PROBABLE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTS IN EAST GERMANY THROUGH 1955

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
S
Document Page Count: 
85
Document Creation Date: 
November 9, 2016
Document Release Date: 
February 12, 1999
Sequence Number: 
1
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
February 15, 1954
Content Type: 
IR
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6.pdf4.48 MB
Body: 
ease 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A0004001 10001-6 PROVISIONAL INTELLIGENCE REPORT PROBABLE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTS IN EAST GERMANY THROUGH 1955 CIA/RR PR-48 15 February 1954 DOCUMENT NO. NO CHANGE IN CLASS. 0 0 DECLASSIFIED CLASS CHANGED TO NEXC REVbEWDATE: AUTH: I3 70 DATE:_VF_`7 EVIEWEC. ,2_ CENTRAL INTELLIGENCE AGENCY OFFICE OF RESEARCH AND REPORTS US OFFICIALS ONLY Approved For Release 1999/09/02: CIA-RDP79-01093 r Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 WARNING This material contains information affecting the National Defense of the United States within the meaning of the espionage laws, Title 18, USC, Secs. 793 and 794, the trans- mission or revelation of which in any manner to an unauthorized person is prohibited by law. Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 CONFIDENTIAL US OFFICIALS ONLY PROVISIONAL INTELLIGENCE REPORT PROBABLE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTS IN EAST GERMANY THROUGH 1955 CIA/RR PR-48 (ORR Project 10.103) The data and conclusions contained in this report do not necessarily represent the final position of ORR and should be regarded as provisional only and subject to revision. Comments and data which may be available to the user are solicited. Office of Research and Reports Approved For Release ~ hNI kDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999 C6F#0tffVt01093A000400170001-6 CONTENTS Page Summary and Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 I. Economic Organization and Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 A. Soviet Organization and Policy . . . . . . . . . . . 5 B. German Economic Organizations . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 1. Governmental Organization . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 2. Extent of State Control of the Economy . . . . 17 3. Economic Planning . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20 C. Economic Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25 D. The "New Course" . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27 II. Economic Development of East Germany . . . . . . . . . . 30 A. Over-All Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30 B. Industry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 C . Agriculture . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38 III. Foreign Economic Relations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 A. Pattern of Trade . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 . . . . 1. East German Trade with the West . . 42 i 2. East German Trade with the Other Soviet Bloc Countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44 B. Role of East Germany in the Soviet Bloc Economy . . . 49 IV. Labor and Population . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . A. State Control over Labor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51 B. Manpower and Labor Planning . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54 C. Labor Force and Population . . . . . . . . . . . 55 D. Incentives and Other Devices to Increase Output 55 E. Migration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57 F. Scale of Living . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58 5-E- Approved For Release I 99 E1:Q APL-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : Cl 5 Pn7.$jQf 93A000400170001-6 CONA A )endixe s Page Appendix A. Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 Appendix B. Sources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69 1. Percentage of Gross National Product of East Germany by Sectors, 1952 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31 2. Indexes of Production in East Germany by Sectors, 1938, 1946-52 . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33 3. Production of Agricultural Commodities in East Germany, 1952 and 1955 Plan . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 4. Foreign Trade of East Germany, 1948-52 . . . . . . . . . 41 Value of the Trade of East Germany with the West by Countries, 1948-49 and 1951-52 . . . . . . . . . . . . 43 6. Commodity Composition of the Trade of East Germany with the West, 1948, 1949, and 1951 . . . . . . . . . . 45 7. Distribution of the Trade of East Germany with Other Soviet Bloc Countries, 1948-52 . . . . . . . . . . . . 47 8. Commodity Composition of the Trade of East Germany with Other Soviet Bloc Countries, 1949 . . . . . . . . 48 9. Employment in East Germany by Sectors, 1952 and 1955 Plan . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10. Production of Selected Commodities in East Germany, 56 the USSR, and the Soviet Bloc, 1952 . . . . . . . . . . 61 CONE _ EN IAL Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400'170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/(ONIFf p93A000400170001-6 Page 11. Migration between West Germany and East Germany, between West Berlin and East Germany, and between West Berlin and East Berlin, by Time Period, 19+8-52 . . . . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . . . 65 12. Total Persons Passing Through the Emergency Acceptance Procedure in Berlin by Age and Sex, January 1952-June 1953 . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 CONFIDENTIA Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79i0; 093A000400170001-6 CONFIDENTI CIA/RR PR-48 t"M _ (ORR Project 10.103) PROBABLE ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTS IN EAST GERMANY THROUGH 1955* Summary and Conclusions The East German economy is. the largest and most productive in the European Satellites. The gross national product. (GNP) of East Ger- many in 1952 was about $15.5 billion (1951 $ US), the largest GNP among the Satellites, with the highest percentage of total GNP pro- duced by industry. Like the other Satellites, East Germany in the postwar period has been progressively remodeled on the Soviet pattern. Transportation, the greater part of industry, nearly all financial services, and much of trade have been nationalized, and government controls over the private sector have been directed toward tying this sector to the directly planned economy with correspondingly reduced scope for private initiative. Controls over labor have reduced the unions to subservience to the government's economic administration, and several government measures permitting the compulsory assignment of workers to particular places of employment supplement Soviet- patterned wage differentials as a means of allocating workers to various industries and categories of employment. Only in agriculture has the Soviet remodeling of the East German economy failed to develop to the desired extent. The goal for eventual socialization of this sector, however, has been made explicit and remains in effect despite a temporary slackening of the pace toward its realization under the concessions of the "new course" which began in June 1953. Soviet control over East Germany from the original occupation to the present has been complete. Although the USSR ostensibly has relaxed controls over the East German economy, there is no conclusive evidence that such a relaxation has in fact taken place, and there is some evidence that close Soviet supervision is remaining in effect. Every effort is being made to strengthen the East German Communist Party, through which much of Soviet control is exercised. The progressive changes in the organization of the East German gov- ernment and economic administration have been directed toward closer * This report contains information available as of 24 December 1953. It is a revision of the ORR contribution to NIE-94, circulated as IP-350, dated 19 November 1953. 9,g/ NTIAL Approved For Release 1999 . I -RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T approximation to the Soviet prototype for the management of a cen- trally planned economy. Economic policy following the Soviet classic example has attempted to reorient the economy away from light industry toward heavy industry, and the planning methodology and procedures represent faithful attempts to follow current Soviet practices. With its advanced technology, highly developed industry, and highly skilled labor force, East Germany has been exploited to the benefit of the USSR through heavy reparations and other forms of uncompensated deliveries. Even if the USSR is sincere in cancel- ing reparations and making other concessi long as the area remains under firm Sovie produce must be included in appraisals of is to East Germany, as control its capacity to Soviet capabilities for supporting hot or cold war. In 1952 the East German GNP repre- sented about 8 percent of the total for the Soviet Bloc,* or about 14 percent of the Soviet GNP. Under Soviet domination the East German economy is being inte- grated with that of the rest of the Soviet Bloc. About 75 percent of the foreign trade turnover of East Germany is currently with other Bloc countries, and the greater part of that is with the USSR. As an advanced industrial area, East Germany is an important sup- plier of machinery, chemicals, electrical engineering products, and precision equipment, and in return it receives from the USSR and the Satellites primarily agricultural and industrial raw materials, food, mineral fuels, lubricants, and certain manufactured products. East Germany contributes the following large percentages of total Bloc output of the indicated products: secondary copper, 39; re- fined lead, 10; ammonia, 29; nitric acid, 17; calcium carbide, 55; caustic soda, 29; refined phenol, 59; synthetic rubber, 22; rayon, 53; machine tools, 16; turbines, 18; and transformers, 16. On the other hand, East Germany is a relatively small producer of iron and steel, grains, vegetable oils, and natural fibers. During the postwar period, production in the East German econ- omy staged a rapid recovery from extremely low postwar levels, especially after 1911$, when Soviet direct exploitation through dis- mantling and collection of war booty ceased and uncompensated Soviet withdrawals from current production were reduced. In 1952, however, the estimated GNP was still slightly below the 1938 level. The annual rate of growth leveled off sharply in 1952 to about 5 percent, and it is estimated that growth through 1955 will continue at about this rate. * Including Communist China. S E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T The growth of industrial production has been impressive since 1949, although the level attained by 1952 failed to reach the 1938 level by a small margin. The investment plans, however, on which the original plans for industrial production after 1952 depended, have not been fulfilled. Excessive concentration upon building up basic industries (such as ferrous metallurgy), poor planning, short- ages of raw materials. and of competent technicians, and the heavy burden imposed upon the engineering industries by reparations -- all these factors contributed to the failure to realize the planned increases in investment. Agricultural production as measured in terms of leading crops and animal products still has not come up to prewar levels. The 1955 goals for agriculture under the Fifth Five Year Plan, though technically feasible, very probably will not be reached, because of the unfavorable reaction of farmers to the government's exactions in the form of compulsory deliveries and to the official interest in collectivization, which has continued despite the modest retreat since June 1953. The scale of living in East Germany is still considerably below prewar levels. A number of factors have contributed to this situation: (1) production of investment goods has been favored at the expense of consumers' goods; (2) the population of the present area is about 10 percent higher than before the war, and East Germany has been obliged also to support the Soviet occupation troops; and (3) reparations and other uncompensated deliveries have imposed a heavy burden on the East German economy. In 1952, unfavorable weather resulted in poor yields of potatoes, sugar beets, and fodder, and harvesting was dis- rupted by the newly instituted drive for collectivization. At the same time, the government sought to add food to the state reserves. As a result of these circumstances the scale of living in 1952 declined for the first time since 1947. Not only did the scale of living decline in the latter part of 1952 and early 1953, but also the East German regime, under the slogan of building up socialism, adopted a number of harshly repressive