SOVIET PLAN FULFULLMENT MID-YEAR 1955

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0
Release Decision: 
RIFPUB
Original Classification: 
S
Document Page Count: 
62
Document Creation Date: 
November 9, 2016
Document Release Date: 
September 2, 1998
Sequence Number: 
1
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
December 30, 1955
Content Type: 
IM
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0.pdf3.5 MB
Body: 
Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001.4 INTELLIGENCE MEMORANDUM SOVIET PLAN I-ULFILLMENT MID-YEAR 1955 CIA/RR IM-422 30 December 1955 WARNING THIS MATERIAL CONTAINS INFORMATION AFFECTING TBE NATIONAL DEFENSE OF THE UNITED STATES WITHIN THE MEANING OF THE ESPIONAGE LAWS, TITLE 18, USCI SECS. 793 AND 794, TBE TRANSMISSION OR REVELATION OF WHICH IN ANY MANNER TO AN UNAUTHORIZED PERSON IS PROHIBITED BY LAW, CENTRAL INTELLIGENCE AGENCY Office of Research and Reports Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T CONTENTS Summary and Conclusions . (WV b ***** ? 4 Page 1 I, Introduction . . . a 4 ? a ,r a 4 0 ? a 4 ? a 4 ? ? 4 4 a 5 II, Industry . 4 ?? 4 *????????? ? 4 a 4 I ? ??? 6 A. Trends in Production a. . IV a all 11 ? 0 4 ? a 4 6 B . Heavy Industry . . . a a V* 4 a V V a ** %a V $ 11 ? 4164,? ? 1. Basic Material and Service Inputs. a 11 2. Engineering Industries .....?. ,? . . 17 C. Light Industry If ? M gh t aV a 4 a 4 23 Capital Investment ? . 4. 24 IV. Industrial Labor Force and Labor Productivity . 4 *a .27 A. Current Trends . . . . . . . . . . ? ,?? r ty 4 ? 27 B. Future Problems and Policies . . . OOOOOOOO 34 V. Cost Reductions and Technological Progress 4 ?Vial 39 A. Cost Reductions and Investment Surplus a V a 4 a W ? 39 B. Efficiency Measures . . . . . . . . . ? . ? 4 4 a? 43 VI. Agriculture ? . a 4 a a 4 a* 4 4 a ? a a W. 4 a ? ? a a 4 45 VII. Trade and Consumption . 4 4 IF t? 4 Vaal 4 ? 47 A. Trends in Retail Trade . . . . OW *VW 47 B. Trends in Consumption Availabilities from Production 4 4 a 4 444 4 ? ? ? 4 ? ??? 49 C. Investment in Trade Activities a * 4 V 4 ? 4 $ 50 S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 VIII. Transport . . A. B. S-E-C-R-E-T Trends in Goods Haulage . ?????????? Transport Investment . . . ? . ? Source References . . 1. Increases in Gross 1951-5 . Appendix alas ........ I Tables * U * Industrial Production in the USSR, 4f 9 4?110 2, Cumulative Indexes 1952-5 0 4 4. Ir?ai I VII ea of Industrial Production in the USSR, ....... 4 3. Increases in Production of Selected Basic Industrial. Materiels in the USSR, 1951-55 . ea ??? ? a a * ? 4. Increases in Production of Selected Industrial in the USSR, 1951-55 . . ... .. 5. Volume end Financing of Capital Inves 1951-5 End Items 4 ??? U S I I 0- ent in the USSR, ?14aaaama I jt 45,0554. 6. Annual Increases in the Productivity. Labor in the USSR, 1951-55 . . Construction I II I ? N S a.* Increases in the Industrial Labor Force and of Industrial Labor Productivity in the USSR, 1951-55 . .... ? . 8. Indexes of Labor Productivity in Selected Industries in the USER, 1940 and. 1954. ? ?9??? ..... - iv - S -E-C -R-E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA a Page 51 51 53 55 7 9 12 18 26 29 31 RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S -E-C -R -E -T Page 9. Comparative Indexes of Average Output per Worker in Selected Ferrous Metallurgical Plants in the USSR; 1954 . . . ???????#1??#????[#?## 34 10. Nonagricultural Employment in the USSR, 19.6-6O . ? ?? 35 11. Total Labor Force in the USSR, 1950 to 1 January 1956 36 12. Reduction in the Total Cost of Industrial Production in the USSR, 1951-55 ? . ? ? ? ? ? 4 al ? 4 4 4. ? 4o 13. Trends in the Formation and Use of the State Surplus in the USSR, 1950-55 ? ? ea ? ? 4 ????al 4 4 42 14. Turnover Tax as a Proportion of State Surplus in the USSR, 1950-55 . ? . . . . ? . . ? . 42 15. Trends in the Improvement of Production Efficiency in Certain Key Industries in the USSR, 1951-55 44 16. Trends in Retail Trade Tux-mover in the USSR . . ? 4 48 17. Trends in Availability of Consumer Goods from Current Production in the USSR , ? 40 4 4.? ...... 4. 50 18. Trends in Transport Activity in the USSR . . . . 52 19. Trends in Production of Transport Rolling Stock in the T.TSSI10 Mulf 4 IP UP** ? 11- 4 0 aP 4 54 - v - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 CIA/RR IM4i-22 (ORR Project 1)-i-838) S-E-C-R-E-T SOVIET PLAN FULFILLMENT* MID-YEAR 1955 Summary and Conclusions Soviet economicprogress should be assessed, for intelligence purposes, from two divergent points of view that of the Soviet leaders and that of the great mass of Soviet citizens. If the pro- gress of the Soviet economy at mid-1955 is assessed from the point of view .of the Soviet leaders, it must be concluded that they had. better reason than the Soviet citizen to be pleased with the improved. per- formance of the Soviet economy since the end of 1954. Gross industrial production already had exceeded (in May 1955) the original Fifth .Five Year Plan (1951-55) goals and was running well .ahead of the very conservative increase planned for 1955. The volume of investment increased substantially and assured a slight overfulfillment .of the plan. -Both these developments suggest that changes in. industrial organization and planning over the past 2 years were successful. -Production of coal, petroleum, steel, and. electrical energy is rapidly approaching the levels which Stalin designated in. his 1946 election speech as the material basis for Communism and should reach most of these goals in 10 to 13 years instead of the 15 to 20 years which Stalin thought would be required. A nuMber of immediate problems, however, still persist. Many of ' the top-priority industries will slightly exceed the 5-year targets but only by straining capacity to the utmost without the slack that has usually been available for above-plan production at the end of a. plan Period. Considerable excess purchasing power remains in the hands of consumers, and the whole wage structure must be overhauled. Agri- cultural production is still lagging and has necessitated the diversion of labor from industry to agriculture. The investment plan for the * The estimates an& conclusions contained in this memorandum repre- sent the best judgment of ORB as of 1 November 1955. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E 1951-55 neriod will be achieved, but because of inefficient construction., the cost of the program will be considerably higher than anticipated. Although there has been considerable iiprovement in construction labor productivity thus far in 1955, the hig cost of construction remains one of the most serious chronic prob1exis in the Soviet economy, Cost reductions in industry were slightly b hind. the plan on the whole. .The volume of rail transport increased in the first half of 1955 but the original 1955 goals already had been e_ceeded in 1954. This overful- fillment resulted from longer-than-pla ned length of haul for fuel, timber, and other basic materials rath r than from the early completion of over-all production plans. The ec9omy as a whole reflected not only the stresses and strains incurred by the "great projects" and by logistical support of the Korean. War (1949-52) but also the diffi- culties encountered in .launching and implementing the post-Stalin con- sumer goods program. The :?rincipal long-range problem facing the Soviet leadership on the eve of the Sixth Five Year Plan (1956-60) is a lagging agricultural production. In addition, the leadership faces serious problems in the slow rates of growth of labor productivity and of saving to support. state irriestments. These problems are closely interdependent, and with the maturation of the Soviet economy, the solution to each problem is more dependent upon success in the other two than in the 1928-50 period. Expansion of agricultural production ie essential to provide more quality foodstuffs for industrial worker -incentives, to continue to provide an important contribution to investment, and eventually to resume the transfer of labor from the agricul ural to the industrial sector. ,Current policies designed to increase gricultural production combine both the carrot and the stick -- on th one hand, increased incentive and concessions to the peasantry and m re local authority in production planning and, on the other, increased authority of the machine tractor stations, increased obligations for deliveries to the state, and the assignment of 30,000 Party technicians of urban origin as collective farm chairmen. Agricultural production!, however, is not particularly responsive in the short run to changes in investment priorities and administrative reorganization. Here tIr Soviet .leaders are faced with the traditional peasant resentment against the regimsa the depletion of human resources in the villages bequeathed to them by Stalin, their own ideology which forbids any retreat from the collective farm system, - 2 - S-E-C-R-E-p Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T and the innate characteristics of agricultural production, where the human and physical environment is much less subject to control and manipulation than in the factories. Although some improvement in ag- ricultural production can be anticipated during the period 1956-60 it very probably will be less than planned and less than required to achieve the other objectives of the leaders. For the first time since 1928 the Soviet leadership must rely pri- marily on increased productivity per worker in order to obtain most of the planned increases in industrial production during the period 1956-60; because an expansion of the labor force will provide only about 25 percent of the increase in production instead of about 50 percent as in the past. The leadership realizes that if lagging out- put per worker endangers the production goals during the next 3 to 5 years, agriculture no longer can provide a pool of surplus labor from which the industrial labor force can be increased in compensation. Four important measures are being taken to increase output per worker: excess purchasing power is being reduced SO that the incentive effects of consumer goods are not negated by the Soviet variety of inflation, the supply of quality foodstuffs and, clothing is being increased, the system of worker output-quotas ("norms") is being revised upward, and a rapid expansion in the quantity and quality of capital equipment available to each worker is planned. In order to finance the flow of capital equipment required to continue the rapid expansion of industrial production, it is necessary to reverse the recent trend of savings mobilized by the state. The growth of state savings will be facilitated if the reduction in the growth of purchasing power and the reform of the wage system insure that in the future (unlike the period 1952-54) the state receives more from the workers each year in the form of increased productivity than it in turn pays to the worker S in the form of increased wages. Mil- itary requirements will continue to be a serious drain on resources which otherwise would be available for investment, and the current Soviet peace campaign probably is in part a direct consequence of the leadership's desire to keep the increase in defense expenditures to a minimum during the period 1956-60. Higher profits made possible by cost reductions throughout the industrial sector will continue to be an important source of savings; but it is unlikely that the pro,- portion of increased profits derived from this source could be much higher in the future than in the past. - 3 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Whereas maintaining high rates of inv stment may be more difficult in the future, the Soviet leadership anti ipates that recent develop- ments in technology will provide some ipijovement in output per unit of new investment during the next 5 years las compared with the period 1950-55, when capital expenditures required for an additional unit of output were increasing in a number Of key industries. This expectation probably wi:.1 prove overoptimistic, however, inasmuch as declining output per unit of new investment appears to be normal as the ratio of capital to :.abor increases. At the same lime, current ideologidal objectives, which neglect the efficiency qf unskilled labor relative tpr madhiner:r and highly skilled labor in some production processes, are i3k certain extent incompatible with the need to get more procluctlori. from a given amount of investment. If the performance of the Soviet econrny is now assessed from the point of view of the Soviet masses, it cartbe concluded that the mater- ial well-beng of the Soviet citizen continued to improve during 1955 but that expectations for the future were subject to more conflicting currents than at the end of 1954. ',This will undoubtedly be the best year for the Soviet consumer since the onset Of forced industrializa- tion and collectivization in 1928; but th more immediate personal needs of the ordinary citizen were far fran satisfied. Although pro- duction of manufactured consumer goods co tinued to increase in the first half of 1955, only a very small num er of Soviet households could afford to buy many of the luxury consumer goods; such as auto- mobiles or television sets. .Increased production of textiles, pots. and pans, footwear, and furniture benefited the broad masses of the population; but these items remained relatively expensive and low in quality. Many consumers had the desire and the mines to purchase larger quantities of less expensive goods Which are in short supply, particularly quality foodstuffs (meat and dairy products and vege- tables) and housing. But queues were sti41 chronic and long. Con- sequently, ea-though the increase in the strate loan and the failure to reduce retail prices* have prevented the *mai increase in the size and purchasing power of the take-home pay bf the Soviet citizen, his morale probably has been little affected; because the consumers still have more rubles available than can be spent on the things most desired. * Price rebactions on a few luxury items rand aluminum cookware were announced in July, but this reduction was in no way comparable to the annual price reductions of the previous 7 rears. - 4 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E7C-RE-T Any hopes that the Soviet economy would shift its orientation from investment to consumption in the immediate future has been exploded during the past 6 months. However, the new agricultural program, the continued substantial increase in consumer goods products, and the emphasis on better housing leave no doubt in the mind