a widening divergence in capital costs relative to foreign corporations by the end of the period. Our calculations show that, for the group as a whole, the cost of capital rose to nearly 12. percent last year, up from 7-8 percent for most of the 1970s. Among the four, only Japan has managed to keep rates in line with historic levels (see table 2). Firms in the United States, in contrast, pay nearly 17 percent today--roughly double the average for the 1970s. Although rates in France and West Germany are lower than the US average, these countries are also experiencing financing costs well above those paid during the early-to-mid-1970s. More importantly, from a competitive standpoint, rate spreads between countries have widened dramatically. Last year, the average cost .of capital faced by US corporations was roughly double the rate in Japan and substantially above West. European. levels (see figure 1). .To get some sense of the reasons for the differences in capital costs faced by corporations in the United States, Japan, West Germany, and France we separated the average weighted cost of capital into three major components:) o The "risk-free" rate for capital. 41 To determine financial capital costs faced by manufacturers in the four major countries, we compiled an aggregate balance sheet for manufacturing firms in each of the countries and assigned costs to equity plus each type of debt. These costs were subsequently blended into a single cost of capital based on the weighted average of the source of corporate funding. The cost of short-term bank loans was based on the prime commercial rate. Long-term costs were either bond rates or commercial lending rates, depending on the degree of reliance on bonds or loans as funding sources. The cost of equity capital was determined by adding a risk factor--based on dividend yield and stock price appreciation--to the risk-free long-term rate as approximated by government bonds. See Appendix B for a detailed description. Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84B01072R000300020023-0 AVERAGE WEIGHTED COST OF CAPITAL TO INDUSTRY Legend ? FRANCE ? JAPAN ? USA = WEST GERMANY 1971 1976 1981 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 The Risk Premium demanded by lenders to compensate the uncertainty attached to corporate performance. The impact of tax deductions allowed corporations interest payments, the so-called leverage effect. Estimated Average Cost of Capital to Industry Risk-free rate 8.6 6.2 7.3 8.0 Inflation 6.0 4.9 5.8 7.8 Imputed real rate 2.6 1.3 1.5 0.2 Risk premium 3.0 5.7 4.1 1.6 Imputed leverage effect -3.1 -1.9 -4.1 -2.7 Cost of capital 8.5 10.0 7.3 6.9 Risk-free rate 10.4 7.6 8.7 7.8 Inflation 7.2_ 5.1 6.8 3.5 Imputed real rate 3.2 2.5 1.9 4.3 Risk premium 2.9 5.7 4.3 1.3 Imputed leverage effect - -3.9 -2.0 -4.5 -2.5 Cost of capital 9.4 11.3 B.S. 6.6 Risk-free rate 16.6 12.9 8.7 10.5 Inflation 11.6 9.6 2.6 4.3 Imputed real rate 5.0 3.3 6.1 6.2 Risk premium 3.5 6.4 4.6 2.6 Imputed leverage effect -5.8 -2.7 -4.1 -3.6 Cost of capital 14.3 16.6 9.2 9.5 The Risk-Free Rate The risk-free rate for capital is defined as the yield on 10-year government securities. It can, in turn, be viewed as containing two components: the inflationary expectations of lenders and a real price for capital. Our calculations show that inflationary expectations are the largest single factor behind the relatively high cost of capital to US industry. The inflation factor in US capital costs last year was 9.6 percent compared with 2.6 percent in Japan and 4.6 LIMITED OFFICIAL USE 7 roved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 LIMITED OFFICIAL USE percent, in West Germany, wherg, inflation rates have been much lower over the last five years, The uneven inflationary performances in the late 1970s, which led to this divergence, resulted from differences in government policy. Tokyo and Bonn chose to combat actual and latent inflationary pressures more strongly than recessionary problems; monetary authorities in both countries held the growth in money supply to rates well below previous norms. In contrast, the US and French money stocks grew much more rapidly as Washington and Paris focused on reducing unemployment from the high levels of 1975. A second key factor in the differential inflation rates of the 1970s appears to have been the wage policies of the various countries. In Japan and West Germany, a labor-business- government consensus that inflation had to be kept in check led to very moderate nominal wage gains. In contrast, the French government's greater emphasis on maintenance of real earnings permitted larger wage increases; rises in wage rates were also relatively rapid in the United States. Finally, the d.ifferenti-als in. inflation appeared to be magnified by positive feedbacks between domestic inflation and exchange rate movements. In Japan and West Germany, low domestic inflation contributed to appreciation of their currencies, which in turn lowered imported inflationary pressures. In France and the United States, where domestic inflation was more rapid, the international feedbacks tended to'boost inflation. The after-inflation, or real, cost of corporate capital has risen sharply in recent years in the three foreign countries to rates ranging from 5.0 percent to 6.2 percent. Japanese firms encountered the greatest absolute increase over the last five years--up 4.2 percentage points from 1.9 percent in 1976. The real rate in the United States, in contrast, rose moderately to an estimated 3.3 percent last year. The real rate rate was estimated by netting imputed inflationary