measures of a political nature, such as increased arrests, greater severity of punishment for a broadened assortment of economic crimes, and increased persecution of the churches. As a consequence, migration from East to West Germany reached new high levels. On 9 June 1953 the Communist Party of East Germany suddenly announced that the policies adopted and the actions taken during the preceding year as part of the program of building socialism had been S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T incorrect and that their "new course" would be to increase the scale of living by increasing the production of consumers' goods at the expense of the projected growth of heavy industry. On 17 June, widespread rioting occurred throughout East Germany. There are many factors which influenced the timing of the riots. The impact of the newly increased work norms was especially onerous, and this by itself may have been the spark. that finally transformed widespread but latent hostility to the regime into active protest. In addition, the fact that some concessions had already been announced by the government may have been interpreted by the workers as evidence of weakness and indecision on the part of the regime. The effect of the riots was to bring about further concessions and hasten their implementation. The implementation of the "new course" has been materially aided by the USSR. In August 1953 a lengthy protocol containing a number of concessions to East Germany was announced jointly by the govern- ments of East Germany and the USSR.. These concessions included cessation of reparations deliveries, the return of Soviet-owned com- panies in East Germany to-German control, and the promise of a large loan on the foreign trade account. In July, moreover, Soviet ship- ments of foodstuffs to East Germany increased significantly. These concessions were designed to bolster the sagging prestige of the East German regime and to strengthen it as an instrument of Soviet control over the area. In the short run the USSR appears to have given up some benefits from the East German economy, but in the long run the "new course" should tend to reduce popular unrest and make it easier to keep East Germany in the Soviet Bloc. Under the "new course," plans for investment in heavy industry have been cut back, and plans for production of consumers' goods have been raised. Prices and taxes have been reduced, and wages have been somewhat increased. If the diversion of resources from heavy to consumers' goods industries takes place as planned, it will be possible for retail trade turnover to increase substantially. If East Germany is indeed freed from Soviet exactions, the projected increase in consumption is feasible. The leaders of the East German regime have emphasized that the "new course" is not a retreat from the basic aim of achieving socialism but instead is a better way of realizing this goal. No retreat from the level of socialization achieved by the summer of S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T 1952 is promised. Collectivization of agriculture is not being forced at present, but it has not been abandoned as an objective. I. Economic Organization and Policy. A. Soviet Organization and Policy. Since the end of the war, Soviet economic policy with respect to East Germany has been conditioned by three basically conflicting aims: (1) to exploit East. Germany as much as possible for the benefit of the Soviet economy, (2) to transform East Germany into a dependable Satellite with a planned economy along Soviet lines, and (3) to use East Germany and the promise of German unity as a means of extending Soviet influence in West Germany and of preventing the formation of an effective European Army. Until mid-1948 the first aim was dom- inant, and Soviet policy was one of ruthless exploitation through dismantling factories and levying heavy reparations from current production. Between 1948 and mid-1953, Soviet policy was to restore and enlarge the East German industrial base insofar as this was com- patible with reduced, though still substantial, reparations deliveries, and to change the structure of the economy to conform to the Soviet model insofar as this was compatible with extending Soviet influence in West Germany. Beginning in the summer of 1952, rapid Sovietization seemed to have become the dominant policy, and the campaign for German unity seemed to have assumed a subsidiary role. On 10 June 1953 the SED (Sozialistische Einheitspartei Deutschlands -- Socialist Unity Party of Germany 'East German Communist Party7) announced. a number of measures, referred to as the "new course," that in effect revoked the policy of rapid Sovietization and also inaugurated a policy that promised to in- crease the real income of the East German people.* Manifestations of Soviet policy with respect to East Germany may be divided into three categories: (1) direct action, (2) delega- tion of authority to German organizations, and (3) more or less covert action through these organizations. It may be said that all sections of the East German government, the parties, and the SED-controlled mass organizations are manifestations of Soviet policy. Thus there * See D, below, for a discussion of the "new course." S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T is no real distinction between Soviet and East German policy. (For purposes of formal organization, the first two forms of Soviet action are discussed in this section, and the last, East German policy and organization, is discussed in the following section.) According to the Potsdam Agreement (Article III, par. 14+), Germany was to be treated as a single economic unit, and to that end common policies were to be established with respect to all important aspects of economic life. J* This condition has never obtained to any important degree. Decisions of the Allied Control Council were to be unanimous. J As a result of this requirement and the funda- mental disagreement of council members, no comprehensive program for Germany as'a whole could be worked out. In organizing the administration of their zone the Soviet authorities carried out, after their fashion, decisions of the Control Council to the effect that German provincial (Laender) administrations be established and also that certain central German administrative departments be established, "particularly in the fields of finance, transport, communications, foreign trade, and industry." 3/ Such departments were to act under the direction of the Control Council; but the Council as an effective governing body soon became unimpor- tant, and the Soviet forces pursued an independent policy in the Soviet zone of occupation. J The German Central Administrations established in the Soviet zone were under the direct supervision of the Soviet Military Administration (SMA).,which was established on 9 June 1945. ~I The Laender Administrations were supervised by the branches of the SMA in each Land. J In the early days of the Soviet occupation, lines of command within both the Soviet and the German organizations were not clear. A number of special missions concerned with the seizure of war booty and the organization of reparations were operating in East Germany and were controlled directly from Moscow rather than by the SMA. In addition, many orders from Moscow regarding occupation duties were sent directly to the provincial SMA's without going through the "nor- mal;" channels of command. / Numerous conflicts took place between various Soviet ministries that laid claim to East German installations and supplies and the SMA, which had the responsibility for maintaining * Footnote references in arabic numerals are to sources listed in Appendix B. -6- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T internal order by supporting the troops in Germany and by fulfilling plans for exports and reparations from current production. The principal Soviet policies were, however, sufficiently clear. During the first 3 years of the occupation, the USSR tried to restore East German industrial production as rapidly as possible at a time when little attention was given to such development in West Germany. At the same time, however, the USSR was quickly remov- ing as much war booty as possible, such as livestock, raw materials, automobiles, tractors, and other valuables, as well as reparations in the form of industrial equipment. ~/ The Russians met with consider- able success in each of these seemingly contradictory endeavors. One of the most important early policy measures carried out by the SMA was the land reform begun in September 1945. All estates containing over 100 hectares were confiscated without compensation and distributed to owners of small- and medium-size holdings and to expellees. J The land reform probably was intended to lead to collectivization, for many of the newly created farms were too small to be operated economically. LO/ Other Soviet measures sought to maintain the German structure of controlled prices by continuing in force the German price and wage ceilings. 11 The SMA also blocked bank accounts and canceled interest-bearing state securities. L2/ The anti-inflationary effects of these measures were more than offset, however, by the reparations policy. From 1945 through mid- 194+8 the USSR took as reparations from current production about one- third of the total industrial production of East Germany. 13 As a result, prices and wages could not be held at the 1944 level, and a severe inflation developed. L4J Planning of production during the early years of the occupa- tion was carried on by detailed command of the Soviet representatives. In carrying out Soviet orders, conflicts arose between the German Central Administrations and the provincial German governments.' The Soviet representatives resolved this conflict through increased centralization of administration, by transforming the Central Admin- istrations into the German Economic Commission (Deutsche Wirtschafts Kommission -- DWK) in 1947 and by giving the DWK extensive powers in economic affairs in February 1948. 15/ The DWK was the forerunner of the German Democratic Republic, whicE was proclaimed provisionally on 6 October 1949. 16/ Four days later the SMA announced its own dis- solution and the formation of the Soviet Control Commission (SCC) and the Group of Occupation Forces in Germany (GOFG). 17/ The SCC S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T retained some of the economic functions of the SMA, and the GOFG assumed responsibility for the security of the Soviet. occupation. These changes represented an increasing delegation of the functions of government to the Germans and also an increasing centralization of eco- nomic controls. In 1952 the SCC had a total personnel of about 3,000 as compared with 50,000 on the staff of the SMA in 1949. 19 The five Land governments and East Berlin retained some control over local industry until the summer of 1952, when the Land governments were dissolved and replaced by 14 Bezirke (administrative districts), which were-designated as local organs of the state executive, thus virtually completing the centralization.of government. 20 At the end of May 1953, it was announced that the SCC was dissolved and replaced by the Office of the High Commissioner for Germany, which was to limit its activities to representing the interests of the USSR in Germany and to overseeing the activities of the German Democratic Republic under the Potsdam Agreement. At the same time, the Chief of the Soviet.Forces in Germany was relieved of responsibility for supervising the East German government. 21/ The constitution adopted by the People's Congress in May 1949 gave the German Democratic Republic a greater degree of control over its.own affairs than was granted the West Germans a few days later. Soviet Bloc constitutional edifices, however, are notoriously at variance with political realities, and the constitution of East Ger- many is no exception to this rule. 22 In theory, the formation of the SCC represented a change from direct Soviet control to mere supervision, but no known contractual agreement was drawn up defin- ing this relationship. Thus the Soviet authorities have remained free to exercise an arbitrary veto over all acts of the East German government. L3/ Economic planning in East Germany reportedly is conducted very much as in the USSR. According to one reliable source, the forms, nomenclature, and commodity code have been taken over unchanged from Soviet practice. 24 According to the same source, the East German State Planning Commission receives mandatory goals for the production of key products on a yearly basis from the economic planning departments of the SCC. The extent to which these goals are set forth in detail is not S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T known, but it is likely that they comprise the 90-odd products and product groups shown on an East German classified report called "Key Positions of the People's Economic Plan" (Schluesse.lpositionen des Volkswirtschaftsplanes). 