of the Soviet citizen that the present leadership accords consumption much higher priority than did Stalin. Social discipline was tightened a little in the beginning of 1955, but this was directed at improving effi- ciency in production and lacked the punitive characteristics of the Stalin era. On the whole, the bonds remain loosened, and there are some signs of further relaxation in some areas. ? The expectations of the Soviet citizen for the next 5 .years are also favorably affected by the stress on technological progress and on the elimination of the distinction between mental and physical labor, which means that more and more Soviet citizens will be engineers; tech- niciansvand highly Skilled workers, thereby escaping the illiteracy and manual labor of the past.. Last but not least, the slight relaxa- tion of international tensions during 1955 not only should reduce the popular fear of war but also should raise the ordinary citizen's hopes of a slightly more favorable distribution of the social product in the future. On the whole, the Soviet leadership currently is exhibiting a more realistic, rational, and flexible approach to the economic problems confronting them and somewhat greater concern for the economic lot of the ordinary citizen than was characteristic of Stalin. I. Introduction. ? In February 1955; Malenkov "requested' his release from the post of Premier on the grounds of errorand incompetence in the administration of the economy of the USSR. With the appointment of Bulganin as Premier the vast propaganda machine did an about-face -- a jDovc -- reemphasizing the preeminence of heavy industry and the subordination -5- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 of light industry in the Soviet pattern o growth. A number of econt-, ?mists who had assumed or argued that the USSR had made a basic, permanent change in economic policy and that consumption rather than investment was to become the end of econo*c activity in the USSR were severe4 criticized. The plan fulfiZIment results for the first half of 195!;* provide an opportunity to evaluate the impact of these events on the Soviet economy and to de-terrine whether the pattern of resource alLocations has changed. Along w:_th the release of the plan fulfillment data, Bulganin de- livered .a detailed report on industry to a plenum of theCentral Com- mittee of the Communist Party of the USSR. The substance of Bulganin's report had been largely foreshadowed in a numbEr Of articles Which appeared in the theoretical journals during the second cLuarter of 1955. .Taken together, this body of information rrovides the basis for a fairly.compLete evaluation of the Soviet economy immediately preceding the Sixth F:.ve Year Plan (1956.-60). The rincipal objectives of this memorandum, therefore, are to relate actu 1 achievements to planned goals, to indicate the principal problems facing Soviet planners for the next 5-year period, and to outline some of the basic: policies which will Letermlne the growth pattern of the economy in the Sixth Five Year Plan. II. Industry. A. .Trends in-Production. During the first half of 1955, in atrial production in the USSR not only exceeded the original (1952) 5-year goals but also in- creased at a rate which will exceed the planned level of production announced in 1955, when the goals were reVised upward in view of the imminent achievement of the original objectives. -Total industrial pro- duction as well as the production of heavy and light industry grew considerably faster than the rates planned for 1955, which were much lower than at any other time in the post-World War II period (see Table 1**). If the actual rates Of growth of the first half Of1955are projected-to the end of the yearj.the resu4t in terms of the cumulative growth of industrial production is as shoi in Table 2.40E* * Unless otherwise stated, the base period for all percentage changes reported in this memorandum for the first half of 1955 is the first half of 1954. ** Table 1 follows on p. 7. -*** 'Table 2 follows on p. 9. - 6 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 1 Increases in Gross Industrial Production in the USSR 1951-55 a/ Percent Increase over Previous Year 1955 First Half 1951 1952 1953 1954 (Plan) of 1955 Total production 17 11 12 13 9 12 Producer goods 17 (12) 12/ (12) (13) 11 (13) 2/ Consumer goods 16 11 13 (12) (6) (10) 2/ a. Data contained herein are from yearly plan fulfillment reports and from Bulganin's speech to the 1955 Supreme Soviet. 1/ (For ser- ially numbered source references, seethe Appendix.) Although the weighting system employed is unknown, ,Soviet statistics on gross in- dustrial production provide a rough measure of the direction and mag- nitude of change. Moreover, these statistics are useful because they represent one of the principal yardsticks by which economic growth is planned and measured in the USSR. For a detailed comment on some of the problems of rounding and internal consistency encountered in these statistics; see source 2/. b. Parentheses denote interpolation. c. Only the rate of growth of total production -- 12 percent -, was reported in the plan fulfillment report. The interpolated rates of growth for producer and consumer goods are consistent with the 7 to 3 ratio Of weights given in Soviet sources. A number of pairs of rates are, of course, consistent with a 12-percent increase in total production. Rates of growth of 13 percent for producer- goods and 10 percent for consumer goods are estimated for the following reasons: (1) the increase in consumer goods production in 1955 would be at least as large as the increase in trade turnover, :which was reported as 8 percent, because inventories and stockpiles were depleted in previous years and probably are being replenished in 1955, and (2) the data on the increase in the sales of various consumer goods - 7 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 1 Inc:?eases in Gross Industrial Pro" 1951-55 a/ (Continued) uction in the -USSR indicate that the rate of increase in conSumer goods available to the population declined about 15 percent in the first 6 months of 1955, as compared with the rate of increase in 1954, which is consistent with a decl:Lne in the rate of growth of consumer goods production from 12 percent in 1954 to 10 percent during the first 6 months of 1955. These achievements suggest that t e changes in organization and planning and the emphasis upon the introdi4ction of new technology al- ready have had some effect, unless Bulganin purposely underestimated the capabilty of the economy in February It was believed at that time that the low rates of growth planned for 1955 represented the de- sire of the regime to ease temporarily th strain on the economy in order to provide a more firm and flexible base for the Sixth Five Year Plan. In Nt.ew of subsequent developments, however, this hypothes&s appears unlkely. There remaineeveral alternative explanations for the low rates of growth -planned for 1955: .(1) Bulganin stated a con- servative estimate pending the implements ion of changes in organiza- tion and planning, (2) Bulganin purposely underestimated the capa- bilities of the economy as part of the prcipaganda campaign to dampen popular expectations of a rapid improvemeAt in the standard of living, or (3) Bulganin and his planners errei seriously in their estimate of immediate production prospects. Despite current successes, the Fifth Five Year Plan (1951-55) will not exceed the original estimates as much as did the results of the Fourth Five Year Plan (1946-50). The iFifth Five Year Plan, however, was somewha-; more ambitious than the Fourth Five Year Plan, and it did not have the benefit of quick returns from reconstruction and recon- version. In the Fourth Five Year Plan, however, the planned growth of industrial production (1950 over 1940),waEi exceeded substantially the actual reported increase of 73 percent in contrast to the 48-Per- cent increase planned. On the other hand, production of consumer - 8 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T > > 73 73 73 Table 2 73 3 3 < < M Cumulative Indexes of Industrial Production in the USSR a/ M CL _ CL 1952-55 nn nn o o -1 1950 = 100 -1 Pp Pp CD m ET First Half of 1955 ET m Original 1952 Goals Revised 1955 Projected to the End M O 0 M (Reached 1 May 1955) Goals of the Year M -a -a CD CD CD Total industrial production 174 180 185 a, CD CD 8 8 CD Producer goods 180 184 187 CD is-3 Consumer goods 160 172 177 is-3 _& _& .. .. C) a. Original goals are from the Fifth Five Year Plan directives; revised 1955 goals are as 0 > stated by Bulganin in July 1955. 3/ The index of 172 for consumer goods represents an up- > 33 ward revision from the index of 171 given by Bulganin in his speech to the Supreme Soviet 33 0 in February. 4/ Bulganin also stated in July that the original goal for consumer goods was 0 17, 165 instead of the index of 160 previously used by Soviet leaders. The projected end-of- 1:I --.1 --1 CD the-year indexes are derived from Table 12 p. 72 above. to ?I ?I 0 0 0 0 CD CD 04 04 cri cri > > 0 0 0 0 0 0 04 04 0 0 0 0 IV IV CDCD 0 0 0 0 0 0 -a -a CD CD - 9 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T goods fell far short of the Fourth Five Y9ar Plan goa1s1:whereas in the current plan the original goals will be substantially exceeded. .The cumulative (1951-55) goal for consumer goods under the Malenkov program was never published, but it is estimated that the 1955 index would have been between 180 an4 185 (for comparison, see Table 2*). The Malenkov program, however, was dependent upon un- realistic goals for agricultural production. .Foodstuffs alone, for example, account for nearly 55 percent of state retail trade. By the end of 1954 it was apparent to the USSR tl4at it could not meet the planned goals and that temporary expedien s were nearly exhausted. In the meantime, consumer purchasing power, *Which already had exceeded the available supply of goods at the beginnin of the "new coursehad-ex- panded too rapidly as a result of the reduction in the state loan?,the retail price reductions, and the concessicins to the peasantry in taxes and procurenent prices. Moreover, the propaganda campaign associated with the Malenkov program raised popular expectations to unjustified levels. Several Soviet writers in the official 'journals even went to far as to sEq that the period of forced industrialization was over-and that, in the future, individual consumptiOn rather than heavy indus- trial growth would be the end object of economic activity in the USSR. There is no evidence that Malenkov concurred (although the planned rates of growth for 195).. and 1955 may have been a little higher for light industry than for heavy industry in order to rectify the past "disproportion"), but these ideas apprently were widespread. The USSR presently is undertaaing h long-range program to in- crease production of quality foodstuffs ard to provide more living space. At the same time an end has been put to speculation that there has been a revolutionary change in economic policy. The policy in- novations of 1955 reflect not a reversion to Stalin's policy but an adjustment in the light of 2 years' experi.1enc. Both the Malenkov program and the current programs are basedj upon the implicit assump- tion that consumption) which is in effect treated as a cost of pro- duction to the state, must be increased across the board in order to provide -incentives for increased labor productivity. * ic 9. above. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 If Bulganings report can be taken as a guide, the pattern of growth of industrial production in the Sixth Five Year Plan will remain approximately the same as in the past. Heavy industry will continue to expand faster than light industry -- that is, the yearly rate of growth of the former probably will be planned at 2 or 3 percent above the latter; but consumer goods production will continue to receive much higher priority than under Stalin. ,Within heavy industry the so- called 'pleading links" -- coal; petroleum; metallurgy; and electric power -- will continue to receive high priority. The yearly production of 60 million tons of petroleum, 500 million tons of coal, 50 million tons of pig iron, 60 million tons of steel, and 250 billion kilowatt- hours (kwh), which Stalin in 1946 defined as the point of departure for Communism and which he expected to require three mr more Five Year Plans to attain) will be exceeded or closely approximated by 1960. In- deed, petroleum production will have reached Stalin's goal by the end of 1955. B. Heavy Industry. 1. Basic Material and Service Inputs. In the first half of 1955 the rates of growth in the "lead- ing links" coal; petroleum; metallurgy, electric power -- generally were higher than in 1954; and consequently the Five Year Plan goals for these industries generally will be exceeded by a small margin. This is a reversal of the trend evident at the end of 19541:when it appeared that a number of these top-priority industries would barely reach, and in some cases would even fall short of, the 1955 production goals (see Table 3*). Throughout the post-World War II period these industries received 4 proportionately larger share of available resources than in the prewar period. In 1948-49 there occurred a marked shift in in- vestment allocations in favor of these industries, and a further shift was made in the Fifth Five :Year Plan. ,As a result of this emphasis, production goals of the Fourth Five Year Plan for these industries were exceeded substantially; and the goals for the Fifth Five Year Plan (announced in 1952) required further growth at very rapid rates, despite the already expanded base to which the increases would apply. For example, the plan called for a 62-percent increase in production * Table 3 follows on p. 12. SE-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 3 > 73 73 3 < cr, a -n o -1 Pp (t, ET a) cf) _& CD CDCD CD 8 CD _& .. C) > Increases Industrial Material in Production Increase over of Selected Basic Industrial Materials in the USSR 1951-55 Percent Previous Year First Half of 1955 Planned Increase: 1955 over 1950 Increase Required in 1955 1951 1952 1953 1954 Pig iron Crude steel Rolled steel Zinc Lead Copper Coal Crude petroleum Electric power Caustic soda 14 -I -.,R 15 15 25 14 8 12 14 8 14 10 12 24 17 15 7 12 13 11 9 10 10 13 22 N.A. 6 12 13 15 9 8 9 7 13 5 8 12 11 11 12 lo 11 7 14 14 12 19 12 12 76 62 64 150 170 43 85 80 79 14 8 6 45 34 8 17 11 17 Pp 0 T -..1 CD ?I CD CD CD 04 al > CD CD CD 04 CD CD IV CD CD CD CD -a c Calcined soda Mineral fertilizers Synthetic rubber Cement Bricks Slate Paper 9- 7 20 19 20 27 12 21 8 9 15 19 26 9 IT 9 13 15 12 22 lo -10 16 1 19 13 17 lo 9 21 9 22 13 18 4 84 88 82 120 130 160 46 6 28 22 17 27 14 a/ a. ?Overfulfilled in 1954. - 12 - SE-C-R-E-T c Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 of crude steel and an 85-percent increase in production of crude petro- leum; which may be Contrasted with the comparable. increases of about 35 percent and 10 percent) respectively, planned.on a much smaller base for the 1940-50 period- Despite the high priorities accorded to) and the rapid rates of growth achieved inl these "leading link" industries through- out the post-World War II period). the requirements placed upon them have grown even faster. Thus a Soviet writer recently admitted what had long been suspected -- namely).that the growth of the engineering industries had been inhibited by an insufficient supply of ferrous metals: As is known; the engineering industries have for a. number of years developed at a more rapid rate than the metallurgical industries. -Consequently metals have been constantly in short supply in the engineering industries. .The shortage of metals acted as a brake on the growth of production in the machine building in- dustries) which; nevertheless) continued to expand faster than metallurgy. ,The engineering industries achieved great economies in the use of metal by reduc- ing input quotas and by improving the structure of metal consumption. The weight of new and modernized. machinery has been .continuously reduced without im- pairing the technological parameters... . The objec- tive or the future/ is not only to liquidate scarcity? in the supply of metal to the engineering industries but also to _create a reserve stock.