expectations from the yield on government bonds--a proxy for a nation's risk-free rate for capital. In actuality it is determined by a combination of factors, but the key ingredient 61 The inflation components were determined by using a six-quarter geometrically distributed lag of the GNP deflator; this, it is assumed, approximates the investor's view of what will happen to inflation over the next several years. LIMITED OFFICIAL USE 8 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BOl072R000300020023-0 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84B01072R000300020023-0 LIMITED OFFICIAL USE remains the flow of and competition for loanable funds from national household sectors. Recently, however, the level of US interest rates has also played a role in determining the real cost of capital abroad. The four nations in question experienced falling saving rates over the past decade, slowing the increase in the supply of loanable funds. o Household saving rates vary significantly internationally--from a high of 18.5 percent of disposable income in Japan to 5.0 percent in the United States. With the exception of France, household saving rates are currently well below the levels which existed in the mid 1970s partly reflecting slower growth in real incomes and higher effective tax rates. o Corporate savings rates fell sharply during the 1974- 1975 recessionary period but --with the notable exception of Japan-- rose during the remainder of the decade. Uncertain economic prospects have kept fixed -capital expenditures below cash inflows for French and German corporations; the two nations have become significant net lenders to the rest of the world. On the demand side, growing government borrowing in capital markets appears to have been a major factor behind the rise in the real price of capital available to foreign corporations. Budget deficits in Japan, West Germany, and France have continued to escalate, while monetary policy has become far more restrictive to contain inflation. Central banks, as a'result, have purchased a smaller proportion of the growing number of government securities issued to finance the deficits. With a greater burden placed on private savings to absorb central government debt, the funds available to the private sector have, in most cases, been insufficient to prevent a substantial rise in the interest rates firms must pay for borrowed capital. The impact has been greatest in Japan because of the dramatic increase in government borrowing. Government debt issues took 43 percent of the domestic credit supply in 1979, up from only 15 percent in 1971. The increased competition from The Japanese treasury was a key factor in the increase in the LIMITED OFFICIAL USE Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 LIMITED OFFICIAL USE estimated real rate for corporate capital -- from 1 .5 percent in 1971 to 6.1 percent last year. o In France, central government borrowing, as a share of total credit raised, increased from less than 2 percent in 1971 to 12 percent in 1979. o Bonn's demands on the West German credit market also increased substantially during the 1970s, from 11 percent in 1971 to 19 percent in 1977. US corporations, in contrast, found increasing direct competition for loanable funds from the financial and household sectors during the 1970s. While government borrowing as a share of total demand for funds fell substantially, direct household demand rose by 9 percentage points, to over one-third of total demand for funds. The share of financial institutions more than doubled as they increased their capital base to support additional lending. While the market for investment capital remains largely domestic in nature, higher US nominal interest rates may have led foreign governments to raise the real cost of funds in. their capital markets. Despite lower domestic inflation, foreign monetary authorities have, to varying degrees, followed the upward movement in US interest rates by raising central bank discount rates. Failure to have done so would have resulted in outflows of interest-sensitive funds to dollar assets, currency depreciation, and ultimately increased inflationary pressures on the domestic economy. Risk Premium There are significant international differences in the risk premium demanded by lenders and investors to compensate for the uncertainty of corporate performance. Our calculations for 1981 show that US corporations bear the highest premium for corporate risk; 6.4 percent compared with 2.6 percent 81in West Germany 3.5 percent in France, and 4.6 percent in Japan.- The divergence in the risk premiums in part reflects differences in earnings variability among countries. An analysis of the variability in aggregate corporate earnings for these four countries indicates the greatest fluctuation in France followed "Business risk" can be defined as the premium attached to the sensitivity of corporate performance to changes in business climate. It is calculated by adjusting the observed cost of equity capital by the degree of corporate leverage. LIMITED OFFICIAL USE Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 Financial markets. in Japan, France, and West Ger- many were reorganized after World War 11 to ensure that capital would flow to industry. Bond and stock markets remained relatively undeveloped for a long period with household savings flowing mainly to banks which, in turn, became major holders of corporate capital. The pattern of corporate-lender relationships that has evolved has substantially af- fected risk assessment and corporate debt levels in these countries. Japan. The