25/ In the past, Soviet authorities have kept a close check on the planning process at the ministry and planning commission levels and in some cases even at the plant level. It is not known whether or not the change from the SCC to the Office of the High Commissioner has resulted in any real lessening of Soviet controls over, East German planning and production. Generally speak- ing, orders for reparations goods, for exports to the USSR, and for SAG Wismut* have received top priority in the procurement of raw materials and labor in East Germany. 26/ In the fall of 1952, orders for the East German armed forces were given top place on the priority schedule. 27/ Information on the priority schedule since the inaugu- ration of the "new course" is unavailable at present. From the end of the war until mid-1948 the procurement of reparations in one form or another dominated Soviet economic policy in East Germany, and throughout the entire postwar period reparations policy has been the most important single factor influencing East German economic development. The following brief account of Soviet reparations policy and practice is necessary in order to give per- spective to the recent Soviet announcement that reparations are to cease beginning on 1 January 1954. The Yalta and Potsdam Agreements asserted the principle that Germany should compensate to the greatest extent possible for the damage caused to the Allied nations. 28/ At Yalta the USSR demanded $10 billion worth of capital equipment and goods from current pro- duction at 1938 prices as reparations from Germany. The Allies did not reach final agreement on the subject, but the USSR has continued to use the figure of $10 billion as the basis for its reparations claims. 29/ The Potsdam Agreement (of August 1945) provided that the reparations claims of the USSR should be met by removal of capital equipment and current production from the zone of Germany occupied by the USSR and by seizure of appropriate German external assets. 30/ The Potsdam Agreement provided further that payment of reparations should leave enough resources to enable the German people to subsist without external assistance. 31/ * Soviet enterprise in East Germany engaged in mining uranium ore. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C,-R-E-T War damage and dismantling reportedly reduced the capacity of East German industry to about 50 percent of 1936 capacity. 32 About 30 percent of the total reduction was due to war damage, and about 70 percent to dismantling. 33/* In view of the subsequent rapid recovery of production, these estimates of reduced capacity appear to be based on inability of plants to operate because of loss of essential machinery, rather than on complete loss of fixed capital. In December 1945 the SMA ordered. some 200 of the largest and most important factories transferred to Soviet ownership and manage- ment- 34 It has been alleged that these plants were originally scheduled for dismantling as reparations but were saved, in the words of Marshal Sokolovskiy, "in order to provide employment and part of the output for the German economy." 35 These Soviet corporations, which are known by the abbreviation SAG," for Sowjetische (later Staatliche) Aktiengesellschaften, are administered by USIG (Upravleniye Sovetskovo Imushtchestvo v' Germanii -- Administration of Soviet Prop- erty in Germany)'. 36 The SAG's are registered in Germany as public companies of limited liability owned by the USSR. 37 The SAG's pay the USSR a yearly rent for the property and installations and also their profits, if any. 38 It is reported that they are subsidized from the East German budget in the event losses are incurred. 39 Investment in the SAG's also is believed. to come out of the East Ger- man budget, but it is assumed that these sums are credited to the Soviet reparations account. 40 Most of the production of the SAG's, especially in recent years, has been sent to the USSR as reparations, exports, or profits in kind. 41 Soviet authorities were reported to have returned 74 SAG's to German ownership (as nationalized firms) in 1947, and they returned 23 in May 1950 and 66 more in May 1952. 42 According to the Soviet-East German Protocol of 23 August 1953, the remaining 33 SAG's (not including SAG Wismut) are to be returned, without compensation, to German ownership on 1 January 1954. 43 The SAG's returned in 1950 and 1952 and possibly those returned in 1947 had to be paid for by the Germans. 44 The Protocol of 23 Aug- ust 1953 provided that the remaining, East German debt of DME (Deutsche Mark East) 430 million for the 66 SAG's returned in 1952 would be canceled. 45 * The West German Social Democratic Party (SPD) estimates the value of war booty and dismantled factories at about RM.(Reichsmark) 5 billion for each category. ** These figures leave four SAG's unaccounted for, but they probably were absorbed by other SAG's. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T From 1945 until the present time, the SAG's have formed a powerful economic empire within East Germany. The value of the pro- duction of the last 33 SAG's to be returned is estimated to be from 15 to 18 percent of the total value of industrial production in East Germany. 46 The SAG's are included in the Five Year Plan, but their production plans and material requirements have had to be accepted in toto by the East German planning authorities. L7/ There is little evidence to indicate that the USSR does not intend to relinquish direct control over the SAG's as provided by the Protocol. In the absence of information to the contrary, it must be assumed that the USSR considers the political advantage to be gained in giving up the SAG's to be worth the loss of about DME 400 million a year in profits from the last 33 SAG's 48 and the loss of direct control over an important segment of East German industry. SAG Wismut was founded by the Soviet authorities in 1945 or 1946 for the purpose of mining uranium ore in East Germany. 49 It is ultimately supervised by the Council of Ministers of the USSR. About 300 ore-bearing shafts in the neighborhood of Aue in Saxony and Saalfeld in Thuringia are being worked. 50 Including subsidiaries that supply the mines with equipment, SAG Wismut employed about 225,000 people in the fall of 1951. 51 Working conditions have improved dur- ing the course of time from catastrophic to miserable. 52 Wages are high, but other pressures must be used to force people to work in the mines. 53 The West German Ministry for All-German Questions estimates the yearly cost of SAG Wismut in wages and equipment at DME 2.5 billion. 54 This estimate is based on average 'wage rates and employment and assumes wages to be about.half of total costs. A part of the profits of the other SAG's and the Soviet trading com- panies is reportedly used to help defray the cost of SAG Wismut. 55/ Moreover, payments for the support of SAG Wismut probably are made from the East German budget. 56/ Payments of DME 400 million and DME 600 million in 1950 and 1951, respectively, to the Soviet-owned Guarantee and -Credit Bank are belived to be for this purpose. 57/ The estimated profit of the SAG's for those years is DME 600 million to DME 700 million. 58/ The sum of these two items amounts to only half of the yearly cost of operation of SAG Wismut as estimated by the West German authorities. Other sources of financing are not known but might be the funds taken from East German banks after the capitulation. Withdrawals from the account of the Soviet-owned Guarantee and Credit Bank with the Deutsche Notenbank were about DME 1.1 billion in 1950. 59/ It is understood that this account was almost exhausted by the end of 1950. 60/ In his address before the People's Chamber (Volkskammer) on 25 August 1953, - 11 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Otto Grotewohl stated that a joint Soviet-German Wismut corporation was to be formed on a basis of parity. 61/ It is possible that, the Russians having exhausted hoarded supplies of marks and given up the SAG's as a source of funds, a joint company is being formed as an excuse for continuing to require the East German government to bear a large share of the cost of SAG Wismut. The Soviet trade and transport companies are an important adjunct of Soviet economic activities in. East Germany. They are supervised by the Soviet Trade Delegation in East Germany, which is a subdivision of the Soviet Ministry of Foreign Trade. L2/ There have been as many as 16 Soviet trade and transport companies operating in East Germany, each ostensibly specializing in a group of related products. ?3/* Their main task has been the organization of the export * The Soviet trading and transport companies believed to be operating in East Germany at the present time are as follows: Exportlen (flax, yarn, fibers, jute, cotton, wool, and products made from these materials.) Exportles (such as wood, paper and paper products, and cellulose) Mashinoimport (equipment for mining, metallurgy, power plants, and transport industries) Promexport (coal and chemicals) Promsyr'yeimport (ferrous and nonferrous metals and scrap) Sovexportfilm (Soviet movie film and exchange agency) Soyuzpushchina (furs, pelts, live animals, and fur products) Tekhnoexport (machines for automotive industry, agricultural machinery, tractors, electrical goods, and metal- processing machines) Tekhnopromimport (equipment for the chemical, food-processing, paper, rubber, textile-printing, and leather industries; leather goods; telephone and telegraph equipment; control and precision machines; and laboratory, X-ray, and optical equipment) S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02.: CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T of reparations and SAG goods, but they also have reportedly procured scarce goods for the USSR from Western countries and engaged in all sorts of black-market activities. L4/ As part of the Protocol of 23 August 1953 the Russians announced that reparations from Germany would cease on 1 January 1954. 65 The Protocol stated further that at the end of 1953 the unpaid balance which was to be canceled would amount to $2,537 million. Since in May 1950 the Soviet News Agency announced that -total Soviet reparations demands had been reduced from $10 billion in 1938 prices to $6,829 million, 66 it appears that the USSR by its own calculations will have received from Germany $4,292 million worth of reparations in 1938 prices by the end of 1953. West German authorities agree that $4.3 billion in 1938 prices is a considerable understatement of total Soviet takings from East Germany, excluding occupation costs. The USSR does not recognize as reparations several forms of exploitation of the German economy such as war booty, the expenditure of captured Reichsmark and printed occupation currency, transportation and packing of reparations goods, and profits and rents paid by the SAG's. The .`Weser Germans also believe that additional -payments-'were made to the SAG's and the SMA and that these payments were charged neither to reparations nor to occupation costs. 7~? The West German Social Democratic Party (SPD) gives an esti- mate of total Soviet takings for 1945-52 as IDMF'78.6 billion in current prices, including RM/DME 7.6 billion or occupation costs. 67 The SPD converts this at the rate of RM/DME 2.5 equals $1 to arrive at $31.4 billion, which probably should be considered a maximum esti- mate of total Soviet takings from the German economy. The SPD esti- mate of reparations from current production in 1950 and 1951 is over 2.5 times as high as estimated by State, HICOG, Berlin, for those years. State estimates total Soviet takings for 1950,including occu- pation costs, to have been about DME 6 billion; and for 1951, DME 4 to 4.5 billion. 68 The SPD estimates Soviet takings for 1951, excluding occupation costs, at DME 5,041 million. 69 Addition of DME 1,950 million for occupation costs (the figure used by State and exactly the same as the figure given in the Protocol of 23 August 1953 for 1953 occupation costs) gives an SPD estimate of total takings for 1951 of DME 6,991 million. Since the original data underlying both these estimates are not available, it is not possible to evaluate them, and the figures are given only to indicate the approximate magnitude of Soviet takings. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C -R-E-T A question of considerably greater interest than the value of total reparations is the current value of Soviet takings and the amount of current income from East Germany to be given up by the USSR under the terms of the Protocol of 23 August 1953. The con- cessions in the Protocol affecting current Soviet income from East Germany are the return of the 33 SAG's, the cessation of reparations, the reduction of occupation costs, and the cancelation of the debt of DME 430 million still owing on the 66 SAG's returned in May 1952. 