- of metals in order to provide supplemental allocations to machine build- ing enterprises which have overfulfilled. the plan for the more important end items, and for those items which are in short supply. ..5_/ The recentlysinitiated program to increase the use of ferroconcrete structures instead of steel in building is also indicative of the shortage. .Similarly, the emphasis on hydroelectric construction and the recent upward revision of coal production plans both suggest that -13 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA S-E-C-R-E-T RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 energy requirements consistently have been underestimated. Bulganin's report to the Central Committee indicated that the expansion of electric power generation was not sufficietly ahead of the expansion of industry as a whole. g , The generation of electric pow r increased 12 percent in the first half of 1955, and the Fifth Five Year Plan will be slightly exceeded if this tread continues. Because of a serious lag in the production of steam turbines and generators,'however, such success apparently will be at the price of using eXisting equipment to the limit,:with little reserve capacity. It i estimated that the installed electrical generating capacity by the end of 1955 may be as low as 75 percent above 1950 instead of 100 percept as originally planned. The rate of increase of electric power generation probably will be higher in the next 5 years inasmuch aE "electrification" of production' proceSses is to be one of the key factors n :the growth of labor productivity., In the. Sixth Five Year Plan th :USSR is planning to in- crease hydroelectric power as a proportion of the total, principally by the construCtion of a number of extreme y large installations in Siberia. At the same time, a large-scale xpansion of industry in Siberia is being planned for the next 5 or possibly 10 years. Output of petroleum has gone up sharply since the end of 1954, increasing-I9 percent compared with yearly increases of 12 percent for the 1951-54 period. At the end of 1954 it appeared that the original Fifth Five Year Plan goal for petroleum had been revised downward, but the 19-percent increase in the first half of 19551 if maintained, will bring about the achievement of the original Five Year Plan goals. It is possible that a baSic shift in policy regarding the proportion of energy to be derived froth petroleum compared with coal and other fuels occurred in the early part of 1955. Historically, Soviet planners have substituted coal for petroleum on a large scale despite the fact that production costs of petroleum were far less,(on an energy evivalent basis) than for coal +- so much less, in fact, that petroleam products included a turnover tax even to heavy indus- trial consumars. The rationale for disco ting the lower production cost of petroleum is believed to have incl ded several factors: -114- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 (a) the high transportation costs incurred owing to the historical concentration of petroleum production in the Baku area, (b) the vulnerability of the Baku region to attack, and (c) the desire to keep the dependence of the economy on petroleum products at a minimum and thereby provide greater flexibility in an emergency. Recent changes in the location and availability of petroleum deposits may have reduced the importance of these factors and resulted in a de- cision to take advantage of the low cost of petroleum as compared with coal by increasing petroleum's share (currently about 20 percent) in the fuel balance. .The Trans-Volga and southern Urals fields now pro- vide almost 60 percent of the total production of petroleum and apparently are very low-cost producers. -Consequently transportation costs of petroleum now compare much more favorably with those of coal, and the vulnerability of the industry is somewhat reduced. Moreover, the post-Stalin regime shows a greater propensity to take real cost considerations into account when making decisions. .The locational shift in production of petroleum also may be a causal factor in the renewed emphasis on locating new industries in Asiatic USSR and should _add to the general efficiency of the economy by. reducing transport costs. .The rates of increase in output of ferrous metals were somewhat higher in the first half of 1955 than in 1954. In the latter year it appeared.that production of steel would barely reach the 1955 target and, that there would be a significant shortfall in pig iron (see Table 3*). Inasmuch as the short supply of ferrous metals has slowed the growth of the engineering Industries in recent years despite the fact that production goals for finished steel have been met, a considerable expansion of the former industry can be anticipated in the next 5 years. According to Soviet writers, 7/ future increases in production of iron and steel will require a relatively greater invest- ment in new plants and facilities than in the current Five Year Plan, when increased efficiency in the use of existing plants was to provide 25 to 30 percent of the increase in output. A projection of trends in chemical production during the first half of 1955 leads to the conclusion that production of many. chemicals will fall short of the cumulative 1951-55 goals. Production * P. 12, above. -15 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T of caustic soda and synthetic rubber almost certainly will be less than planned. Production of mineral ferti iZers rose sharply (21 percent) during the first half of 1955, an if the 1955 goal of a 24.-percent increase is achieved, .?./ the cumulative growth for the 5-year period will be more than 80 percent (1955 over 1950). Al- though this will be less than the original goal of 88 percent (1955 over 1950), .the result is still impressive and important because of heavy requirements for more mineral fertiltzers in agriculture. The chemical industries are sl ted for rapid expansion in the Sixth Five Year Plan. The broader app.ication of chemical pro- cesses in the economy, the so-called 'chemica1ization of production)" is to be one of the key measures in increaSing labor productivity. The chemical indastries themselves are readily adaptable to automation. Moreover, the high priority accorded to th agricultural sector is reflected in plans to double production of chemical fertilizers in the next 5 years. Judging from the results of the first 6 months, the pro- duction of aluminum at the end of 1955 Slightly exceed the am- bitious planned increase of 160 percent for the 1951-55 period. Apparently this is not enough., however, beause Bulganin singled out the aluminum industry for continued rapid expansion, which probably reflects not only increased requirements for military end items but also the regairements for consumer gocds. Production of other non- ferrous metals, however, is considerably behind the original 5-year plan. Production of copper is especially Lagging, and this metal is known to oe in short supply. Althcugh -n 1954 output of lead was double that Df 1950 and output of zinc was more than 70 percent above the 1950 level, the original 1951-55 plan or these m?isI been abandoned. NTevertheless, it can be inferr d from available Soviet data that th a output of zinc during the fist half of 1955 was running well behind even the new, downwardly revis d plan, increasing only 7 percent over the first half of 1954 comp red with a planned increase for the year of 16.5 percent. On the othe hand, output of lead ex- ceeded the pLanned rate of increase for th year. Pressure for rapid expansion of these industries can be antic pated in the future. Goals for 1960 may be double the 1955 level of oUtput for most nonferrous metals. -16- Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T 2. -Engineering :Industries. During the first half of 1955 the engineering industries continued to expand rapidly,. and the pattern of growth generally fore- shadowed the basic trends planned for the Sixth Five Year Plan, In some instances, however, the rates of growth of machinery production .are far less than the planned rates of growth (see Table 4*) and do not appear consistent _with the growth of the industries which use this machinery. The whole pattern of development of the .engineering industries is considerably different in the Fifth Five Year Plan from that in the Fourth Five Year Plan. From 1946 to 1950, almost everr. major engineering industry had a 1950 goal of from 2 to 4 times the 1940 rate, and much of the increase was to come from new plants in the relatively less industrialized areas of the country. .In the -Fifth Five Year Plan? _many engineering industries had relatively small projected rates of increase -- about 20 percent for the automobile and tractor industry, for. example. On the other hand, those engineering indus- tries which provided the .capital equipment for .the basic metal and energy Industries and for the "great projects" -- the oil and electri- cal equipment industries, for example -- were scheduled for great _expansion 4 In practice, some industries :the locomotive industry, for example -- were so disrupted, by shifts in the product mix during 1949-52 that production declined substantially. The cumulative increase in production of hydroturbines during the .first half of 1955 will exceed 700 percent for the 1951-55 period. -Production of steam turbines, on the other hand, has remained at the same level as the first half of 1954, -although a 33-percent - increase in 1955 is required to meet the Five Year Plan goal. Produc- tion of equipment for the petroleum industry. will be .far behind the Five Year Plan, goal for a 230-percent increase because by the end of 1954 production of petroleum equipment was only 50 percept above the 1950 level.. .Similarly, production of metallurgical .equipment probably is barely above the 1950 level despite the planned- increase of 85 percent (1955 over 1950). -How the USSR is achieving its planned pro.- duction- goals for ferrous metallurgical products and petroleum products without the planned inputs of capital equipment is not known. In any event, production of equipment for these industries. is scheduled to be expanded substantially in the next 5 years. .In ferrous metallurgy, ,in particular ,-a smaller proportion of the increment to production** * -Table follows on p. 18. .** Continued on p. 20. - 17 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R=E-T Table 4 Increases in Production of Selected Industrial End Items in the USSR > > "0 1951-55 "0 "0 -0 a a < Percent < 0 ? cr? a a ILierette over Previoub Year Increase m -n O First Half Planned Increase Required 0 -1 -1 End Item 1951 1952 1953 1954 of 1955 1955 over 1950 in 1955 73 73 CD CD ET Steam turbines 10 8 40 44 130 33 (7 A) Large hydroturbines 145 24 35 82 10 680 0 O Electric locomotives 11 34 7 . 22 N.A. (1) _.% Steam locomotives N.A. N-A, 163 13 -16 N.A. CD CD Freight cars LA. N.A. 3 N.A. 38 N.A. co CD CD Trucks N.A. 11 .11 12 15 CD 8 Passenger cars N.A. 7 30 23 13 49 8 CD CD Antifriction bearings 30 17 15 13 15 N.A. _.% Petroleum equipment LA. 44 17 N.A. N.A. b/ 250 _.% .. Metallurgical cqui--cnt w A 1,1 14.rie _LC. i Q ...., 5 ? _t_ 0,? (.0 0? OU L./ .. 0 0 Metal-cutting machine 4 > ' . tools 3 d/ 14 8 16 LA. 73 Large; heavy, and unique 73 0 0 "0 -_tools .11 26 2/ N.A. "0 "A Chemical equipment 38 28 24 14 5 230 32 CD CD ?I Loons N.A. 39 2 -69 2 LA. ?I a . a Spinning machines N.A. 18 LA. 9 11 N.A. a a CD Tractors N.A. . 7 , .13 22 V .27 68 f/ 14 to ca GI cn Grain combines 15 W,A, 2 LA; :22 N.A. cn > Sugar-beet combines N.A. 19 50 140 75 a N.A. a > a a a a GI * lbotnotes for Table 4:follow on p.19. GI a a a a r..) -18- 0 a a SEC-R-E7T a a a 6 6 > > 73 73 7373 Table 4 3 3 < < M Increases in Production.of Selected Industrial End Items M CL in the USSR a ln 3,951-55 m0 -1 (Con t itued ) - 0 1 Pp Pp m m ET ET a. Overfulfilled in PA 1954, when the cumulative index for the 1951-54 period reached 746. PA M b. Production of petroleum equipment is planned to be only 50 percent above the 1950 level at M -& the end of 1955. 2/ -& CD c... It is estimated that production of metallurgical equipment dropped sharply in 1951 and that CD CD CD CD the index at the end of 1954 (1950 = 100) was approximately 103. VCD 8 d. Ministry of MAChine Tool Industry only. 8 CD CD e. Production of this class of machine tools is planned to be 180 percent over the 1950 level is.3 "by the end of 1955. 10/ " .. .. f. The original goal of a 19-percent increase is believed to be in terns of horsepower, which 0 0 is estimated to be equivalent to about a 40-percent increase in terms of physical units. ..Re- >> 33 vised.goals under the "new course" provided for about a 68-percent increase in physical units, , :which probably will be achieved. 11/ Pp 0 ? 