Japanese financial system was designed to enhance the ability of banks and financial authori- ties to allocate credit to industry. Japanese compan- ies, until recently, have had little alternative to bank borrowing. The authorities have kept bond yields artificially low and-have-rationed-the-volume of issues. Until recently, stock could only be issued at par, making stock issues a costly way of raising funds. Although measures have been taken to im- prove corporate alternatives to bank lending and to free somewhat the flow of capital in and out of the country, Tokyo has remained content with the limit- ed nature of the capital market-a system consistent with its objective of steadily increasing industrial output. The small number of major banks in Japan-13 city banks backed by nationwide branch networks-has centralized the supply of investment capital, allowing major corporations to raise funds efficiently. Strong competition for corporate business and banks' ability to loan at 100 times equity-as opposed to 25 times equity in the United States-have kept interest rate spreads reasonable for major corporate customers. More importantly, central bank supervision has often kept interest rates below market levels. As a result, the major city banks periodically need Bank of Japan refinancing and thus become subject to government guidance on the allocation of loans among industries. This guidance bolsters banker confidence in the abili- ty of targeted borrowers firms integral to Tokyo's vision of industrial development-to sustain high debt levels. Although most commercial bank lending is short term, explicit or implicit rollover agreements allow Japanese corporations to view short-term loans as long-term liabilities. Investment risks are, in fact, substantially reduced by a large home market remote from foreign competition and, in many cases, by the internal demand of highly integrated Japanese firms. Lending institutions, for their part, rely less on balance-sheet criteria in making loans. The corpora- tion's bank(s) usually has a detailed knowledge of firm affairs. The bank counts on the firm as a stable source of loan demand and, in return, implicitly guarantees that funds will be available to the com- pany, even if it means recourse to temporarily une- conomical sources of funding. Thus, Japanese bank- ers take a long-term view of firm prospects and base lending on the corporation's traditional profit and growth record, capacity for innovation, and potential for growth as measured by its position within the industry. France. The French capital market is characterized by an extremely complex set offinancial intermediar- ies, most under government control, which channel household savings into corporate investments. French firms depend heavily on bank lending to supplement internal funds; in the 1970s, domestic financial insti- tutions supplied over 75 percent of the funds raised by French corporations. The banking institutions are funded from postal savings, life insurance, and annu- ity accounts, which provide a tremendous flow of savings-more than 20 percent of personal income- at relatively low rates. The French stock market has traditionally been somewhat thin, and the bond mar- ket has been dominated by the nationalized indus- tries and special credit institutions. The Banque de France exercises close control over the amount and cost of financial assets available to firms. It sets annual ceilings for increases in bank lending, with specialized provisions for favored cate- gories such as export credits and housing. It also sets interest rates on the money market and fixes rates offered to household savers through the key savings Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 instruments. As in Japan, commercial banks rely on central bank refinancing of medium- and long-term industrial loans and are thus subject to administra- tive guidance. The Banque also offers' refinancing facilities at preferential interest rates to authorized credit institutions. The commercial banks are dominated by three government-owned banks-Banque Nationale de Par- is, Credit Lyonnais, and Societe General. These were nationalized in 1945 and currently account for rough- ly 70 percent of all deposits placed in France's 275 deposit banks. Although these three banks operate as private institutions, the chairmen and managing di- rectors are appointed by the government, and each bank has a government representative on its board of directors. The central government further influences business behavior via interest rate rebates on long-term indus- trial loans, largely to small and medium-sized firms, made by special credit institutions such as the Credit National and Credit Hotelier. Investment funds pro- vided by these institutions are often raised on the French bond market under government guarantee. ? Direct loans by the Credit National make up about 5 percent of all industrial finance in France. The bank has tended to take the lead in the development of national interest industries. French commercial banks have not been particularly supportive of riskier long-term investment in recent -years. Bank profitabil- ity has been depressed by the artificially low govern- ment regulated lending rates, and government-im- posed ceilings have limited the total amount of credit that may be extended. Citing French commercial bank caution in lending- specifically the excessive weight accorded short-term profits in deciding among potential borrowers-the Mitterrand government has nationalized an addition- al 39 commercial banks. As a result, the nationalized banking