70/ The profits of the SAG's were estimated at DME 600 million to DME 700 million yearly in 1950 and 1951. 71 Since the return of the 66 SAG's in 1952 reduced the SAG's share of East German industrial production from about 25 to 27 percent 72/ to 15 to 18 percent, it is assumed that profits were correspondingly reduced -- that is, to about DME 400 million, disregarding any change in profits from 1951 to 1952. The Protocol announced that occupation costs in 1954 will be DME 350 million less than in 1953. 73 Nothing is known about the rate at which the debt on the 66 SAG's was being paid off, but for the purpose of estimating the annual Soviet takings, a rate of DME 215 million a year in 1954 and 1955 is arbitrarily assumed.* Greatest difficulty is found in estimating reparations from current production, because more information is available and not all of it is consistent. Estimates of reparations from current production range from a high figure of DME 2.4 billion for 1952 reparations given by the SPD 75/ to a low of about DME 1 billion suggested by East Ger- man budget data published by State, HICOG, Berlin. 76/ An intermediate figure of DME 1.4 billion can be derived by applying a dollar-mark conversion ratio of $1 equals 2.5 marks (the prewar rate, which the Russians are said to use) and a price inflator (1.75) to the 1938 dollar figures published by the Soviet sources. By adding to the reparations from current production the estimated SAG profits of DME 400 million, DME 215 million for debt repayment, and DME 350 million for the saving on occupation costs, one arrives at estimates ranging from DME 2 billion to DME 3.4 million as the annual sum which East Germany will be relieved of paying the USSR during the next 2 years. These sums amount to 4.5 and 7.6 percent, respectively, of an esti- mated East German GNP of DME 44 billion in 1953. * This is a minimum estimate. The value of the SAG's returned in 1952 has been estimated at DME 1.6 billion, which would have meant a repayment rate of DME 600 million a year in.1952 and 1953. 74 S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T B. German Economic Organizations. 1. Governmental Organization. The East German central. government came into existence in a de facto sense on 13 February 1948, when the German Economic Commission (Deutsche Wirtschafts Kommission -- DWK) was expanded and given extensive powers by order of the chief of the SCC, Marshal Sokolovskiy. 77 The transfer of power from the provincial govern- ments to the DWK was completed by a transfer of property, in which the largest and most important nationalized firms, whose capacity amounted to two-thirds of the capacity of nationalized industry under German administration, passed from the control of the provincial governments to the DWK. 78 Since the Soviet-appointed membership of the DWK contained a laxge proportion of important members of the SED, the centralization of German governmental organizations increased the influence of the SED. The nature of the relationship between the SED and the DWK was made clear in July 19+8 by the handling of the Two Year Plan. This plan was first presented as the plan of the Party at the Annual Congress of the SED, and it was subsequently adopted by the DWK without substantial change. 79 The SED was at that time, and still is, the de facto German government of East Germany, but its operations are monitored and controlled by the Soviet authorities. The provisional German government proclaimed in October 19+9 was con- firmed by the People's Chamber (Volkskammer), elected from a single list of candidates, on 15 October 1950. 80/ The economic administration of East Germany is concentrated in the Council of Ministers, which consists of a minister president, his 6 deputies, 17 functional ministers, a minister of coordination and control, the chairman of the State Planning Commission, and 6 state secretaries with their own fields of responsibility. 81 The list of ministries includes those customarily found in a European government (for example, foreign affairs, interior, and finance) and other ministries whose functions are directly related to the manage- ment of the nationalized industry (for example, the Ministry of Heavy Machine Construction). The ministries concerned with the adminis- tration of nationalized industry have been reorganized almost yearly. In the latest reorganization, announced on 4 November 1953, a new Ministry of Heavy Industry has been created which will take over the S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T functions of the former Ministry of Metallurgy and Mining; the State Secretariat for Coal and Energy; and the State Secretariat for Chemi- cals, Stones, and Earths. J Three important reorganizations of the East German govern- ment took place in 1952. The first occurred under the "Law on the Government of the German Democratic Republic" of 23 May 1952, which incorporated the following essential features 83/: a. It increased the number of deputy prime ministers from 5 to 6 and added a minister without; portfolio to be in charge of coordination and control. b. It established five coordination and control bodies within the Office of the Minister President. c. It authorized the government to adapt its structure to the requirements of the economic plan by acting on its own decision. d. It extended the right of the Council of Ministers to establish autonomous state secretariats assigned to special tasks. The second reorganization established a Presidium within the Council of Ministers on 17 July 1952. 84 The Presidium is the top executive body in the East German government and consists of 7 voting and 7 nonvoting members. The nonvoting members are the five chiefs of the coordination and control offices, the Chairman of the State Planning Commission, and the Chairman. of the Central Commission for State Control. The law of 23 July 1952 on the "Further Demo- cratization of the Structure and Functioning of the State Organs in the Laender of the German Democratic Republic" abolished the last vestige of federalism in East Germany. This third reorganization provided for the following 85/: a. The replacement of the 5 Land governments by 14 Bezirke (administrative districts). 143 to 217. b. An increase in the number of Kreise (counties) from c. The transfer of the functions of the Land governments to the central government and the Bezirk councils. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T d. The dismissal or reassignment of the personnel of the Land governments to the new Bezirk councils. As a result of these changes, the government of East Germany approximates more closely the Soviet model for the operation of a centrally planned and directly controlled economy. An uncon- firmed report received on 6 November 1953 states that a further reorganization of the GDR government has taken place. 86 According to this report, the coordination and control bodies have been abolished, but a new "Office of the Council of Ministers" designed to implement Council decisions has been created. This new office is reported to have under it a larger number of control groups. The staff of the "Office of the Council of Ministers" is reported to consist of Grotewohl, Ulbricht, Leuschner, Stoph, Rau, Selbmann, and Wach. If this report is true, it indicates a greater degree of centralization of power in the hands. of these men. 2. Extent of State Control of the Economy. The German-owned nationalized enterprises (Volkseigene Betriebe -- VEB) derived initially from the expropriation of firms owned by the government and leading Nazis. On 30 June 19+6 the people of Saxony voted "yes" to a referendum calling for the expro- priation and socialization of factories owned by "nationalist mo- nopoly capital and Hitlerite fascists," and this decision was en- forced throughout East Germany without much more ado. 87 Although the Soviet-owned plants and the German-owned nationalized enterprises together comprised not more than 10 percent of the number of plants in East Germany, it is estimated that they accounted for about 75 percent of the total value of industrial production in 1950. L8/ According to Ulbricht, this share had risen to 80 percent by the end of 1952. 89 The goal of the Five Year Plan is that 81.2 percent of total production is to be produced by nationalized and comparable (SAG) firms by 1955. 90 The Five Year Plan implies that this increase in the share of nationalized industry in industrial production is to come about through a relatively greater increase in the production of the nationalized sector. The Plan provides that the value of the pro- duction of the nationalized firms* shall increase during the 5 years by 12+.8 percent, while the production of private industry is to in- crease by 66.7 percent and the production of handicrafts by 66.5 percent. 91 * Presumably not including SAG's. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Heavy industry is entirely nationalized in East Germany. The 20 percent of industrial production still in private hands is restricted almost entirely to small-scale consumers' goods industries, such as flour mills, clothing firms, woodworking establishments, and handicrafts. 92 There also are several thousand small machine shops. 93 Handicrafts undoubtedly comprise the largest part of pri- vate industry. In 1949 there were 304,000 handicraft shops employ- ing about 980,000 people in East Germany. 94 These establishments are required to belong to the Handicraft Chambers in their localities and are encouraged, mainly by tax privileges and larger supplies of raw materials, to form handicraft cooperatives. 95 Handicrafts are regulated by the "Law for the Advancement of Handicrafts" of 16 March 1951. 96/ This law provides, among other things, that in order to secure materials, a handicraft establishment must conclude contracts with the State Contract Office (Vertragskontor), or with a nation- alized firm, thus tying the handicraft firms to the directly planned sector. Prices and wages in the handicraft trades are fixed by law. The consequence is that, though private industry still exists, very little scope is left for private initiative. German telephone and -telegraph communications and rail transport were nationalized before the war. In addition, barge and truck transport are now nationalized. Wholesale trade in East Ger- many today is almost completely nationalized. German Trade Controls (Deutsche Handelszentrale -- DHZ's) for each principal industry are subordinate to the ministry to which their industry belongs and operate as wholesalers for the nationalized industry. 97 State Con- tract Offices operate as wholesalers on the local level for private industry and the cooperatives. 98/ The Associations of People's Owned Procurement and Purchasing Enterprises (Vereinigungen Volks- eigener Erfassungs- and Aufkaufbetriebe -- VVEAB) function both as wholesalers of agricultural products and purchasing agents for private, cooperative, and nationalized farms. 99 Next to agriculture, retail trade and the professions have the largest proportions of private enterprise of any sector of the economy. Retail trade is carried on by the state-owned shops (Handelsorganizationen -- HO's), the consumers' cooperatives, and private firms. 100/ In 1950, the last full year for which actual data are available, 26.6 percent of the total retail trade was handled by the HO's, 16.8 percent by the cooperatives, and 56.5 percent by private firms. The Plan for 1955 was 40.7 percent of turnover to be handled by the HO's, 25 percent by the cooperatives, and 34.3 percent by private firms. 101/ S-E-C.-R-E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 . S -E -C -R-E -T The banking system of East Germany has been entirely nationalized since 1946 and completely centralized since the end of 1950. The system consists of the German Bank of Issue (Deutsche Notenbank), with 14 branches and about 300 subsidiaries and deposi- tories; the German Investment Bank, with 15 branches and 23 sub- sidiaries; the German Farmers' Bank, with 14 branches and 3,150 State loan offices run by the Farmers' Trade Cooperatives; the 125 Savings Banks, with 2,300 depositories; and the Guarantee and Credit Bank, which is Soviet-bwned.and handles all of the banking of the Soviet High Commission, the GOFG, the SAG, and the Soviet trading and transport companies. 102 Agriculture is the least socialized sector of the econ- omy of East Germany. Until July 1952, collectivization of agri- culture was approached only indirectly in East Germany. The land reform of 1945, in which-estates over 100 hectares were broken up and distributed to owners of small- and medium-size holdings and to expellees, seemed to be a step in the opposite direction. By the end of 1949, only 1 percent of the farms were over 125 acres, and 78 percent were under 25 acres. 