0 1:1 1:1 CO CO ?I ?I c) c) c) c) CO CO G4 G4 C)1 al > > c) c) c) c) c) c) G4 G4 C)C) C) C) IN3 IN3 COCO C) C) C) C) C) C) -& - 19 - -& 4) 4) SE-C-R-ET Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA S-E-C-R-E-T RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 will be deri,red from increased efficiency in the use of existing .ca pacity, and a correspondingly larger proportion from new plants and facilities, than has been the case during the past 5 years. 12/ /L 16-percent increase in production of metal-cutting ma- chine tools was reported for the first half of 1955, and, snore important for the future, .a 67-percent increase in p oduction of forging and pressing equ4ment. Soviet reporting of metalworking machinery in the Fifth Five Year Plan has not been consiste t either in terms of cate- gories or in terms of subordination of the roducing units. It is probably a safe assumption, however, that the 1951-55 goals will be reached. ,The metalworking equipment industry is scheduled .for sub- stantial expansion duringthe -next 5 Years, particularly in the form of more complex, ,automatic machinery, which is to be one of the key factors in increasing labor productivity. Jn1ike the emphasis in the first four Five Year Flans, the main emphasis in machine-tool produc- tion in the 1951-55 period has-been on heavier) more complex tools rather than .on rapid expansion of unit outpUt. At the same time, how- ever, as a heritage of the past, an excessively large proportion of Soviet production has consisted of relative y few models .Which are mass produced at low cost. ,These mass productio models are 3general-purpose tools and are often technologically obsoles ent. Moreover, production of forging and pressing equipment (which is usually far more efficient in producing small metal items that Are req ired in large numbers) has enjoyed lower priority in the past than pro uction of metal-cutting tools. These two factors probably are larg ly responsible for the fact that the USSR requires a machine tool nventory approximately three-fourths that of the US in order to pr cess only about one-third as much metal. In the Sixth Five Year Plan thei dominant trends in the metalworking equipment industries will be ag follows: (a) complex, specia1ized7tools'(with particular emiihabib on groups linked-together to perform a production task automatically) will account for a much larger proportion of production, and (b) production of forging and pressing equipment will continue to expand rapidly. In other words, these industries are to provide the machinery for the automation and mechanization of production processes whichi the Soviet leaders believe will increase labor productivity more rapidLy than in the past few years. -20 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Production of row-crop-type tractors continued to increase rapidly in 1955 and should total at least 63,000 to 65,000 units for the year compared to approximately 70,000 units planned. The probable slight shortfall, however, will be in the most important row-crop model, the "Belorus." Production of heavy, general-purpose tractors (used primarily for small-grain cultivation) has been stable for several years and should be ample to support both the agricultural and industrial sectors during the next 5 years. -Further increases in production of row-crop-type tractors can be anticipated. One of the most marked trends in the first half of 1955 was the sharp increase (see Table 4*) in the production of most types of railroad equipment, an industry which has been in the doldrums during most .of the Fifth -Five Year Plan. Production of steam locomo- tives, which dropped to less than one-third the 1949 level in 1952 when many plants were switched over to producing Capital equipment for ?the leading linksand the great projects, probably regained only. about 75 percent of the 1949 level in 1954 and then dropped about 16 perdent in the first half of 1955. The USSR has, however, a substantial re- serve inventory of older steam locomotives and is currently converting -to the production of new, larger, and more efficient models. -Unit production of steam locomotives will continue to decline in the future as the USSR begins to implement the extensive dieselitation and elec- trification program outlined by Kaganovich in M1d-1954. .The internal evidence in Kaganovich's speech indicates that a comparable program was proposed in one of the original versions of the Fifth Five Year Plan, but it is believed that the program was dropped because of the magnitude of requirements for the great projects, the accelerated ex- pansion of the leading links, and possibly the requirements for logistical support of the Korean War, .If the large increases in production of diesel and electric locomotives reported for the first half of 1955 are indicative of the future, the USSR will have made substantial progress toward dieselization and, electrification of freight hauling on all main lines by 1960. Production of railroad cars,,' which probably was below the 1950 level in 1954, also is in- creasing rapidly. In general, the =results of the first half of 1955 indicate that the major commodity production goals :in the producer goods sector will be fulfilled, Most of the items subject to specific annual. * P. 13777&576-. -21 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : C1A1RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C7R-E-T reporting will barely reach the planned goals, which is in sharp con- trast to the large overfulfillments of the Fourth Five Year Plan. -Even with a slight shortfall in the present plan, -however, the increase in production is impressive because of the larger base (1950 for the Fifth Five Year Plan, 1940 for the Fourth Five Year Plan) and the vir- tual exhaustion .of unusual sources of graw h available during the Fourth :Five Year Plan, such as reconversior and reconstruction, looted capital equipment, and the retention of skilled prisoners of war. .The pattern of growth of the e gineering industries in the Sixth Five Yoar Plan apparently will be mo ie similar to the pattern in the Fourth F:Lve Year Plan than to that in he Fifth Five Year Plan. .Expansion will be general rather than concentrated in only those indus- tries which oontribute directly to the leading links. -The-1951.-55' - period was largely devoted to completing and expanding plants started or reconstructed in the 1946-50 period, and geographic dispersion al- most ceased. It is evident from the data presently available that much new conotruction of engineering industry plants will be initiated in the next years and that a significant part of this new construc- tion will.be in Central Asia and the Far Fast. Concomitantly with this new conotruction? there evidently will be anextensive program to reequip the technologically more -backward and high-cost enterprises. ? Previously the planners had concentrated on getting more production, largely igna7ing the fact that some plants had production costs which were 2 or 3 ..;imes as high as other plants producing the same product, Similarly, .there will be much greater emphasis on specialization .-? that is, on ;educing the range of end item produced by an enterprise. .In the past ;he tendency has been to distribute responsibility for producing a new product among the existing plants rather than to build a new, specialized plant to produce the new product, .Thus the pattern of growth of the engineering industries in the Sikth Five Year Plan, while in many cases more similar to the 1946-504seriod than to the 1951-55 period, will aim at a more rational growth in the interest of the greater over-all efficiency of the economy. -22 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T C. Light Industry. In assessing the growth in production of consumer goods in the USSR, it is necessary to distinguish between those items which are processed agricultural raw materials and those goods which are produced from raw materials of industrial origin. ,This distinction roughly corresponds to the standard categorization of nondurables and durables. The USSR, by shifting distribution priorities and by in- creasing investment allocations, has at various times in the past sub- stantially increased the output of industrial consumer goods in a relatively short time. The situation is quite different, howeverl.if an increase in the output of agricultural raw materials is a prerequisite. Historically (from 1928 to the present), investment in Soviet agriculture has had an almost negligible effect upon agricultural produc- tion. State investment in agriculture (particularly machinery) has facilitated the large-scale migration of labor to the cities and has more than compensated for the disinvestment of collectivization (par- ticularly in the form of animal draft power), but the normal effects of greater capital intensity upon production have been negated by peasant resentment resulting from the low level of peasant income and the political and social pressures applied to the peasantry by Stalin. In the long run it is increased peasant income, relaxation of political pressures, more realistic planning, more fertilizers, and better agro- technology which offer the greatest potential for increasing productivlty in agriculture. In addition, agricultural production depends upon such factors as adequate rainfall and the time required to build up live- stock herds, which makes it very difficult to secure short-run incre- ments to output merely by shifts in distribution priorities and in investment allocations. Output of consumer goods as a whole continued to increase sub- stantially in the first half of 1955, but the estimated rate of growth declined 2 to 3 percent below 1954., .In general, those items which were lagging behind, plan in 1954 have continued to fall short thus far in 1955. .Increases in the production of sewing machines, radios, and television receivers were substantial but still well behind plan. Fr duction of cameras, watches and clocks, and household refrigerators is keeping abreast of the plan. Production of passenger automobiles increased 13 percent despite the fact that the 1955 plan was fulfilled -23 - S-E-C7R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T In 1954. On the other hand, the rates of growth in production of bi- cycles and furniture, which promised to re ch "new course" goals if the 1954 rates were maintained, declined substantially in the first half of 1955, Production of furniture may have been affected by the continued fa:lure of the timber industry tc) meet the production plan. Production of cotton textiles :probeb1y will meet the plan, but production or wool and linen fabrics and.lather goods probably will mot. In general, raw materials are in short sup ly in these industries, with the exception of raw cotton.. Production ir the linen and. silk .indus- tries actual:3r declined slightly in the first half of 1955. Production of leather footwear has definitely been affected by leather shortages, whereas production of rubber footwear shows a satisfactory increase. The most serious production failures continue to be in quality food- stuffs. .The only favorable development in this area was the reported increase of :6 percent in the production of milk products. Although still far behind plan these were the highest rates of growth reported for several years. In the future the bulk of the increase in consumer goods produc- tion will continue to depend upon increased agricultural production, particularly of quality foodstuffs which wi 1 simultaneously provide incentives to the bulk of the population and bsorb the normal increases in mass purchasing power. .The other essential to any substantial im- provement in the standard of living of the more and better housing. .In addition, pro have to increase despite the fact that dura of the populetion. Provision of inceir:ives of engineersj highly paid techniciant, and much higher level of output of television s quality furniture, and even of passenger au III. -Capital investment. The reported 11-percent increase in the ,(measured in 1950 prices) during the first large in viey of the slight reduction fun pl for capital investment (see Table 5*). A c rise for the entire year insure an ove percent in the cumulative 1951-55 plan whi * Table 5 fcllows on p. 25. -24 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA verage Soviet citizen is ction of durables will les are luxuries to the mass for the ever growing class nagers will require a ts, home refrigerators, omobiles. volume of capital investment alf of 1955 is surprisingly nned .budgeted expenditures ntinuation of the 11-0percent fulfillment of 3:to 6 h specified an increase of RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 SE-C-R-E-T Table 5 Volume and. Financing of Capital Investment in the USSR 2/ 1951-55 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 Volume (actual) Increase over preceding year (percent) 112 111 104 115 111 12/ Financing (planned) (Billion 1 July 1950 rubles) 132.0 143.1 156.1 169.0 167.5 As percent of preceding year 97 108 109 108 99 a. Volume of investment refers to the value of essentially completed investment (according to a complex definition of "completion"). ,It is distinct from the financing of investment, which measures current ex- penditures for investment purposes. .b. First.6 months of 1955 only. 90 percent Over the 1946-50 period. It is not known precisely how such a rate of increase in volume was achieved while planned expenditures remained approximately the same, but a number of possibilities exist. .First, actual expenditure for investment in 1954 definitely may have been less than planned, so that planned. expenditures in 1955 actually represent an increase. Second, installation of equipment paid for in previous years but not actually installed. and. the completion of a large number of projects (both of which goals have received much attention in the Soviet press) would make possible an increase in volume without a corresponding increase in expenditures. Finally, inasmuch .as a large number of projects are being pushed to completion this year, the 1955 expenditures for investment may not have included an increase in working capital for construction. -25 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Aside from general statements about th trends, little information on the distribution of investment was rele sed in the 6 months' plan fulfillment :?eport. Increases were specif cally mentioned for certain sectors of heavy industry, for transport, dnd for agriculture. Failure to specify aa increase in investment in 1i4ht industry suggests that investment may have failed below the level of the first 6 months of 1954. Although the amount of