sector directly or indirectly accounts for 97 percent of all resident deposits and 93 percent of all loans. The government hopes that this additional control will enable it to ensure that lending criteria are adjusted in favor of long-term investments judged to be in the national interest. West Germany. In the West German financial system, a few large banks are crucial in attracting long-term deposits and relending to industrv. The central gov- ernment has not taken advantage of the financial system to guide lending activities. Financial policies are generally macroeconomic, with sectoral assist- ance provided by specific lending institutions. The banks own and control major blocks of corporate stock and thus often play a major role in decision- making. Corporations rely heavily on bank credit and are highly leveraged. An active secondary market for corporate bonds does not exist, and the stock market, aside from being depressed, is thin. Equity has traditionally been costly to market. The interlocking relationship between the financial and industrial sectors is perhaps greatest in West German v. Besides voting their own corporate shares, banks generally receive authorization to represent the interests of customers whose stock they held on deposit. In 1980 banks voted an average of 63 percent of corporate shares in the 74 largest West German corporations; the big three banks alone accounted for 35 percent of the shares voted. Bank directors sit on and frequently chair business supervisory boards; 570 bank executives, for example, are on the supervisory boards of the top 400 companies. As financial advisers and large holders of voting rights, banks have the potential to exert considerable influence on corporate behavior. At a minimum. banks are interested in ensuring that decisionmaking is consistent with long-term return to capital and thus the ability to repay the extensive long-term bank exposure. The firms benefit from the information bankers bring to the boardroom and from the greater degree of certainty that financial support exists for corporate decisions. Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84B01072R000300020023-0 by the United States, Japan, and West Germany. In addition, private investors in Japan, France, and West Germany may demand lower nominal risk premiums because favorable tax provisions enable them to obtain the same after-tax yield on investments from lower nominal returns. French investors may write off the first 5000 FF in share income and may claim a tax credit for 50 percent of dividend earnings from resident corporations. West German shareholders may claim a tax credit for 55 percent of all dividends, while Japanese taxpayers may exclude the first 100,000 yen in dividend income from a Japanese corporation. 0 The Leverage Effect Foreign corporations benefit from a close and longstanding .relationship with lending institutions which results not only in relatively low risk premiums but more importantly in an assured supply of funds. These tendencies are strengthened in France by direct government lending and in Japan by commercial banks' confidence that they have little to risk in lending to firms targeted by Tokyo for expansion. Rapid corporate expansion in the 1960s and early 1970s, facilitated by the close relationiship between banking and industry, has led to high debt-to-equity ratios. In Japan the ratio of borrowed money to equity is, on average, 2 to 1 compared with a 1 to 2 ratio in the United States (see figure 2). The financial benefits to leveraging are significant. Interest on borrowed capital is a tax-deductible business expense whereas dividend payments--the return on equity-capital ar.e taxed as part of corporate earnings. The impact is particularly great in the United States where distributed income is taxed at normal corporate rates. In Japan, France, and West Germany the advantages of leveraging are reduced to some extent by tax breaks on distributed income which were enacted to avoid double taxation of dividend income. Implications for the United States Firms paying relatively low capital costs have a distinct advantage in the international marketplace.. First, they can undertake investments that their competitors would consider unprofitable. Second, when these firms go head to head against firms facing higher capital costs, they can price output at levels that would not be profitable for competitors or, by pricing at the competitor's level, derive a superior return on investment. The US disadvantage in capital costs, in conjunction with a greater uncertainty about capital availability, may well serve to reduce the willingness or ability of US corporations to engage in anticipatory or rapid capacity expansion or other high-risk LIMITED OFFICIAL USE Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84B0l072R000300020023-0 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84B01072R000300020023-0 investment. At the margin, it would seem to be easier for non-US firms, which are far less reliant on equity capital and thus less subject to short-term investor pressures, to undertake investments with below-cost-of-capital returns. US firms would tend to be downgraded by the investor ratings services, thus raising capital costs and thinning out the supply of capital. The crunch caused by high financing costs in the United States will be particularly acute over the next year. Lenders are still demanding a large premium for their money. Moreover, with inflation headed downward, corporations cannot count on the ability to raise product prices in the future to offset high nominal financial