103/ It is probable that many of the new farms were deliberately made too small to be economically operated and that the USSR intended to achieve collectivization in East Germany gradually through the voluntary cooperation of the farmers with Machine Tractor Stations (MTS's)* and the Farmers' Mutual Aid Association (Vereinigung der gegenseitigen Bauernhilfe -- VdgB). The MTS's, which were founded in 1949, took over the tractors and equipment acquired from farms expropriated under the land reform. Starting out with about 4,800 usable tractors, the, number of MTS's increased to 585 active stations with a park of about 20,000 tractors (calculated in terms of 30-horsepower units). 104 These stations do not lend their machines but send their operators and equipment out to the farms to plow and harvest. Fees per hectare of work per- formed increase with the size of the farm, a measure designed to divide the peasantry into opposing factions with a view toward voluntary collectivization.of the smaller farmers and eventual elim- ination of the larger units. 105/ The VdgB, which during the early years of the occupation was the collecting agency for agricultural products, was amalgamated with the village cooperatives (Bauerliche Handelsgenossenschaften -- BHG's) in 1950, and the collection function was transferred to the VVEAB. 106/ The VdgB is now primarily a political organization, but it also handles some purchasing of supplies for the farmers and agricultural loans. The VVEAB, in con- junction with the Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, plans and Formerly Machine Lending Stations (MAS's). - 19 - S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T sets the quotas for, and prices of, farm products to be delivered each year. Both prices and quotas have tended to discriminate against large farmers. 107 These organizational changes in agri- culture parallel changes in other Satellites in Europe, but the Sovietization of agriculture is less advanced in East Germany than in the other Satellites. State farms (Volkseigene Gueter -- VEG's) have existed in East Germany since 1949. There are now about 513 VEG's with an estimated agricultural area of 212,000 hectares, or approximately 4 percent of the total arable land. 108 The VEG's are supposed to function as experimental and model farms, and as sources of seed and breeding stock. Collectivization of agriculture as a goal of agricultural policy was admitted by the SED for the first time at the Second Paxty Conference in July 1952, when a program for the formation of agri- cultural cooperatives was announced. 109 Although the formation of the cooperatives was ostensibly voluntary, farmers were subjected to a variety of pressures to get them to join. By mid-1953 there were 3,255 agricultural production cooperatives (Landwirtschaftliche Productiongenossenschaften -- LPG's) farming 14+ percent of the total arable land. 110 Most of the cooperatives were small. The average size was estimated to be about 125 hectares of arable land farmed by 21 members and their families. 3. Economic Planning. The East German State Planning Commission receives yearly from the Economic Planning Department of the SCC mandatory goals for the production of key products. 111 How detailed these goals are is not definitely known, but it is likely that they comprise the 90-odd basic materials and commodity groups shown.in the "Key Positions of the People's Economic Plan." 112 The key position figures re- ceived from the SCC are expanded by the State Planning Commission to include additional products and product groups, and it is this list of production targets, called "control-figures" (Kontrollziffern), to which the remainder of production and all resource allocation must adjust. Good authority states that there were 300 such figures in the 1952 planning. 113 These control figures for the yearly plans are distributed by the State Planning Commission to the appropriate ministries and state secretariats, which expand them further and distribute the production targets to the nation ized firms, directly S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T in some cases and in others through the associations of nationalized firms or the Bezirk administration. 114 The nationalized firms then work out requirements plans incorporating the material, labor, investment, and subsidies necessary to meet the Plan goals expressed in the control figures. According to the West German Ministry for All-German Questions, these control figures can in no way be lowered by the ministries, state secretariats, or nationalized firms but are frequently raised by them. 115/ The requirements plans follow the same route back to the State Planning Commission and are adjusted and aggregated at each higher administrative level. The State Planning Commission then "balances" the material requirements with available resources and, in consultation with the Ministry of Finance, draws up the plans for production, investment, finance, export, import, and material and labor supply. 116 Additions to state reserves may be incorporated into planned production to meet emergency production requirements. The individual plans are reported to be synchronized exactly in quantitative terms only with respect to the key positions laid down by the Russians. For the other products, only a rather general or aggregative balancing takes place. 117 A good many reports were received near the end of 1951 about unrealistic goals laid on from above and about insufficient knowledge on the part of the State Planning Commission of actual capacities and lead times. 118 Thereafter, occasional references were made to planning "from below to above instead of from above to below." 119 The first of a series of articles in Die Wirtschaft, entitled Balancing in Economic Planning," stresses the point that since all parts of the economy are related, all parts of the Plan must be worked out simultaneously. 120 This view is borne out by the procedures for preparation of the Economic Plan for 1953, passed by the East German Cabinet on 30 May 1952. 121 The ministries, state secretariats, and Land governments were directed to instruct the nationalized firms to begin preparatory work immediately for the 1953 Plan, to establish contracts immediately with each other, and to conclude temporary contracts. for 1953 in order to guarantee the sale of the items to be produced in 1953. 122 The Ministry of Foreign and Domestic Trade* was likewise directed to begin prepara- tions for 1953 trade agreements. All of this was to take place * Ministerium fuer Aussenhandel and Innerdeutschen Handel. Inner- deutschen here means "interzonal." In translating Innerdeutschen as t Domestic," the State Department convention is followed. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T before the confirmation of the 1953 control figures by the Cabinet. It appears that the nationalized firms are directed to start planning on the basis of the production of the previous year and of the goals of the Five Year Plan. The place of private enterprise in the system is not clear. In those cases where the products of a private firm are consumed by a nationalized firm, the nationalized firm contracts for the production of the private firm and receives an allocation of raw materials for transmittal to the private firm. Otherwise, private firms receive their allocations of raw material (if any) from the State Contract Offices under the Bezirk and Kreis administrations. 123/ Generally, the Bezirk administrations receive their control figures only in value terms. Occasionally, when there is a private firm in the Bezirk whose production is particularly important, control figures are received in quantitative terms. 124 The nationalized firms receive their production quotas in quantitative and value terms or only in value terms, depending upon the nature and relative importance of the product. Production is planned in terms of Plan prices, or Messwerten. Messwerten, literally translated, means "measuring values." They are based on the prices used in the 1950 Plan, which were, for the most part, current prices. 125 The Messwerten were fixed for the duration of the Five Year Plan and were intended to take the place of a price index -- that is, to permit the measurement of the change in production in constant prices. The Messwerten apply to the gross production of a factory as defined by the products contained in the General Commodity Code (Allgemeine Warenverzeichnis), regardless of whether or not they are consumed entirely or in part within the factory. 126 In some aspects of planning, such as the planning of sales, current prices are used. These prices take the usual form of factory, wholesale, and retail, with the latter divided into HO prices and rationed prices. Current prices are fixed by law. They derive originally from the 1944 ceiling prices, which were continued in effect by order of the chief of the SMA, 127 but they have been changed piecemeal over the years. The East German planning authorities intend eventually to recalculate all prices on the basis of the Marxian labor theory of value. 128 They do not seem to have solved in theory the prob- lem of expressing in prices relative scarcity deriving from demand. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T In practice, the problem is partially solved on an ad hoc basis by manipulating the turnover tax rates on retail sales and by the use of a priorities system for allocating raw materials and components within the nationalized economy. Although the "balancing" of planned production and material requirements by the State Planning Commission theoretically equates supply and demand, it has not balanced supply and demand in practice. Goods have been produced according to Plan which could not be sold at fixed. prices, while at the same time the raw materials used in their production have been in short supply. The import plans seem never to be fulfilled on time, and raw material shortages are chronic. In order to assist the economy in balancing supply and demand as planned by the State Planning Commission, the "Law on the Introduction of the General Contract System for Goods Deliveries in the Nationalized and Comparable Industry" was passed in December 1951. 129 This law provides that within a month after the distribution of Plan goals to the firms, they must complete contracts with other firms and with import and export agencies for both their material requirements and the sale of their products. Financial penalties are imposed on the firm for nonfulfillment of these contracts. The General Contracts Court has been set up to handle disputes arising from the operation of this law. The result of these cases has usually been that no penalty has been imposed., because the nonfulfillment can be traced back to an event for which nobody in East Germany can be blamed, often to the nonfulfillment of the import plan. The law provides, however, an important in- centive to the factory manager to fulfill his production plan, since by the "Lag on the Reorganization of the People's Owned Indus- try" of 22 December 1950, the individual firm manager is responsible for operating the firm as economically as possible. 130 Before the passage of this law, profits and losses were equalized among the firms belonging to an association of nationalized firms (Vereinigung Volkseigener Betriebe -- VVB's). Financial planning in East Germany serves the purpose of control rather than direction, the latter being determined by the over-all economic plan. The nationalized firms receive their circulating capital from the Deutsche Notenbank and pay it back according to plan. Profits, subsidies, and the reduction of operating costs are planned. Until 1953, amortization funds were paid into the state treasury and redistributed by the German Invest- ment Bank, not as loans, but as grants, to industry for investment S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T purposes. Beginning in 1953, nationalized firms must use their amortization funds and may use a part of their profits for planned investment. 131 Additional funds for investment are available through the German Investment Bank. Of course, no investment may be undertaken that is not planned, and the banking system is directed to see that funds are spent only as planned. The currency plan is an important aspect of East German financial controls. Under the "Law for Control of Payments," dated 21 April 1950, 132 particularly under its second implementation of 28 June 1950, a.sharp distinction is made between two different groups of money users. The first group comprises practically all private persons, small tradesmen with a yearly turnover of less than DME 20,000, landlords with less than DME 250 monthly income, and mem- bers of the professions with less than three employees. The second group comprises the bulk of the economy -- that is, all other persons, enterprises, and organizations. The use of cash is restricted mainly to the first group. Private persons are subject to no limitations as to its internal use. Since bank accounts of private persons and of small private industry are kept exclusively with the savings banks or cooperative banks, it is easy to handle them differently from the accounts of the rest of the economy. 