housing construction was stated to have increased, omission of the customary volum increase indicates that the rise was less than in other years of t1.e current Five Year Plan. In general, investment in heavy industry, tate agriculture, and housing probably will exceed the 5-year go is for volume increases whereas transport and communications and 1 ght industry probably will fall slightl:r short of the 1951-55 targets The gene:7ally satisfactory quantitativ trends are somewhat offset by the fact 'that the current cost of the pifogram for the 1951-55 period will be higher than anticipated owing to t e failure to reduce con- struction costs as planned and to the lagging growth of labor productiv- ity in constmction. Construction costs were not reduced according to plan in the :7irst half of 1955 -- a failure characteristic of all the previous years of the Fifth Five Year Plan Indeed, official reports indicate tha-; construction costs actually ncreased in 1953. On the other hand, :_abor productivity in construc ion increased 10 percent in the first 6 months of this year, which is he highest rate of increase of the current Five Year Plan (see Table 6). Nevertheless, the Five Table Annual Increases in the Productivity in the USSR 1951-55 of Construction Labor First Half I crease Required 1951 1952 1953 1954 of 1955 in 1955 9.5 7 I. 8 10 -26- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA 17 Percent 1951-55 Goal 55 RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Year Plan for the growth of labor productivity in construction will not be fulfilled, because of the quite unfavorable rates of growth in the earlier years. Soviet data indicate that the 1951-55 investment program probably will exceed. the total cost of the 1946-50 program by about 90 percent rather than the planned 60 percent. The cost of the investment program in the Fourth Five Year Plan also was greater than planned, but the volume goal for that period was exceeded by 22 per- cent compared with the probable .3-to 6-percent overfUlfilIment for the 1951-55 period. .The scale :and pattern of investment in the next 5 years probably will be quite similar to the trendsin the past few years. Consumer- oriented activities -- agriculture; housing, and light industry -- will continue to receive a somewhat larger share of investment funds. Con- siderable new construction will be combined with renewed emphasis upon improving existing plants by introducing more technologically advanced machinery. Thus the investment program in the Sixth Five Year Plam will be a cross between the dominant trends of the Fourth and Fifth Five Year Rlans, Two of the primary determinants of the scale of the 1956-60 investment program are, however, relatively unknown quantities ? namely; the degree to which agricultural production can be increased so as to provide a larger investment surplus, and the competition of the military program for investment resources. IV..Industrial Labor Force and Labor Productivity. A. Current Trends. The last 2 or 3 years mark the passing of the era when Soviet planners could freely milk the agricultural sector of surplus labor in order to meet and exceed industrial production goals when output per man in industry did. not increase as planned, .For the next 5 years at least the dynamics of Soviet economic growth will differ significantly from the past because the industrial labor force can no longer be ex- panded at will. Explicit, and remarkably frank, recognition of this change has recently appeared in the Soviet press, as follows: .The plan for industrial production was overful- filled. for the first four years of the Fifth Five Year Plan despite the fact that the plan- for labor -27 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T :productivity was not achieved or the 1952-54 :period. These results were ac ieved by increas- Lng the number of workers more than planned. In the first half of 1954 th-1. number of work- ers and employees in industryllconstruction and transport increased 1,200,000 n comparison with the first half of 1953. .Such tempo of growth of workers in industry will no be possible in the Sixth Five Year Plan inasm ch as the agri- eultural labor force will have to be increased, and in part by drawing upon th urban population. Already in the first half of 1 54 the number of workers in agriculture (machin tractor stations and state farms) increased by 300,000 over the first half of 1953. Thus in the Sixth Five Year industrial production must corn :productivity of labor to a gre in the Fifth Five Year Plan. workers, are of particular imp industries, which employ the 11 ing labor productivity. 13/ lan the growth in from increased ter degree than he engineering rgest number of rtance in increas- Bulganin said much the same thing in his J ly 1955 report to the Central Committee, and most of the importalit policy decisions of the past 2 years, the agricultural and consume 4 goods programs, the re.- duction in administrative overhead, and thei changes in the planning apparatus have been adopted primarily to i crease labor productivity. The :'ate of growth of labor productivity is important to the Soviet leadership for several reasons. First, in each of the postwar Five Year Plans about 75 percent of the increment to pro- duction was planned to come from increased output per worker, the other 25 percent to be achieved by expanding the labor force. .It should be noted in this context that the USSR classifies the contri- bution of all other factors (land, capital, management) under_the category of labor productivity. Second, the Soviet leaders believe that exceeding the level of labor productivity which exists in the -28- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T capitalist world is a prerequisite for the final victory of their system. Third, it is a principle of Soviet planning that labor pro- ductivity should increase faster than real wages in order to provide the necessary saving for investment and future growth. In other words, what the state gets out of the workers should increase faster than what the state pays to the workers. During the past 4 years the growth of labor productivity has been unsatisfactory on all counts. In order to fulfill production goals in the face of lagging output per worker, the labor force has been increased far more rapidly than planned (see Table 7). Exceeding the planned rate of growth resulted, of course, in a much larger increase in the wage bill than originally was anticipated, which contributed to the growth of excess purchasing power. .The growth of excess purchasing Table 7 .Increases in the Industrial Labor Force and of Industrial Labor Productivity in the USSR 1951-55 Percent Increase over Previous Year First Half of 1955 Planned Increase 1955 over 1950 Increase Required in 1955 1951 1952 1953 1954. Industrial labor force a/ 5 ?4 6 6 4.5 13 lo/ 21 Industrial labor productivity 10 7 6 7 7.0 50 13 a. Derived from Soviet data on increases in industrial output and indus- trial labor productivity which indicate that the Fifth Five Year Plan goal was achieved by the end of 1953. b.? Based on original plan of a 70-percent increase; see Table 1, p. 7, above. Since the output goal has been revised upward, the labor force goal also would be increased somewhat (it is known that the productivity goal was not increased). c. Overfulfilled. Actual increase will be nearly double the planned increment. -29- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T power was aggravated further by the reduct ons in retail prices and in the state loan in 1953-54) while the supplr of consumer goods did not increase commensurately despite the releas s from inventories and re- serves, imports, and the emphasis on consuner goods production in 1953- 54. Explicit recognition of this phenomen n recently appeared in the official press, as follows: Despite the significant incr Df consumer goods) certain imb tween the level of production and the purchasing power of th During the past few years the Df the working population incr than the production of consume 2ome of workers, peasants) int excessively increased by the r tail prices. A larger prcport lation was able to demand high During the postwar years) part and 1954, there was a rapid sh toward higher quality consumer :present time the trade network supply the demand for certain sumer goods, particularly for Justrial products and for food Meanwhile, llbor productivity was not incr and the imbalance between the consumer pur availability of consumer goods was an impo. The net result was that payments of gcods ers was increasing faster than labor produ Soviet statistics, labor productivity incr the 1951-54 :period, whereas real wages inc ase in the supply lances exist be- f consumer goods population. urchasing power ased faster goods. The in- lligentsia was ductions in re- on of the popu- r quality goods. cularly in 1953 ft in mass demand goods. At the is unable to ategories of con- igh quality in- tuffs. 112/ asing according to plan, hasing power and the tant contributing factor. nd services to the work- tivity. According to ased only 33 percent for eased 37 percent. From the point of view of the Soviet leadership) such a relation between these rates )f growth is highly unfavorable because it tends to con- strict the szrplus available for investment and hence the rate of growth of the Soviet economy. -30- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : C1A1RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 SE-C-R-ET Labor productivity has been lagging not only in industry as a whole but also in many of the basic extractive industries, where the rates of growth have been much less than the average (see Table 8), Table 8 Indexes of Labor Productivity in Selected Industries in the USSR 1940 and 1954 1940 1954 .Total industrial labor productivity 200 180 Coal industry 100 120 Timber industry 100 106 Ferrous metallurgy 100 174 Transport 100 131 Indeed, some of the high-priority industries -- coal and timber,* for example -- have the lowest rates of growth in labor productivity despite the heavy capital investment in these industries during the postwar period. '11h.e timber industry, for example, had a fourfold increase in capital stock between 1940 and 1954, but labor productivity increased only 6 percent; and the slow rate of growth of labor productivity in the coal industry persists despite the large investment in modern machinery and facilities, 12/ This suggests that coercion and control techniques are essential factors in the growth of labor productivity in the USSR, since in these two industries, which have been relatively well provided with incentives and capital equipment in recent years but in_which labor cannot be continuously controlled and supervised as in a factory;:the 'relative growth of labor productivity is low, * The high priority of the timber industry, of course, dates only from the end of the Fourth Five Year Plan (about 19)49). -31 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T In _addition to morale factors, there are other important insti- tutional phenomena which are inhibiting the growth of industrial labor productivity, The whole system of labor "norms," or output quotas for various types of workers, is completely oult of date. .The last complete revision was in 1931 and was only partial; despite the tremendous sub- sequent changes in technology, only haphazard adjustments have been made since that time. Premiums and bonusea for exceeding the norms account for nearly one-half the total wage bill. It is probable that the premiums and bonuses are being paid as much to reduce labor turnover as to reward the workers for outstanding levels of productivity. The abuses of the wage system and attendant consequences have recently been stated quite frankly by Soviet writer, as in the following excerpts: The system of premiums which is in force in in- dustry and -transport, because of its deficiencies often leads to the result that in a number of in- dustries and enterprises the w rkers who do the easiest work are the ones who et the premiums. 1?./ The socialist principle of distribution accord- ing to work plays an important role in the raising the technico-cultural level of the workers. It provides a material incentive o each worker not only to increase his oUtput but also to improve his quality. .Consequently the correct application of c the socialist principle of' distribution according to work is a key factor not only in the growth of Labor productivity but also in the technico-cultural Level of the workers. The serious deficiencies of the existing wage rate system, and particularly the output quotas giorms7 in a number of industries, reduce the influence of this most important prin- ciple and damage the naticnal economy. E/ As long as tde industrial lator force could. readily be expanded by transferring labor from agriculture, these deficiencies in the wage 1. system apparently could be disregarded. e overriding objective was to get production. But with the passing o' the era of surplus labor in agriculture the wage system will have tO be reformed. -32- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 v0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-R0P79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Recently Soviet leaders have publicly complained that the growth of labor productivity has been inhibited by the slow tempo of techno- logical progress and by the unsatisfactory dissemination and adaptation of Western technological developments in the Soviet economy. The latter failure is apparently one of the consequences of the "Zhdanovshchina" -- the campaign against "bourgeois cosmopolitanism," against the "kow-towing to the West," against the thought that any one else had discovered any- thing first -- which was launched by Zhdanov in 1947. One of its man- ifestations was the disappearance of news about foreign technological advances from the industrial trade journals. To be sure, superpriority activities such as the atomic energy program undoubtedly were not af- fected, but for the ordinary Soviet industry, for the rank and file of engineers and managers, an important source of knowledge and stimulus was largely eliminated. The gradual reappearance since Stalin's death of discussions of Western technological advances indicates that the desire to speed up technological progress which in turn will tend to increase labor productivity has overcome these ideological inhibitions. The growth of labor productivity is slowed not only by the lagging of technological advance but also by the wide variations in the technology; scale, andmanageriaL efficiency of plants producing the same product. Historically; the preoceupation with increasing production as fast as possible has resulted not only in the construc- tion of modern and efficient plants but also in the continued operation Of backward and. high-cost producers. _Few if any Soviet?plants have " been known to go out of production because their costs- were 2 or 3 times as high as the average, An excellent example of this phenomenon is provided by the indexes of labor productivity in .the largest .ferrous metallurgical plants in .the USSR (see Table 9*). .Such variations in labor productivity are usually accompanied by comparable variations in production costs, which in turn vastly complicate the planning process. In the future a more rational distribution of resources, particularly of labor, will be necessary if hlgh rates of growth of industrial production are to be maintained. * Table 9 follows on p. 34. -33- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 9 Comparative Indexes of Average output per Worker in Selected Ferrous Metallurgical lants in the USSR Ei 1954 Ilants Kuznetsk CoMbine MagnitoEorsk Combine Novo-Taeil'skiy Plant Chelyabinsk Plant "Zaporozhstal" Plant "Azovstal" Plant Makeyevskiy Krivorozhskiy Dzerzhinskovo Stalina Voroshil ova Blast Furnaces Open-Hearth Furnaces 100 122 79 69 55 50 51 42 38 34 N.A. 100 89 52 50 77 57 43 N.A9 43 N.A. 46 B. Future Problems and Policies. Th i . e future possibilities for incre sing industrial production by expanding the labor force and the recent tends in the distribution of increments to the labor force are illustra.ed in Tables 10* and 11.