costs. Hence, the uncertainty of investing is particularly great. In Japan, on the other hand, the relatively even inflation and cost-of-capital performance provides a much more certain environment for investment in either new product development or improved facilities. International differences in the availability and cost of capital to corporations may prove crucial in high-technology industries, where substantial benefits accrue to firms able to undertake rapid anticipatory expansion and thus experience decreasing costs as production increases. Rapid expansion enables a firm to obtain a. lower cost, higher profit position .than competitors. Once a lead is established in an industry, the leading firm tends to increase its lead through the rapid generation of funds for additional investment. In the past, US corporations could count on superior production. technology to shelter their market from foreign competition. Under these circumstances, they could be relatively assured of demand despite the profit margins needed to cover their relatively high cost of capital. In recent years, however, US technological advantages in key markets have been eroded by foreign competitors, principally Japanese firms. As a result, competition has become increasingly characterized by aggressive pricing and the ability to meet tight delivery schedules. Higher capital costs substantially disadvantage US firms under these conditions and in some cases, may lead to the surrender of key markets to foreign competitors. Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84B01072R000300020023-0 DEBT/EQUITY RATIO IN 1979 Legend ? EQUITY HOLDINGS = SHORT-TERM DEBT ? LONG-TERM DEBT WEST GERMANY JAPAN UNITED NOTE: FRENCH DATA FOR 1978 FRANCE STATES Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84B01072R000300020023-0 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 APPENDIX A THE AVERAGE WEIGHTED COST OF CAPITAL: A METHODOLOGY The cost of capital is defined in this paper as the minimum rate of return management should realize in order to properly compensate investors--both debt holders and shareholders--for the risks they undertake by investing in an enterprise. This cost of capital concept does not refer solely to the external financing costs for specific projects. It incorporates the opportunity cost of using funds from all sources--external or internal. The assumption is that all funds can be priced the same as the next dollar of capital raised in the market. In order to avoid Qonfusingtthe merits of an investment with the manner in which it is financed, a weighted average cost of capital is used in decisionmaking. This ation is made, in turn, by weighting the cost of each component--short-term debt, long-term debt, equity--by the proportion of each in ttre total capital structure. It is assumed that a fi-rm's debt/equity proportions will remain the same as it generates additional capital. A balance sheet for manufacturing was used to analyze the cost of capital for. industry as a whole. US balance sheet data were taken from US Department of Commerce figures aggregated by industrial sector. Japanese data were taken from Ministry of Finance compilations. French data, based on surveys of 500 manufacturing enterprises, were compiled for the OECD Financial Statistics series. West German figures, based on sample data from 45,000 firms, were also published in the OECD Financial Statistics. LIMITED OFF ICAL USE 1 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84B01072R000300020023-0 The average weighted cost of capital for the manufacturing sectors in each of the Big Four was calculated using the following equation: Ck = Ki (1 - T) B + Ke S B + S B + S Ki = Pretax cost of debt K = Cost of Equity Be = Value of debt S = Value of equity T = Marginal tax rate Value of Debt (B) Traditional analysis of capital costs regards the value of bonds outstanding as a proxy for total debt. We have expanded this definition to account for the growing importance of short- term bank and other money market funding as a source of capital among US corporations and the traditional heavy reliance on bank debt in the three foreign countries. The value of debt used in our calculations thus consists of the balance sheet-totals for short-term bank debt and long-term debt, including bonds. The short-term figures exclude accounts payable, which are an essentially costless form of short-term credit. Pretax Cost of Debt (Ki) The pretax cost of debt is the finance charge associated with the issuance of bonds or the drawing down of bank credit. Each type of debt has its own cost, depending on term, money market conditions, and other factors. An attempt was made to use interest rates that are comparable among the four countries and that reflect rates close to the actual charge on each type of debt. Data on exact rates charged on business loans are not published, but base rate figures are available for short-term (under one year) and long-term conmercial lending and industrial bonds. The various interest rates--in each case annual averages of daily rates-- were blended into composite debt costs for each country, based on the weighted average of the term segments making up total debt as compiled from the balance sheet data. o For Japanese debt costs, the short-term standard rate of interest and long-term top priority lending rate were applied to the two categories of debt. The standard LIMITED OFFICAL USE 2 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 LIMITED OFFICAL USE rate is the rate for the discount of first-class bills. It is regarded as the representative indicator of interest rates for short-term bank loans. The top priority lending rate for loans granted to Japan's basic industries is determined by agreement between Japan's long-term credit banks and the Federation of -Banker's Associations of Japan . It 1is, in effect, the basic rate for long-term bank loans.