133 The enterprises and organizations are permitted.to accept cash, but they may not spend such receipts as cash except in trans- actions amounting to no more than DME 50. Otherwise, they are under obligation to pay all cash receipts immediately into accounts with credit institutions. 13 For payment of wages, they receive the required cash from the credit institutions, subject to submission of their payrolls. Since the Deutsche Notenbank knows the wage bill, retail turnover, and savings deposited in banks for any given period, the Notenbank can theoretically calculate the amount of cash being hoarded and going into illegal trade. The Deutsche Notenbank has a phobia about inflating the currency and apparently confuses the amount of hand-to-hand money with the total supply of money. It has maintained the amount of currency in circulation almost constant at about DME 3.5 billion since the end of 1949, 135/ despite rising wages and an increase in retail turnover. As a result of this procedure, a serious shortage of hand-to-hand currency has developed in East Germany. 136 It is uncertain whether the shortage is a result of a miscalculation on the part of the Notenbank as to the amount of currency needed or S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T whether sizable sums are being hoarded. Toward the end of 1951 the Notenbank calculated that about DME 2,100 million in circulation could not be accounted for. 137 This amounted to roughly DME 300 per capita of all gainfully employed persons. 138 It is highly unlikely that this sum was evenly distributed among the population, because the scale of living has been so low that many such cash hoards would have become effective demand for unrationed goods in the HO's. State, HICOG, Berlin, concludes that "the SED, the semi- official trading organization, the occupation power, economic enter- prises (particularly private industry), trade and agriculture, and black marketeers have large cash holdings and that there are large- scale transactions in the economy outside the plan." 139 Because currency has become scarce, the Notenbank may have concluded that cash hoards are larger now than in 1951. The real or fancied existence of this unaccounted-for cash may be one reason for the frequent rumors of an impending currency reform in East Germany. Such rumors, however, cannot always be accepted as reliable indi- cators, because currency reform rumors are the stock in trade of black marketeers of currency. If the East German authorities contemplated a currency reform, it is likely that it was to assist in the program for "build- ing socialism."* A currency reform would not be consistent with the present policy of increasing the real income of the population. A reform that did not touch savings in banks might, however, be politi- cally feasible. C. Economic Policy. The organization of the economy described above was virtually complete by the end of 1950, with the exception of the agricultural cooperatives. East German economic policy from 1950 until mid-1952 concentrated on fulfilling the goals of the Five Year Plan and im- proving the functioning of the existing organization. Further sociali- zation was played down and the theme of German unity emphasized. 140 In July 1952 the Second Party Conference of the SED signaled an abrupt shift in policy. The conference announced that the time had arrived for East Germany to proceed with "building socialism." According to the decisions of the conference, the building of social- ism required the following 11+1: * The program for "building socialism" consists of the various meas- ures for Sovietization of the economy and for its development under centralized planning following the Soviet model. See C, below. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T 1. The creation of a national army. 2. The strengthening of the state through a reorganization of the government and the rewriting of the labor, civil, and criminal codes. 3. The creation of the economic basis for socialism by quickly breaking the bottlenecks in basic industries, increasing labor productivity, improving the quality of production, and so on. 4. The formation of agricultural producers' cooperatives. 5. The strengthening of the ideological orientation of Party members and the elimination of the last vestiges of capitalistic thought and methods from the nationalized economy. Following the Second Party Conference, the atmosphere of terror and oppression in East Germany increased appreciably. Persecution of the churches increased, and membership in Protestant youth groups was made ground for dismissal from school. Prosecution of farmers and other private business men for tax evasion and sabotage increased. In October the "Law for the Protection of the People's Property" was passed. 142 This vague law provided stiff penalties for incorrect reporting in the nationalized economy and for failing to report an instance of planned or actual crime against the nationalized economy, as well as for the usual crimes of theft and embezzlement. Recruiting for the People's Police was stepped up, and restrictions on interzonal travel were increased. In January 1953 a law was passed forbidding East Germans to make any contact with representatives of Western governments and international organizations except through the Foreign Office. 143 In January also the Central Committee of the SED recom- mended that the efficiency of the distribution system be improved by removing all capitalistic influence from wholesale trade and by expanding local retail cooperatives. 144 Quotas for the delivery of meat animals, milk, and eggs were raised. in January. 145 In February 1953 the law on the "Safeguarding of Agricultural Production and the Supply of the People" was passed. 146 This law provided that a farmer who, in the judgment of the Bezirk council, violated the law or did not operate his farm according to regulations could be dis- possessed of his farm and that the farm could be turned over to the agricultural cooperatives. In March the income tax for private firms was increased. 147/ In April, ration cards were taken away from the self-employed and owners of private industry and trade. 148 - 26 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T On 14 May the Central Committee of the SED called for a 10-percent increase in working norms, effective 1 June 1953. L29/ The introduction of these repressive and unpopular measures leading to more complete Sovietization coincided with a severe food shortage, brought on partly by a very poor harvest of root crops in 1952 but aggravated by greatly increased deliveries of foodstuffs to the state reserves and by the drive for collectivization. Beginning in the second half of 1952, the influx of refugees from East Germany into West Germany rose.sharply, and it reached unprecedented propor- tions in the first half of 1953.* About 340,000 people fled to the West between June 1952 and July 1953. 150 D. The "New Course." On 9 June 1953 the Central Committee of the SED recommended a number of measures than amounted to an abrupt reversal of the repressive tactics of the previous year. The recommendations were accompanied by the admission that the government and Party decisions of the past year and the manner in which they had been enforced had been responsible for the mass exodus from East Germany. 151 The measures recommended by the SED and subsequently adopted by the government included; (1) a reduction of the rate of investment in heavy industry and an increase in the production and distribution of consumers' goods; (2) some rehabilitation of the private sector of trade and industry; (3) some reduction of pressure on the private sector of agriculture, including repeal of the laws on "Safeguarding Agricultural Production and the Supply of the People" and "Devastated Agricultural Land," (4) nonretaliation against refugees returning from West Germany and the return of confiscated property; (5) easing of restrictions on travel between East and West Germany; (6) aban- donment of the campaign against the churches and Protestant youth organizations and the release of arrested pastors; (7) amnesty for persons sentenced to 3 years or less for economic crimes; and (8) issuance of ration cards to all persons. No mention was made of repealing the increase in working norms. On 17 June, widespread rioting occurred throughout East Germany, beginning ostensibly as a protest against increased working norms. The riots,were stopped by the intervention of Soviet troops and tanks. * For a discussion of migration, see IV, E. below. - 27 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T On 21 June 1953 the Central Committee of the SED recommended further concessions, including (1) repeal of the minimum 10-percent increase in working norms which had been ordered in May to take effect in June, (2) an increase in social security benefits and the reduction of contributions to former levels, (3) an increase of over DME 600 million in the value of housing construction and social facilities as compared with 1952, and (4) the abolition of electric power cuts for householders. 152 In succeeding months, announcements of measures to improve the standard of living of the populace have increased in number and importance. The most important of these measures are (1) an increase in wage rates for the.four lowest wage groups, and for doctors, dentists, and pharmacists; (2) a decrease in taxes on wages and on incomes from private business; (3) price reductions on over 12,000 consumers' goods; (4) reductions in compulsory deliveries of agri- cultural products; and (5) announcement of quantitative changes in the plan to decrease investments in heavy industry and to increase the production of consumers' goods. 153 Nearly every member of the East German government who has spoken on the "new course" has quantified the value of the planned increase in real income. The latest estimate was by Foreign Minister Bolz, who said on 7 November that "the population had benefited to the extent of DME 3.4 billion in the second half of 1953." L/ On 26 October, Grotewohl gave DME 3.8 billion as the value of measures taken under the "new course," but the period and the items covered were not specified. 155 The most detailed and internally consistent account of the financial aspects of the "new course" was given by Grotewohl in a speech before the Volkskammer on 29 July 1953. 156 It can be calculated from Grotewohl's figures that the increase in real income from wage increases and price and tax reductions is DME 1.4 billion. Late in October, prices and taxes were reduced further. In his October speech, Grotewohl gave figures of DME 540 million for the value of the latter price cuts and DME 450 million as the value of the tax cuts, but the period to which he referred is not clear. 157 If these latter figures are on an annual basis, then for November-December DME 165 million more should be added to the planned increase in real income during the second half of 1953. This gives a total of DME 1,565 million as the added benefit to the population from wage increases and price and tax reductions. The average monthly wage bill originally planned for 1953 was probably something over DME 2.1 billion. 158 S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T The planned increase in retail turnover in the second half of 1953 is DME 5 billion over actual turnover during the-first half. A part of this increase was originally planned as ,.a normal"seasonal increase. About DME 2.4 billion worth of goods, in pre-July prices, are to be available in the second half of 1953 in addition to those originally planned. According to Grotewohl, the sources of these goods are imports from the USSR and added production from domestic sources under the revised plans. 159 Aggregative data on the value of increased imports from,the USSR during the second half of 1953 are not available, but during July the number of freight cars bringing grain into East Germany from the USSR reportedly increased-by 74 percent over theaverage for the previous 9 months. 160 A'phenomenal increase in the move- ment. of refrigerator cars into. East Germany from the USSR also was observed. Previously a monthly average of 100 to 150 loaded refrig- erator cars entered East Germany from the USSR. In July this traffic of meat, fruits, and vegetables is reported to have increased to 1,256 carloads, an increase of over 700 percent. 