** During the period from 1950 to 1955 (inclu lye), nearly 5 million new workers were obtained from the agrlcuitur4 population. .It is esti- mated that la 1956-60, only about 1 million to 2.5 million workers can be added to the nonagricultural labor forc from the =normal increment to the agricaltural population, and a cons derable number of.petple with technical educations will be transfer ed to agriculture. Conse- quently, increased output per worker will iave to account for the bulk of the increase in industrial production d ring the next few years- * Table 10 follows on p. 35. ** Table 11 follows on p. 36. -34- S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-1RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 10 < Nonagricultural Employment in the USSR a_ 1946-60 0 Million Workers and Employees 73 ET 1 January 1 January 1 January 1 January 1 January 1 January 1946 1951 1951 1956 1956 1961 Fourth Five Year Plan .(1946-50) 23.7 36.8 ? Fifth Five Year Plan (1951-55) 36.8 43.3 ? Sixth Five Year Plan (1956-60) 43.3 48.o to 48.5 8 CD0 i3 D CD a a CD 01 a a a a a CD a a a -35- 0 S-E-C-R-E-T 0-1.0006Z00?000V9?60016/dC1N-V10 : IZ/60/6661. eseeieN .10d peA0.1ddV Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 11 Total Labor Force in the USSR 1950 to 1 January .956 Mill'on Workers and Employees Year Collective Farms State Agri ulture Nonagricultural 1950 49.0 2.4 34.8 1951 49.0 2.4 36.8 1952 48.2 2.6 38.2 1953 48.7 2.6 39.1 1954 48.5 4.1 40.7 1955 48.6 5.0 42.0 1956 2/ 49.6 5.5 43.0 Preliminary estimate. Current Soviet policies designed t labor productivity run the gamut from the crease the supply of quality foodstuffs; w incentives for higher productivity; to mea nological innovation. HThe underlying ass are necessary to promote the growth of lab changed since the adoption of the "new cou. program and the emphasis on improving hous vide greater incentives to the labor force During the first 6 months of 1955 increase in emphasis on improved technolog productivity. 22/ Introduction of new tec (1) the general diffusion of knowledge and -36- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA promote the rapid growth of ong-range program to in- ich presumably will increase ures designed to speed tech- ption that greater incentives r productivity has not se.11 The current agricultural ng are both designed to pro- here has been a significant as one of the keys to labor nology has two aspects: information concerning RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 _S-E-C-R-E-T technological developments, and (2) the widespread application of specific techniques; particularly mechanization and automation.* These techniques not only have great potentialities in terns of reducing labor inputs into productive processes but also have a distinctive ideological and emotional appeal to the Soviet leadership. Automation in particular promises to become a mystique, to become charged with more ill-defined overtones of a panacea than was "planning" in the early 1930s. Soviet leaders look to mechanization and automation not only to reduce direct labor inputs but also to make possible the "elimination of the distinction between mental and physical labor" which they conceive to be essential to the transition from the present "socialism" to the future "communism." In. other words, even the manual worker will become a combination of meter reader, maintenance man, and low-grade engineer. It is also likely that the Soviet leadership an- ticipates the promulgation of such a vision to strike sparks of interest and enthusiasm and to improve worker morale.** * The Soviet concept of automation is comewhat broader than the term used in the West inasmuch as the USSR tends to apply the term to a single machine which performs one, or possibly two; operations with very little assistance from the human operator. In the West, automation is usually limited to a number of machines which are linked together and which automatically perform a number of operations; including the inspection of the quality of the product. ** In the past; the Russians have had difficulty in adjusting mass expectations concerning the technical training and responsibilities which would be available to the average worker to what actually was available. In the 1930's, because of the demands of industrialization and the Party's desire to relieve itself of dependence upon the tech- nical intelligentsia inherited from the Tsarist period, great stress was laid upon the opportunitlies open to all for technical advancement. The response was a widespread aspiration for higher eduction and the white smock of the engineer. When, however, the immediate needs for engineers and technicians had been largely met in the late 1930's, and it was desired to control entry into this social class more closely, it was found necessary to limit these expectations; Kalinin complained eloquently; Who is going to do the hot and dirty jobs?" In subsequent years the class lines between the workers and the intelligentsia have been clearly drawn, and movement from the first to the second has been restricted in order to enhance the prestige of the new managerial class. -37- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 The Soviet desire to eliminate the essential distinction" be- tween mental. and physical labor complLcates the problem of getting more capital per unit of output through mechanization and automation. Given the rate of output specified in the plan as the objective, the Soviet engineer is told to design machinery which will require engineers and highly skilled technicians to operate it, eliminating the use of un- skilled and semiskilled workers if possible. Judging from US experience and from a few examples of Soviet designs, the same rate of output usually could be achieved by using machiney of lower original cost and of lower opErating costs in terms of wages but which would still use some unskilled and semiskilled labor. Such capital intensive solu- tions, of course, represent an improvement over the existing combina- tions of capital and labor but certainly do result in more capital in- tensive solitions than in. the West, where the primary objective is to minimize total costs (both capital and labor). Unless sharply modified in practice; the Soviet theory will tend th slow down the rate at which the new technology will reduce unit costs. Furthermore, the introduction of mechanization and automation competes very directly with the production of military end items for modern weapons systems,' and the pinch on such industries as electronics and precision instru- ments can be expected to be severe. The elimination of the distinction batmeen mental and physical labor" seemingly is the slogan adopted to dramatize the current policy on this matter. It appears that, through the provision of more compli- cated equipment and continuous training o?1 the laboring force, an attempt is being made to raise the genera level of technical ability far enough to obtain increased productivi y and to provide some prestige rewards to the working class. But the prdcess of raising the general level of technological competence, in its social aspects, must stop short of destroying the distinctive positioa and special privileges of the in- telligentsia. Although the current slogan has not yet been widely pop- ularized (it is, of course, a historic goal, but it fell from prominence for many years), it will probably come inCreasingly to the fore. This development is related to current revisiors of the 10-year school cur- riculum in the direction of increased vocational training in the future, 10--,!rear education is to become universal and is to be aimed not only at entrance into universities but chiefly at manning the labor force with personnel falling in the range between skilled workers and technicians. -38- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T The prospects for achieving a more rapid growth of labor produc- tivity in the next 5 years, and an increase of 50 to 60 percent compared with about 40 percent officially reported for the 1951-55 period; may be assayed briefly. The Soviet leaders should be successful in increas- ing the flow of technical knowledge, improving the general level of technology in the economy; and reforming the wage system; although there will be strong institutional pressures to abuse the system of premiums and bonuses. All these things should do much to promote the growth of labor productivity. Two crucial problems remain; however. First; there is by no means any guarantee that increased output of quality foodstuffs; which will increase mass incentives; will be forth- coming and, second; the ability of the planners to insure the necessary degree of improvement in the general technological level of the economy may well be limited by the competition of modern weapons systems. V. Cost Reductions and Technological Progress. A. Cost Reductions and Investment Surplus. There are several measures of efficiency which are quite im- portant in assessing Soviet plan fulfillment. All Soviet production schedules are based on anticipated cost reductions and increased pro- ductivity of capital as well as on the planned allocations from current account. In the current Five Year Plan; for example; Of the 90-percent in.- crease planned in the volume of investment, one-third was to be achieved by reducing total investment costs (1951-55 compared with 1946-50) and two-thirds by increasing allocations from current account. Probably the most important efficiency measure is the re- duction in aebestoimostv (cost of production*) of industrial produc- tionl_which includes the value of raw materials and semifinished goods, fuel and power;.wages; an amortization allowancel** and certain administrative expenditures. This cost reduction is the difference * -Sebestoimost';the accounting category which is the basis for most Soviet pricing and cost accounting; cannot be directly translated. The closest approximation is our concept of total cost with the qual- ification that under the Soviet _system fixed costs are geared more closely to production than is common in the West. ** The Soviet amortization allowance includes repair and replace- ment of capital equipment but does not contain- an obsolescence factor, 39 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T between the actual cost of production in gear II and the total cost of production :xi year II calculated on the b sis of cost per unit in Year I. Such reductions in the cost of industrial production increase the state surplus available for investment and defense and provide the basis for price reductions in producer goOds and military end items. Price reduc-Lions for producer goods?1- raw materials, and semifinished goods together with reductions in construction costs make possible a greater increase in real volume of investMent than is indicated by the allocat.ons from current account. The yearly decline in the aggregate sebestoimost? of industrial pro uction is shown in Table 12. Table 12 Reduction in the -Total Cost of Industrial Production in the USSR 1951-55 Percent Cumulative Percentage Reduction from Preceding Year Four-Year 1955 Reduction 1951 1952 1953 .1954 (6 Mont.I.ST Plan) (l952- LA. a/ 8.0 5.0 4.o 3.8 .5) 19.0 Five Year Plan (1951-55) 25.0 a. The total reduction in 1951 was not reriorted in percentage terms. The Soviet press, however, did report that savings from cost reductions, excluding the savings from the reduction in wholesale prices of raw materials and semifinished goods, amounted to 26 billion rubles.. Ap- parently, moEt of the savings from 1951 price reductions were passed on to provide the unusually large reduction in 1952. As indicated above, planned cost rieductions for the 1951-55 period were to amount to 25 percent (aggr gate production in actual costs compared with aggregate production ib 1950 costs). If 1951 is * Price reductions in consumer goods are !derived primarily from the re- duction in the turnover tax, although red tion of the sebestoimost? of processing may be a factor. In general) te rate of profit decreed by the state is hiEher in the consumer goods indu1stry than in heavy industry. -11-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T excluded from consideration and if it is assumed that the rate of de- crease during the first half of 1955 is representative of the entire year, the cumulative cost reductions for the 1952-55 period will amount to 19 percent. Even allowing for the savings in 1951, it is now doubt- ful if the economies planned for the 1951-55 period will be achieved. ,Reductions in production costs will assume even greater impor- tance in the next 5 years than in the past because they are one of the principal means of increasing the state surplus -- that is, that part of the difference between production and consumption (in a given time period) which is available to the state for investment and defense.