- o The French and West German short- and long-term charges are commercial bank lending rates as published by the central banks. Since the early 1970s, industrial bonds have lost much of their importance as an instrument for long-term borrowing by German enterprises. They have been largely replaced by loans against borrower's notes (Schuldscheindarlehen). Likewise in France, industrial bonds do not constitute a significant part of total long-term debt. o For the United States, the commercial bank prime rate is used as a proxy for short-term costs. Since most US long-,term debt is bond financed, the 10-year rate for triple-A industrial bonds was used as a proxy for long-term debt costs. Value of Equity (S) Equity consists of share capital and corporate funds held in reserve to cover anticipated future expenses and to protect against potential business losses. Yearend equity values for French and West German manufacturing firms were taken from central bank data; Japanese yearend equity values for manufacturing firms are published by the Ministry of Finance in its Quarterly Bulletin of Financial Statistics. US equity figures were taken from Department of Commerce data. 1/ A bond rate was not used, since bonds were a negligible source of funding over the period 1971-81 as a whole. Although now growing rapidly, the market for industrial bonds in Japan is not yet large enough to meet a significant share of demand for long-term financing. Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 Cost of Equity (Ke) The cost of equity is defined as the minimum after-tax rate of return that must be earned from an investment to compensate shareholders for business and financial risk. The commonly accepted method for estimating equity cost is to add the sum estimated for risk elements to an interest charge that represents compensation for an investment carrying virtually no risk. Risk-Free Rate The proxy for the theoretical risk-free rate in all four countries is assumed to be the issue rate for long-term central government bonds. An alternative would be secondary market yields on central government bonds. The difference between issue and secondary yields on central government bonds in the four countries has, for the most part, averaged under 1 percentage point in'the past 15 years, with some .widening in recent years. Because of the uncertainty over exactly what constitutes a realistic market ri2sJc-free rate, we chose to use the central-government issue yield.- Risk Premium Holding common stocks entails risk, because the actual return may differ from what is expected. This risk premium is generated from two components; a "market risk" premium which compensates investors for the underlying variability in returns associated with holding- stocks in general and a "corporate risk" premium which accounts for the variability in earnings of any given firm in comparison with the stock market as a whole. For the United States, we determined a market 3~isk premium from the results of a University of Chicago study.- The study 21 It has been argued that, because of the thin, undeveloped nature of bond markets in Japan and Western Europe, as well as government manipulation of public sec.urities issues, the issue rates do not fully reflect market forces. For example, a recent Chase Manhattan Bank study comparing US and Japanese electronics firms used the more widely traded Nippon Telephone and Telegraph (NTT) issue .rates as more closely reflecting market-determined costs of a relatively."riskless" instrument. In Japan, NTT issue rates substantially exceed (often by 2-3 percentage points) those either category of central government rates. - Ibbotson and Sinquefield, "Stocks, Bonds, Bills and Inflation: Year by Year Historical Patterns, 1962-1974", The Journal of Business, January, 1976. Updated periodically. Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 LIMITED OFFICAL USE examined the rates of return earned - on investments in long-term US Treasury bonds and compared them with Standard and Poor's 500 Stock Index from 1925-1979. The average annual return on the Standard & Poor index was found to be 5.9 percentage points greater than the risk-free rate as approximated by government bond yields. We assumed that this premium (which was rounded to 6 percent) represents the market risk demanded by investors. We applied this methodology to determine the market risk premiums in Japan (9.7 percent), France (5.0 percent), and West Germany (3.0 percent).. In each case long-term series for annual changes in common stock prices and dividend yields were sunmed and the average long-term central government bond rates for the years 1951-81 subtracted to derive proxies for market risk premiums. A further risk premium is demanded by investors to account for the variability in earnings for any single firm. In order to quantify this additional charge, risk indices, or betas--the ratio of the volatility of the common stock to the volatility of the market as a whole--are calculated for every common stock. Multiplying the market risk premium by its beta will yield an estimated additional cost to compensate for the risk associated with a specific investment. Thus, the risk-free rate, plus the market risk premium times a risk index, yields an estimate of the- cost of equity. The risk premium