161- Refrigerator car traffic from Hungary, Rumania, and Bulgaria was reported at the normal rate. These countries did; however, make refrigerator cars, available for food shipments into East Germany from the USSR.- A normal seasonal increase in supplies of food took place during July and August. Additional meat, fats, and textiles appeared on the market in July; apparently released from state. reserves as announced by the government. Ration cards appear to have been fully honored since the beginning of the "new course."- Accord- ing to reports in East German newspapers., the elimination of electric power cuts to households has- not been accomplished, but improvements in that direction are reported. 162 It appears that in its initial stages the improvement in the.. scale of living promised under the "new course"-is-being implemented with imports from the USSR and from domestic reserves.-The important question is whether or not.East Germany can continue to improve the scale of living and pay off its' foreign trade debt from. its;,;own resources. It seems that this is quite possible.. The cessation of reparations deliveries and other uncompensated deliveries will free a minimum of 4.4 percent of GNP and 8.8,.:percent of .industrial goods output for East German use in 'consumption' or investment . In. the. recent past, reparations goods have been largely machinery and fine mechanical optical. equipment. .Not much of the capacity: of the firms -29- S-E-C=R-E-TI Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T formerly producing reparations goods can be used directly to increase the scale of living, but the goods formerly sent to the USSR as reparations presumably can now be exported. Excess capacity is also available in the consumers' goods industries of East Germany.* The leaders of the SED have reiterated that the "new course" is not a. retreat from socialism but is merely a better way of achieving it. They have stated that the general line of the Party was and remains correct. 163 In this they have been consistent. None of the measures taken under the "'new course" would reduce the level of socialization achieved by the summer of 1952, although a minor retreat from mid-1953 levels took place. The pace of invest- ment in heavy industry has apparently slackened, and a real increase in the scale of living has taken place. In the long run, this policy should serve the USSR better than the harsh measures under- taken to build up socialism in the summer of 1952. There is evidence that the very speed of the investment program resulted in considerable waste of resources. A slowly rising scale of living should do much to allay unrest among the East German people and at least reduce active resistance. The USSR thus can continue to hold out the promise of German unity while consolidating its hold upon East Germany and particularly upon the minds of its youth. II. Economic Development of East Germany. A. Over-All Development. East.Germany, including East Berlin, had in 1945 approximately one-third of the total area, population, arable land, and industrial capacity of "Potsdam" Germany. 164 Before the war the area now known as East Germany (the West Germans refer to it as "mittel Deutschland") "exported" to the :rest of Germany about as much as it "imported" in value, sending out one type of agricultural product (grain, potatoes, and sugar) in return for another (dairy produce, meat, edible fats, and livestock) and exchanging such industrial commodities and raw materials as optics, precision instruments, textile and printing machinery, textiles, newsprint, and lignite against heavy machinery, bearings, rubber products, iron, and steel. 165 Before the war, industry and agriculture each produced a slightly higher share of the regional GNP in East Germany than in * The changes in the production and investment plans connected with the "new course" are discussed in II, below. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T West Germany. !L6/ In the prewar economy, when the relative roles of West and East German industries are compared, it can be.said roughly that West Germany was the producer of basic materials and that East Germany contained predominantly the processing and fin- ishing industries. 167 The industrial composition of the East German economy is shown in Table 1. East dermany.is the most industrialized country in the Soviet Bloc. The percentage of GNP produced in industry was larger in East Germany than in any other Bloc country, and the percentage produced in agriculture was the smallest. In the USSR the comparable percentages in 1952 were 40.5 percent in industry and 21.4 percent in agriculture. Percentage of Gross National Product of East Germany by Sectors al 1,68 1952 Percent of GNP Agriculture 13.0 Industry 49.9 Transport and Communications 5.8 Building 1+.9 Services 13.0 Trade 13.3 a. The product by industrial sectors was calculated from wage and employment data. - 31 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T The GNP of East Germany in 1952 amounted to $15.5 billion (1951 $ US).*' Table 2 shows the trend in the East German GNP. Recovery from the very low` postwar level was rapid, especially after 1948, but the GNP in 1952 was still slightly below the 1938 level. Recent annual rates of increase were 19.5 percent in 1950, 14.6 percent in 1951, and 5.5 percent in 1952. The high rate of increase in 1950 was partly due to a sizable gain in agriculture that resulted from favorable weather conditions. In addition to this, the rapid growth of GNP prior to 1952 represents a recovery from the effects of the war and Soviet dismantlings. The rate of gain in 1952is more nearly the rate that would be expected for the years 1952 to'1955. If the East German economy averages a 5-percent-per- year gain from 1952 to 1955, the GNP in 1955 will be about $17.9 billion (1951 $ US). The "new course" is not likely to affect substantially the over-all'growth of the economy over the next 2 years except insofar as it checks a deterioration of worker morale and productivity. Some gain in production can be expected from the fuller utilization of consumers' goods industries, where considerable excess capacity has existed. Primarily the "new course" will affect the composition of production rather than its over-all growth. Output of consumers' goods will grow more rapidly and producers' goods more slowly than heretofore. B. Industry. When the'Kremlin stopped the removal of capital equipment in 1948, Eat German industrial capacity was less than 50 percent of the'prewar level. 171_ In mid-1948 the SED announced the Plan for 1948 acid the Two Year Plan for 1949-50. 172_ This was the first public mention of either an annual economic plan or a long-term * The dollar value of the GNP for 1952 was arrived at by moving forward an estimate of prewar GNP in dollars by the GNP indexes given in Table 1'. The prewar dollar estimate was obtained from Colin Clark's estimate 169 for prewar. Germany. Ferdinand Grunig''s estimate 170 of West Germany's share in prewar Germany was subtracted and adjustments were made for other territorial changes. The prewar estimate was then inflated to 1951 dollars. * Table 2 follows' on p.- 33 'S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 2 Indexes of Production in East Germany' by Sectors, 1938, 1946-52 1938 Major Sectors Industry 143 Producers' Goods 106 Consumers' Goods 189 Agriculture 114 Transportation 140 Communications 121 GNP 126 Industry Energy Electric Power 68 Solid Fuels 90 POL 28 Nonferrous 150 Ferrous 164 Machinery and Equipment Shipbuilding Bearings Automotive Equipment Electronic Equipment Railway Equipment Machine Tools Chemicals Forestry Products Light and Textile Industries 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 52 61 67 77 100 127. 140` 52 58 68 86 . 100+ ` 123 137 52 64 59 75 100 133 144 69 66 85 85 100 103 101 48 55 66 84 100 112, 120 N.A. N.A. 85 96 100 106 105 N.A. N.A. 76 84 100 115 121 59 70 81 92 100 113 ' 124; 81 76 82 92 100 ,113 r 127 39 58 66 83 loo , 126.., N.A. , 62 23 24 38 N.A.: 3 . N.A.',N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A.; N.A. IQ 31 N A . . N.A. N.A. N.A. 195 N.A. N.A 48:.. 58: 6o N.A. ,,72 74 57 100 ,159 . 100 1Q7 loo 2Q7 100 117 ,..- 10 0 ll 100 2~ 78 39 58 70- 83 100' 100 N A. 56 52 79 100 96 123' 127 122 91 100- 157 1556 62 74 -lo6. S=E-C-R-E-T 74 , 89, 100 ' o5 '`10 . 4g 67 100 113'1-1176 N.A., 202 - 300 1 37 ~8 OFIVY 117 ,25, 1d5 x:1'1 100 99 116.. 136. Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T plan. The Two Year Plan declared that by 1950 industrial production was to reach 81 percent of 1936 and 1.35 percent of 1947. 173 To facilitate this planned increase in production, the USSR reduced reparations deliveries somewhat and stopped dismantling altogether. It was announced in January 1950 that the Two Year Plan would be fulfilled in 18 months instead of 24. L7,4 Industrial production in East Germany revived rapidly after 1948, though at a somewhat lower rate than in West Germany. On the basis of indexes compiled from ORR estimates of the physical production of a number of com- modities, it is, estimated that East German industrial production (1938 = 100) rose from 47 percent in 1948 to 70 percent in 1950 and 98 percent in 1952. 175 West German indexes of industrial production for the same years were 52, 94, and 121 percent of 1938, respectively. 176 Both parts of Germany had a currency reform in 1948, but there the similarity in bases of recovery ends. West Germany received large amounts of free food and raw materials from GARIOA* and Marshall Plan aid and gradually removed wartime and postwar restrictions on the economy. East Germany, however, continued to pay heavy reparations, which reduced the amount of goods available for export and correspondingly reduced the ability to import raw materials and industrial equipment. Restrictions on interzonal trade imposed by both the USSR and the Western Allies worked more to the disadvantage of East than West Germany. Moreover, poor planning by the East German authorities made for inefficient use of resources. The indexes of industrial production compiled by ORR shown in Table 2 indicate approximately the same growth in over-all indus- trial production as that claimed by the East German authorities. For instance, ORR shows total industrial production in 1952 to have been 40 percent higher than in 1950 -- East German authorities claim an increase of 41.4 percent. 177 This is an impressive achievement, particularly in view of the handicaps under which the economy has * Government and Relief in Occupied Areas -- a part of the title of the US law appropriating funds to be used by the US Armed Forces for this purpose. - 34 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T operated.* The ORR indexes also tend to bear out the East German claim that on an over-all basis the goals of the Five Year Plan have been fulfilled. The East German Five Year Plan (1951-55) requires the gross value of industrial production (excluding handicrafts) to increase from DME 23.4 billion in 1950 to DME 45 billion in 1955, a, total increase of 92.3 percent, or an average annual increase of 13.7 per- cent.** 179 Explicit in the Plan are the following aims: (1) independence of East Germany from Western capitalistic countries for supplies of basic materials, (2) great expansion of basic and heavy machine industries, and (3) considerable reduction in the scope of private enterprise. Over the 5-year period the original Plan allocated DME 28.6 billion to net investment, of which DME 5.8 billion were to be for residential and cultural buildings. ILO/ This represents an average of DME 5.7 billion a year, on the average less than 15 percent of GNP. On the surface this would not appear to be an excessive rate of investment and might well be sufficient to provide the industrial basis for the planned increases in production. Nevertheless, the investment plan has not been announced as fulfilled in any of the first 10 quarters of the Five Year Plan, and a reduction in the rate of investment has been announced as a part of the "new course." Four principal factors contributed to the failure of the investment plan: (1) the kind of investment attempted, (2) in- adequate and incorrect planning; (3) reparations and other uncom- pensated deliveries, and (4) curbs on interzonal trade. Under the Five Year Plan, investment has been concentrated in a relatively few key projects in the basic. materials industries and. in the heavy machine building industry. Investment and even. replacement has been neglected in other industries, including transportation. 'East Germany has relatively few technicians well trained for building an iron and ,In West Germany the increase in industrial production for the same period was only 28 percent. 