* According to Soviet accounting practice; this surplus consists pri- marily of the profits of state enterprises and the turnover tax. .Re- ductions in sebestoimost', together with increased volume of production, increase the prOfits of enterprises and hence the state surplus. Trends in the growth of this surplus and the demands made upon it by invest- ment and defense are illustrated in Table 13.** It will be noted that, in the 1952-54 period, the surplus grew at a slower rate than did the de- mands upon it. The same process is also expressed in the growth of real wages at a faster rate than labor productivity during the same period. In recent years the share of the state surplus derived from the turnover tax has been declining rather rapidly; this has been compen- sated for by profits of enterprises, which in turn are heavily dependent upon cost reductions. .This trend is illustrated in Table a4** and is in sharp contrast to the Fourth Five Year Plan, when almost the entire surplus was derived from the turnover tax, -Furthermore, during the immediate postwar period almost the entire turnover tax was levied on goods which were agricultural in origin, serving ,as a vehicle for ex- tracting the bulk of the state surplus from the economy as a.whole. * This assumes, of course; that consumption as a proportion of national income remains the same. The definition of the state surplus as used here corresponds to the Soviet concept of "net income" of the state; it should not, of course, be confused with the budget surplus. Private savings are excluded, as are private and collective farm investments, ** TableS.13 and 14 follow on p. 42. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 13 Trends in the Formation and Use o in the USSR 1950-55 the State Surplus 1950 = 100 1950 195 1952 1953 1954 Income to surplus 2/ 100 107 Expenditures from surplus12/ 100 105 1955 (Plan) 110 111 111 125 113 115 118 121 a. Turnover tax collections plus total profits of state enter- prises. b. Explicit defense expenditures plus total investments in state enterprises. Table 14 Turnover Tax as a Proportion of in the USSR 1950-55 State Surplus Percent of Total 1950 1951 1952 1953 78 77 75 73 Industrial profits probably were outweight 1946-49 periDd. Since 1951-52, however, t cultural sector has leveled off and may ha creased proclrement prices and the grcwth agriculture. Retail price reductions (car lug the turnwer tax) have tended to reduc -42- S-E-C-R-E-T 1955 1954 (PlEal 67 62 d by subsidies during the e contribution of the agri- e declined owing to in- f other state outlays for ied out prima:rily by reduc- the contribution of urban Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T consumers, The declining contribution of the agricultural sector to the investment _surplus while the industrial base is expanding rapidly poses a serious long-run growth problem for the Soviet planners and increases the importance of cost reductions in industry as a com- pensating factor, It can be anticipated that the planned reductions in sebestoimost? of industrial production in the 1956,-60 period will be at least 25 percent and .probably more. ?The capability of the economy to reduce costs is; of course, heavily dependent upon the rapid growth of labor- productivity; which has been lagging seriously throughout the 1951-55 period. -Moreover; the political unpalatability of increasing retail prices and resorting to heavy income taxes will make it difficult to reduce consumption; and, thereby increase- the state surplus by such means.. B. Efficieheasures. Several measures of utilization of capital equipment are con- sidered sufficiently important to be reported in the annual plan ful- fillment announcements.. ?Plans for production of capital equipment inputs necessary to achieve final output goals are based upon the anticipated economies in the uge of the existing stock of capital equipment in each time period, Among the most important efficiency measures are production per cubic meter of blast furnace volure and coal input per kilowatt-hour of electricity. Efficiency trends .for the Fifth Five Year _Plan are indicated in Table 15.* Although progress has been stbstantial; most of the cumulative 5,year efficiency goals probably will not be reached. The failure after 1951 to report improvement in the utilization of coal combines probably indicates that in fact no improvement occurred. In general; the coal industry has been operating quite inefficiently despite the fact that gross_ output goals will be exceeded. _While improvement in. .efficiency of use of existing capital stock will continue to be a very important aspect of planning; more rapid and. comprehensive introduction of new technology is necessary if the Soviet planners are to count on continued rapid .improvement of efficiency in the future.- * Table 15 follows on p. 44. -43- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 CD 0_ -11 0 CD (7) a ) CD " CO CD CD CD ? ? F. ".4 CD CD (A) CTI (A) CD 6 Trends in the Improvement of Production Efficiency in Certain Key Industries in filF> nqqp. 1951-55 Percent Production of pig iron per cubic meter of blast furnace volume Production of crude steel per square meter of open-hearth furnace area Productivity of coal combines Speed of drilling in proved fields -Gut-put?of electrI7c power per unit of coal input Increase in Yield per Unit of Input _ Cumulative First Half Target 1951 1952 1953 1954. of 1955 (1951-55) 5 5 2 4 5 30 5 3 5 3 5 25 19 N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. 4 5 5 N.A. N.A. N.A. 2.4 1.9 2.6 N.A. S-E-C-R-E-T Increase Required in 1955 10 LA. Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T VI. Agriculture. The semiannual plan report gives impressive data concerning incre- ments to the input side of the agricultural economy. A: remarkable increase in sown acreage, an increased flow of agricultural machinery, and a marked improvement in the quality of the machine tractor station managerial class are indicators that concrete efforts are being made to increase output. The increase in sown acreage of all crops of the 1955 harvest probably will be about 22 million hectares, a gain of more than 13 percent above last year. The actual acreage increase of the 7 or 8 crops listed in the plan report exceeds by 5 million hectares the net increase in acreage. This is probably the result of a decrease in perennial grasses and low-yielding small-grain acreages in favor of corn. Besides a fourfold acreage increase in corn, sowings of the other heavily emphasized grain crop, wheat, also increase) perhaps by as much as a quarter. Most of the wheat increase was accomplished in the overfulfillment of the "new lands" expansion plan. Sizable increases in area planted to other important food crops, such as potatoes, sun- flowers, and sugar beets, and to flax were in line with plans announced since the initiation of the "new course." The one significant negative aspect of this acreage expansion is the large increase in labor required to care for these crops. The acreage increments to relatively high labor-consuming crops such as corn, flax, sugar beets, and potatoes in the traditional agricultural regions and the demands on these settled regions to send manpower to open up the unsettled "new lands" regions are undoubtedly causing temporary labor shortages, Press complaints this year on the lag in such operations as haymaking indicate that local farm managers are being forced to give priority to the cultivation of corns for example, rather than to the timely cutting of hay. The problem of labor short- ages probably will be at its height during the grain harvest. Although. 1955 is the second year of the "new lands" program for the extension of area sown to small grains in Kazakhstan and West Siberia, this is the first year in which the acreage is of nationally - 45 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T significant proportions -- 20 million hectares (roughly one-sixth of total grain acreage). The lack of ra:Lns iia the late spring and early summer indicates that grain yields in the "new lands"' will be at or below the lcw average characteristic of the region. Unpublished comments made recently by a high Soviet agriculture official indicate that the Soviet planners are well aware of the limiting factors (mostly low rainfall) in crop cultivation in.these areas but believe that the venture will be profitable because of low labor and material expenditures per sown hectare. Khrushchev has indicated that the planned ,'break-even point" is an average yield of 4.8 centners of grain per hectare, which is approximately the long-run average yield in this area. This required average yield; is too low, if past ex- perience with planning the cost of state f' rm production can be used as a criterion. Operational and investment expenditures on state farms, the primary unit in the "new lands," have always been abOve the planned level of cost per unit of outp t. The success or failure of the "new lands" program may depend on w ether the Russians can increase labor and capital productivity to a point where cost of production to the state in the "new lands" will be below costs in- curred in the non-black-soil regions 't.' European USSR. Machinery allocations for the first 6 iionths were at a higher an- nual rate than for the previous year. Esp cially prominent is the in- crease in allocations and production of la or-saving machinery for the cultivation of "new" crops such as corn and formerly unmechanized crops such as potatoes and vegetables. Aslis indicated by the republic plan reports, most of the large diesel tr4tor and, grain combine allocations are going to the "new lands." Although production of corn- harvesting combines was tripled compared 14'.th the first 6 months of last year, tee harvesting of this crop will be mostly unmechanized at least for this crop year. The lack of sufficient peak season labOr in cutting and ensilaging undoubtedly will lead to large fodder losses and to lower feed value for the silage. The plan to increase the quality Cf th rural elite or managing class apparently is being met, if one uses the criterion of educational background. Ninety percent of the directors of machine tractor stations now have special secondary or higher educational training, and 70 percent of the chiefs of repair sh ps are now in the upper educational 'orackets compared with 36 perc nt and 10 percent, re- spectively, Ln 1953. No indication was gi en as to how successfully -46- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T the plan is being carried out to make 1 out of every 3 collective farm chairmen a Party technician from the urban areas. .This plan, first announced in April, calls for the staffing of 30,000 backward collec- tive farms with chairmen of Party and usually nonagricultural experience. In the livestock sector the most notable success has been the rais- ing of milk production during the nonpasture season of October to May, when as little as 20 percent of the annual milk production is usually produced. There is no indication that there were sizable increases in holdings of livestock of individual owners. One of the key incen- tives given the peasants early in the post-Stalin era was the official encouragement, including financial aid, to restore the depleted hold- ings of privately owned. livestock. After large gains in these holdings over the 1953-54 period, there now seems to have been a levelling off, suggesting that feed was in such. short supply after the regional droughts last summer that many private owners had to dispose of hold- ings during the winter. VII. .Trade and Consumption. A. .Trends in Retail Trade. Sales of goods to the population for the first half of 1955 are reported only 8 percent above (in comparable prices) those for the first half of 1954; these, in turn, had been reported 21 percent above those for the first half of 1953. This significant drop in the rate of increase probably reflects a diminished ability to exploit with- drawals from state reserves as well as a possible reluctance to in.- crease greatly imports of consumption goods. Inasmuch as the plan is reported fulfilled, this decrease prob- ably means that the Russians, forced now to rely chiefly upon current do- mestic output for the supply bf goods for sale (see B, belcw),'anticipated in their planning a tighter availability than in 1953 and 1954. If this is so, the growth of sales is as rapid as is possible with current production rates, wtich are restricted both by a limited past invest- ment in facilities for production of consumer goods and by lags in the growth of agricultural. output, which provides most of the material input for consumer goods production. -47- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA S-E-C-R-E-T. RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Generally speaking, the individual items and categories of items which comprise the bulk of retail trade show a significantly diminished rate of sales growth for the first half of 1955 compared with the rate of increase for the first half of 1954 (se Table 16). Table 16 Trends in Retail Trade TurnoTer in the USSR Selected Items First Half of 1954 as percent o First Half of 953 First Half of 1955 .as Percent of First Half of 1954 Meat and me lt products 130 106 Fish and fi 3h products 124 120 Milk and mi. Lk products 121 112 Cotton fabr Lcs 119 110 Clothing 124 118 Knitted goo. is 124 113 Footwear-2/ 115 io6 Sewing mach Lnes 131 117 Furniture 137 117 Bicycles 129 120 a. For 1954, leather footwear. Besides the supply constrictions o demand also was somewhat curtailed during addition to ,;overnmental fiscal measures d assets held by the populace -- for example loan -- effeotive demand was influenced by with some prospective purchasers probably certain item:; (particularly durables) in a price reductIon before the middle of the y failed to ma-;erialize (though some few red locally publIcized, in the cost of certain -48- S-E-C-R-E-T ? sales, it is likely that he first half of 1955. In signed to blot up liquid the increase in the state consumer expectations, ?elaying their buying of ?ticipation of a general ar -- a reduction which ctions occurred, and were television sets and radios). Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-ET The general demands of the population are reported as still being met inadequately, both in respect to the aggregate amount of goods available in certain areas and in respect to the assortment of Items offered, such as food and clothing. Progress in the development of rural trade was not mentioned In the official plan fulfillment report. Subsequently, consumer coop- erative trade -- predominantly rural -- was reported to have grown 13.5 percent over the first half of 1954, representing a 101-percent fulfillment of the plan. These figures include commission trade. Excluding commission trade, the increase was slightly less -- 12.4 percent. B. Trends in Consumption Availabilities from Production. Inasmuch as sales trends increasingly depend upon the trends of current domestic production of consumer goods, these production trends must themselves be examined- Whereas the growth of retail sales has dipped from its 1954 high, general availability of goods from current production continues to grow at a fairly constant rate.* Growth in availability of the major categories of consumer goods is shown in Table 17.** * These indexes are computed on the basis of adjusted physical. pro- duction estimates Tof significant items .of consumption, weighted by their current ruble prices. The rough preliminary comparison of the annual growth rates of the first half of 1955 with the 1954 rates is computed by applying announced percentage production increases for the first-half of 1955 to the appropriate figure in the array of 1954 price-quantity products. -These adjusted products are summed and. the totals compared with the 1954 totals. This preliminary comparison, of course-, has limited reliability the first-half-of-1955 annual rates are compared with full-year rates for 1954, and for such commodities as are not reported. it iS assumed that the 1955 rate will be the same as the rate for 1954. Thus, if 1955 is a better crop year than 1954, this comparison will understate the full-year growth -- pay of wheat, .which naturally was not reported but which plays a large role in the index. -** Table 17 follows on p. 50. Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S -E -C -R-E-T Table 17 Trends in Availability of Consumer Good in the USSR from Current Production Category Calculated Weights. Year 1954 as Pe of Year 195 Food products 55 10-'; Clothing 111 Manufactured consumer goods 4 125 Total 100 107 Annual Rate . cent for First Half of 1955 as Percent of Year 1954 lo4 107 111 105.5 The dips in growth for 1955, of co rse, are in manufactured consumer goods and clothing; food products actually increased at a higher rate than in 1954. .That agriculturl production is a basic prob- lem should be clear from the fact that foo production, though in- creasing, is growing at a rate significant y below other consumer goods. Because of its weight, therefore, this slati growth constitutes the majOr drag on increases in the living standard. C. Investment in Trade Activities. The amount of Soviet investment in the pattern of this investment is fairly c trade net, two aspects are currently empha of facilities in the area of the virgin la and a considerable amount of investment in to construction of new facilities to repla older areas of the. USSR. - 50 - .S-E-C-R-E-T trade is unreported, but ear. In developing the ized: extensive development ds enjoys high priority, trade activities is devoted e obsolete stores in the Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 14 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T VIII. Transport. A. Trends in Goods Haulage. ' The aggregate volume of goods transported during the first half of 1955 increased significantly over the first half of 1954, even though the precise increase cannot be determined on the basis of the report of plan fulfillment.* The increases in average daily loadings by rail were appreciable, and in cargo turnover and cargo carriage by the seagoing merchant fleet were the highest that have been reported during the period of the Fifth Five Year Plan (see Table 18**). The half-year plan was markedly overfulfilled for these two modes of transport, which together haul about 90 percent of the volume of Soviet transport. Although substantial gains are reported in river and motor transport, the increases fall somewhat short of the plans in each case (except for overfulfillment of the plan for bus passenger transport). The above-plan increase in aggregate carriage may reflect, in addition to overfulfillment of the plan. for industry as a whole., a possible Soviet tendency to solve crash production problems by means of increased transport inputs rather than by means of higher levels of plant inventories of scarce raw materials. Given ample capacity in the transport plant, such substitution might involve less current outlay than would an increment to the materials inventory. The plan for increasing the average speed, of freight trains, a goal unfulfilled for some time,. was fulfilled in the first half of 1955. Fre1ght7car turnaround time was also reported, decreased. These two operating factors are related, to the announced 9-percent increase in average daily. loadings, one of the highest reported in the post- retonstruction period. This is especially significant because of the large proportion of total transport that is handled by Soviet railroads. * However,.as an approximation and based on average daily loadings-by rail and cargo turnover data for other modes of transport, aggregate transport plan fulfillment is almost 102 percent. Similarly? total volume of traffic is about 111 percent of the first half of 1954. Weights used are as follows: rail, 85; merchant fleet, 5; river fleet, 6; and motor transport, 4.. ?** Table 18 follows on, p. 52. -51 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA S-E-C-R-E-T Table 18 Trends in Transport Activit RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 n the USSR Percent of Plan Transport Increase Fulfillment over Previous Period First Half First Half Transport (ctivity of 1954 of 1_955 Rail Average daily loading Merchant fleet Cargo turnpver Cargo carriage River fleet Cargo turn)ver Cargo carriage Motor transpprt 102 fil 103 102 1 6 93 102 82 N.A. Cargo turnover 103 5 Cargo carriage 101 9 Bus passen3ers 108 1Q6 1954 First Half of 1955 10612/ 109 118 130 106 118 106 108 111 100 166 135 175 150 N.A. 148 a. Not give:1; figure relates to full year 1954 and 1953. .b. Figure r,?.lates to first half of 1954 aid first half of 1953. The increased-volume of goods tran ported by the merchant fleet accompanies a general rise in Soviet forei n trade activty which persisted in:o the first half of 1955. Th increased volume of cargo also reflect;3 increasing POL transport by Soviet bottoms as well as in- creasing dry cargo movements between the Far East and the European USSR. -52- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T The shortfalls from river fleet transport plans probably are in good part a consequence of the unusually late thaws of the 1955 spring. The primary regions for river fleet operations are extremely vulner- able to weather conditions. It should be noted. that the shortfalls for the first half of 1954 were even larger than those aurrently reported -- yet the 1954 full-year plan was met. The reported shortfalls from the very high planned increases in motor transport for 1955 are not large. In fact, the physical vol- ume of the increase probably is significantly larger than that of the comparable 1954 period over 1953. These high targets clearly highlight the sharply increasing reliance of Soviet economic planners upon motor transport to provide urban dray services and rural railhead. access. B. Transpat investment. Because of its paramount role in the movement of goods and persons in the USSR, rail transport absorbs the bulk of transport in- vestment. Such investment may take place in three major directions: extension of rights-of-way; the improvement of fixed plants and fa- cilities (such as signal systems; marshalling yards, or depots);;and- expansion and improvement of the rolling stock park. The first of these, by expanding the territory of service, is considered. to involve extensive development. The latter two generally are considered to involve intensive improvements. -Under Stalin the. railroads of the USSR were rapidly extended in an effort to keep pace with the geographic dispersion of economic activity and. the widely publicized emphasis upon Siberian development. .In the investment review that occurred. immediately after Stalin's death, the policy seemed to have shifted to give less emphasis to the rapid laying of new trackage and more emphasis to improvement of the existing plant and equipment park. Total transport investment increased, how- ever, Data reported for the first half of 1955 indicate continuance of this policy (see Table 19*). The electrification..and dieselization programs are clearly reflected in the above figures. The drop in out- put of steam .locomotives is probably temporary owing to model changes.. * Table 19 follows on p. 54. - 53 - Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-1RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 1.9 Trends in Production of Transport Ro ing Stock in the USSR First Half or 1954 First Half of 1955 as Percentlof as Percent of 1953 First Half of 1954 Item First Half o Mainline electric locomotives 104 Mainline diesel locomotives N.A. Mainline steam locomotives 131 Mainline freight cars N.A. Trolleybuses 109 Motor trucks 110 Autobuses 168 The Ministry of Transport Construe creased the volume of its construction-ass half of 1955 by 4 percent over the first half the 1954 increase. This is the small 122 121 84 138 113 112 100 ion is reported to have in- mbly work for the first if of 1954, or about one- at increase reported for any of the construction ministries and repl'esents underfulfillment of the plan. Since this ministry is principally concerned, of course, with the extension of rights-of-way and th ir improvement, this rel- atively small increase in construction-ass mbly work reflects contin- Uation of the relatively slight emphasis oil extension of the transport net. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 . S-E-CHR-E-T APPENDIX SOURCE. REFERENCES This memorandum is based on Soviet plan fulfillment reports/ issued quarterly through 1952 and semiannually thereafter, and on CIA analyses of the mid-,1954 report. All data in this memorandum? unless otherwise indicated, are taken from the annual and sendannual Soviet plan fulfillment reports. These reports appeared in the Soviet press on the following dates: 21 Janu- ary. 1947, 18 January 1948, 20 January 1949, 18 January 19501 27 January 1951, 29 January 1952, 23 January 1953/ 17 July 19531 31 January 19541 23 July 1954, 21 January 1955, 22 Okay 1955, and Premier Bulganin's speech in Pravda, 17 July 1955 Translations of these reports, beginning With the annual report for 1948, appear in the following numbers of the Current Digest of the Soviet Press: 1948 annual: Vol. 1, No. 4; 1949 ?6-;:1-4.Voarinr.W.Lal: Vol. III,No. 3; 1951 annual: Vol. IV) NO. 3; 1952 annual VoL V, No. 2; 1953 semiannual: Vol. V, No. 27; and. 1953 annual: V014 1/1, No, 5. All. Soviet newspapers, books, and journals are considered to be highly reliable sources of economic information. The FBIS publica- tions are primarily translations, and slight errors in broadcast Intercept as well as in subsequent :translation make them slightly less reliable sources than the originals. valuation, following the classification entry and ,designated' uEval.?'" have the followingeignificance: -55- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA,RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Sou-ce of Information Information Doc. - Documentary A - Completely reliable B - Usually reliable C - Fairly reliable D - Not usually reliable E - Not reliable F - Cannot be judged 1 - Confirmed by other 2 - Probably true 3 - Possibly true 4 - Duatful 5 - Prcibably false 6 - Cannot be judged S ources "Documen-;ary" refers to original documnts of foreign governments and organiza-Aons; copies or translations cif such documents by a staff officer; or :mformation extracted from such documents by a staff officer, all of which may carry the field evaluation "Documentary." Evaluations not otherwise designated are those appearing on the cited document; those designated 'RR" are by the author of this memorandum. No "RR" evaluation is given when the author agrees with the evaluation on the cited document. 1. USSR, Verkhovnyy:Sovet SSSR. Zasedaniya verkhovnogo soveta SSSR, chetvertogo sozyva, vtoraya sessiya, stenograficheskiy otchet (Proceedings of the Supreme Soviet of the USSR, kth Meeting, 2d Session: Stenographic Report), Moscow, 1955, p. /75-476. U. Eval. RR 1. (hereafter referred to as USSR, Verkhovnyy Sovet SSSR. Zaseldaniya) 2. CIA. CIA/RR IM-411, Soviet Plan F91fillment, 1954, 5 Jul 55, Tab-e 1, footnote d, p. 6. s. 3. Pravda, 17 Jul 55. U* Eval. AR 2. 4, USSR, Verkhovnyy Sovet SSSR. Zasedaniya (1, above). 5. Klimenko, K. "0 putyakh povysleniyta proizvoditel'nosti trucLa v mashinostroyenii" (On Ways to Increase Labor Produc- tiv:ty in Machine Building Industries), Voprosy ekonomiki, no 5, 1955, p. 21i. U. Eval. PR 1. -56- S-E-C-R-3- Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 S-E-C-R-E-T Pravda, 17 Jul 55. U. Eval. RR 2. 7. Perovskiy, N. "Vnedreniye peredovoy tekhniki vo vse otrasli proizvodstva" (Introduction of New Technology into All Branches of Production), Planovoye khozyaystvo, no 3, 1955, p. 3. U. Eval. RR 2. 8. Izvestiya, 8 Feb 55, P. 3. U. Eval. RR 2. 9. CIA. CIA/RR 37, The Role of the Tractor Industry in the USSR, 1940-54, 16 Aug 54. S. 10. Ibid. 11. Ibid. 12. Klimenko? aa. cit. (5, above). 13. Ibid. p. 23. U. Eval. RR 1. 14. Gatovskiy, L. "Rol sovetskoy torgovli v sotsialisticheskom vosproizvodstve" (Role of Soviet Trade in Socialist Repro- duction), Kommunist? no 9, 1955, p. 33. U. Eval, RR 1. 15. Khromov, p. "Povyshentye prolzvodite1'nosti obshchestvennogo truda" (Increasing the Productivity of Social Labor), Voprosy ekonomiki, no 4, 1955, p. 65. U. Eval. RR 1. Pashko? Ioyand Kheyman? S. "0 reservykh uvelicheniya protzvodstvo chernykh metallov v SSSR" (On the Reserves for Increasing the Production of Ferrous Metals in the USSR), Voprosy ekonomtki, no 4, 1955, p. 87. U. Eval. RR 2, Kommunist, no 7, 1955, p. 10, U. Eval, RR 1. 16. Khromov? op. cit. (15, above), p. 72, U. Eval. RR 2. 17. Kozlova, 0. IlTahnicheskiy progress i rost kultturno- tekhnicheskogo urovnya rabochikh" (Technical Progress and the Growth of the Cultural-technical Level of the Workers), Voprosy ekonomiki?no 6, 1955, P- 32. U. Eval. RR 1. 18. Pashko and Kheyman, op. cit. (15, above), p. 88. U. Eval. RR 2. 19. Khromov, op. cit. (15, above), p. 63. Ti. Eval. RR 2. Kommunist, no 7, 19552 p. 6. U. Eval. RR 2. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA-RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA SECRET Approved For Release 1999/09/21 : CIA RDP79T00935A000300290001-0 RDP79T00935A000300290001-0