for the manufacturing sector in each country was subsequently calculated by averaging firm stock-price volatility data (betas) for seven industrial sectors in the United States-11 and deriving an average beta (1.1.1) for these seven sectors to yield a composite investment risk for manufacturing as a whole. In the absence of reliable foreign data, and because studies have shown that stocks within the same industry have fairly highly correlated price fluctuations, the average beta for the United States was used as a proxy for the three foreign premiums as well. Effective Tax Rate (T) The blended cost of debt times its share of total capital, plus the cost of equity times its share of total capital, equals the estimated pre-tax cost of investment capital. To adjust for the effects of the tax deductibility of interest payments, the 4/ Steel, chemicals, petroleum, non-ferrous metals, general machinery, electrical machinery, and transportation equipment. Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 LIMITED OFFICAL USE cost of debt is reduced by the effective tax rate on interest payments. Although specific tax provisions vary among the four countries, corporations generally were subject to an effective tax rate of 50 percent during the period under study. For this reason we used .5 as the marginal rate for all four countries. Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO 1072 R000300020023-0 LIMITED OFFICAL USE ELEMENTS OF THE COST OF CAPITAL The cost of capital as calculated in Appendix A can be subdivided into three principal elements; the risk-free rate of return, the risk premium demanded by investors, and the interest rate savings accruing from the tax deductibility-of interest payments. This presentation provides a framework for understanding the reasons behind international differences in capital costs. The following table shows these various elements for the four countries in 1981: US France West Germany Ja an p Risk-free rate 12.9 16.6 10.5 8.7 Inflation I 9.6 11.6 4.3 2.6 mputed real rate 3.3 - 5.0 6.2 6.1 Risk Premium 6.4 3.5 2.6 4.6 Imputed Leverage -2.7 -5.8 -3.6 -4 1 Effect Cost of Capital 16.6 14.3 9.5 . 9.2 Risk- Free Rate The risk-free rate of capital, determined by issue rates for long-term central government bonds, is assumed to be representative of lender demands for guaranteed returns on investments. In effect, this rate can be viewed as an indicator of the supply, and demand relationships affecting capital markets. The inflationary component of this rate was estimated by applying a six- quarter geometrically distributed lag to national GNP deflators. The derived annual averages are assumed to be proxies for that portion of the risk-free rate which represents investor/lender expectations concerning the future rate of inflation. Other lags may be equally valid, but, unless the distribution were substantially changed, the impact on the results would not be substantial. LILMITED OFFICIAL USE roved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 Approved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BO1072R000300020023-0 The underlying real rate of interest for risk-free capital was imputed by subtracting inflationary expectations from the risk- free rate. The real rate, in theory, represents the result of basic supply and demand factors, including the flow of household and corporate savings and the competition for funds among financial and non-financial institutions, the central -government, and private individuals. The estimates should be regarded as indicative of trends rather than as preci-se numbers. Risk Premium for Business Corporations must pay lenders/inves'tors an additional premium to compensate for the uncertainties attached to business performance and, in particular, the variation in profitability over the business cycle. This "business risk" premium is independent of a firm's "financial risk" which stems from its capital structure, specifically its ratio of debt to equity and the composition of its debt. A 1980 Chase Manhattan Bang financial study of US and Japanese semiconductor firms -// defines business risk as the cost of equity less the financial risk premium.(The netting out-is eequired to compensate for the impact of a firm's debt structure on variables --stock appreciation and dividend payout-- that determine the cost of equity. Interest payments have first claim on corporate earnings. Thus, in bad years, dividend payout may be lower for a firm heavily in debt.) The Imputed Leverage Effect The impact of a firm's debt structure on its overall after- tax capital costs was derived by subtracting the risk-free rate and the estimated premium for business risk from the nominal average weighted cost of capital. The leverage effect is uniformly negative because corporate tax deductions for interest payments lower the effective rate faced by the firm. This benefit is partially offset, however, by the higher nominal rates faced by firms who depend heavily on debt financing. While a direct calculation of the leverage effect is theoretically possible, it would be exceedingly difficult because of the lack of hard information on the structure of and interest payments on outstanding debt and the exact degree of tax breaks provided to the corporation. The imputed leverage effects appear consistent with what would be expected given international differences in coporate reliance on debt financing, tax rates, and nominal interest levels. 11 US and Japanese Semiconductor Industries: A Financial Comparison, 1980. LILMITED OFFICIAL USE roved For Release 2007/03/07: CIA-RDP84BOl072R000300020023-0