178 It must be borne in mind, however, that in 1950 the West German. economy was at a more advanced stage of recovery than the East German economy. ** This is a lower rate of increase than implied by the planned rates of increase in the production of the nationalized firms and private firms (see p. 17, above). Such apparent inconsistencies are not uncommon in published East German accounts of both plans and achievement. - 35 S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T steel industry or a heavy machine construction industry. Conse- quently, many serious mistakes were made in plans, and the plans were never completed on time. Political considerations often interfered, with disastrous results. The premature firing of the first blast. furnace at the Stalin Kombinat (formerly the Iron and Steel Combine East) is an example perhaps extreme in its results but typical in origin. In order to have the firing coincide with the anniversary of the October Revolution, the furnace was fired before the equipment had been adequately tested; the blowers broke down; and the charge solidified, causing great damage to the furnace. Reparations de- liveries and some other forms of uncompensated deliveries had a greater adverse effect on the investment program than their total value in re- lation to ONP (about 5 to 8 percent, excluding occupation costs*) would indicate, because the bulk of reparations deliveries in recent years have been products of the machine industry, especially the heavy machine and electroengineering industries. Products of these indus- tries were especially needed for the investment program. Similarly, the restrictions on interzonal trade deprived East Germany of iron and steel and equipment needed for the investment program. Although the gross production plans were announced as fulfilled every year until the first quarter of 1953, in each year the nonful- fillment of production plans for a number of important products was announced. In 1952 these were bituminous coal and heavy machinery., 1811 In 1951, building materials, crude steel, rolling. mill products from nonferrous metals, metallurgical equipment, and some chemicals were among the products whose production plans were not fulfilled. 182 In the first and second quarters of 1953 the following products were among those whose production plans were not fulfilled: electric power, coal, copper ore, copper, power machine construction, steam turbines, revolving lathes, freight cars, trucks, electric generators, sulfuric acid, various textiles, and food products. 183- The investment plan of the nationalized industry for the first quarter of 1953 was announced as being "by far not fulfilled," although a substantial increase over the preceding year was shown. 184+ The nonfulfillment of the invest- ment plan meant that a great many projects were only partially com- pleted, thus tying up materials and labor without achieving the planned increases in capacity. At the same time, the shortage of materials resulted in an underutilization of capacity in some indus- tries. * Based on a GNP estimate of about DME 41.6 billion in 1952 and the reparations estimates, I, A, above. - 36 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Leaders. of the SED have emphasized that the changes in the production and investment plans under the."new course" are designed to eliminate "disproportions" in the economy, and to bring the speed of "socialist construction" into line with existing economic capacities as well as to improve the scale of living. Ulbricht in a speech before the Central Committee of the SED on 19 September said; "The ministries and administrative authorities ... as well as the enter- prises and various organizations of the GDR must be guided above all by the principle that existing capacities must be fully utilized so that investment funds may be used in particular for the expansion and reconstruction of enterprises actually in operation. This will make it possible to increase production at a lower cost and within a shorter time to the extent necessary to meet the requirements of the people and the economy." 185 The announced changes in plans bear out this general statement of policy. In discussing the revised plan for the second half of 1953, Bruno Leuschner, Chairman of the State Planning Commission, stated that the revised figures for total volume of gross production were not substantially different from those in the original plan. 186 Grotewohl revealed that for the-entire year the plan was to be changed, so that heavy industry would produce DME 1.4 billion less, while the light industries and foodstuffs industries would produce DME 950 mil- lion more. 187 According to the resolution of the Central Committee of the SED, heavy industrial production in 1953 as compared with 1952 was to rise 5.5 to 6 percent instead of the originally planned 13 per- cent, and light industrial production was to increase by 10 percent instead of 7.1 percent. 188. According to Grotewohl, planned investments in 1953 had been reduced by DME 1.7 billion from the amount in the original plan. However, expenditures for housing, construction of highways, and social facilities were to be increased by DME 670 million, giving a net reduction of DNE 1,030 billion. 189 No firm figures are avail- able on the original investment plan. The reported figures for total investment range all the way from DME 4.9 billion to DME 6.5 bil- lion. 190 If the higher figure is authentic, it probably contains planned investments for armaments and military construction, which are not shown in the official economic plan and which a private information bureau in Berlin reported to be DME 1.6 billion for the year mid-1952 through mid-1953. 191 Since investments in light industry.and in power and coal mining are not to be reduced, and since it is unlikely that the entire reduction could come out of S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T investment in heavy industry, which in Communist planning termi- nology includes replacements, it appears that a part of the reduc- tion probably will take place in military investment, such as investments for armaments and military construction. In 1953 and 1954, originally planned investment will be reduced by DME 2 billion each year. The reduction is to affect pri- marily the metallurgical, ore mining, and heavy machine construction industries, while investment in industries producing consumers' goods, power, and coal, as well as in the MI'S's and the state-owned farms, is to be further expanded. 192 Grotewohl stated that in 1954 retail turnover, measured in 1953 prices, would increase by DME 4.5 billion as compared with the revised plan for 1953. Taking into account the additive role of excise taxes and distributors' margins in retail price formation, it seems that this increase in turnover is quite possible, if investments are reduced as planned. Capacity for produc- tion of consumers' goods in light industry has not been fully utilized in the postwar period or has been partially diverted toward production of investment goods. The changes in the, investment program for 1945-55 should make available additional materials for the expanded production of consumers' goods. C. Agriculture. In 1952, East German agricultural production as a whole was about 11 percent below the 1938 level.* Population, on the other hand, was about 10 percent greater than in 1939. 193 (The increase in population came about primarily as a result of the transfer of population from the German territories east of the Oder-Neisse line.) 194 East Germany had to feed, in addition to its own popu- lation, about 400,000 Soviet occupation troops. 195- Before the war the area known as East Germany was, on balance, about self- sufficient in foodstuffs, exporting to Western Germany grains, potatoes, and sugar, and importing meats, fats, and dairy products. 196/ Among the major agricultural commodities, only the production of meat and vegetable oils had exceeded the 1935-39 average by 1952. The increase in meat production was achieved by abnormal slaughter of livestock in the face of shortages of feedstuffs caused by the * Estimate based on indexes computed in CIA. Indexes derived from CIA estimates of agricultural production in physical quantities. - 38 S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T unfavorable crop conditions in 1952. East Germany had deficits, more- over, of both meat and vegetable oils before the war. As a result of generally lower postwar production in agriculture and higher re- quirements because of increased population, East Germany has found it necessary to import foodstuffs. These imports, which for the most part have come from within the Soviet Bloc, have not been sufficient to provide an adequate diet for the population. In 1952, supplies of potatoes, sugar beets, and other sources of food for the population declined sharply. The harvest was poor because of unfavorable weather conditions and of disaffection among farmers caused by the drive for collectivization. Moreover, consider- able quantities of foodstuffs were added to the State reserves. The East German Five Year Plan calls for considerable increases in agricultural production (see Table 3).* The goals of the Five Year Plan for agriculture can possibly be achieved in view of the prewar performance in this sector and in view of the expansion of yields in West German agriculture by amounts greater than those required by the East German Five Year Plan. 197 Fulfillment of the Five Year Plan will depend primarily upon adequate supplies of fertilizers and upon achieving peace and stability in the agricultural community. The cessation of reparations deliveries should enable East Germany to obtain phosphatic fertilizers, and it should be possible to. expand domestic production. of potash and nitrogen fertilizers. The goals for animal products very probably will not be realized, because of the abnormal slaughter of livestock in 1953 following a shortfall in pro- duction of fodder in 1952. The number of swine declined by approximately 20 percent, and the population of other major kinds of livestock failed to increase. Although the present livestock popula- tion is close to prewar levels, the average weight of slaughter animals is considerably below prewar. As part of the "new course," compulsory delivery quotas for agricultural commodities have been decreased, and several of the measures designed to drive farmers into cooperatives have been re- pealed. Independent farmers have been promised credits and some easement of obligations to pay back taxes. Nevertheless, the policy. of collectivization has merely been slowed, not abandoned.. The speech of Ulbricht before the Central Committee of the SED on 19 September 1953, in. which he stated, among other things, that one reason for the diffi- culties in 1952 was that the political work of the NTS's was not good * Table 3 follows on p. 40. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 3 Production of Agricultural Commodities in East Germany 1952 and 1955 Plan 198/ Thousand Metric Tons J 1955 Plan Annual Average 1955 as Percent of Postwar Peak 1952 Plan Prewar Crops Grain and Legumes 6,129 b 5,6+7 7,313 111 Oil Seeds 182 J 181 279 71 Potatoes 13,.098 c/ 10,1.62 17,507 129 Sugar Beets 5,880 b 3,788 6,8o4 127 Meat 619 / 619 1,357 221 Milk N.A. N.A. 6,772 124 Eggs (1,000 Eggs) N.A. N.A. 1,980 153 Butter 71 J 71 100 95 Slaughter Fats 124+ 124 245 175 a. Unless otherwise indicated. b. 1951. c. 1950. d. 1952. enough, could hardly have been reassuring to the independent farmer. 1221 For the time being, however, the East German regime apparently intends to pacify the independent farmer. Although a measure of improvement in over-all agricultural production can be expected, the 1955 goals for leading plant and animal products very probably will not be met. III. Foreign Economic Relations. A. Pattern of Trade. East German foreign trade has shown constant and substantial gains since the reversal of the policy of dismantling German industry S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T in mid-1948. Soviet plans for East Germany suggest that its role in the economy of the Soviet Bloc is to be similar to its former role in the European economy, the role of a modern manufacturing economy. If these plans materialize, a. continuation of the upward trend of exports and imports may be expected, and trade with the Bloc as a percentage of the total trade of East Germany is likely to increase over the long run. As shown in Table 4, the world trade of East Germany increased several'fold over the period from 1948 to 1952. This increase was Table 4 Foreign Trade of East Germany 1948-52 Current Prices Total Trade East-West Trade (Thousand (Thousand Percent of Exports I$ us) I$ US) Total 1948 133,870 20o J 48,419 202a/ 36.2 1949 299,227 202 J 94,616 20o a/ 31.6 1950 460,000 201 183,041 202 39.8 1951 714,800 20l 112,964 202 15.8 1952 724,344 123,731 2E2/ 17.1 1952 724,344 203 174,567 204 J 24.1 204 J Imports 1948 170,946 Loo a/ 63,358 200 J 37.1 1949 314,576 20o a/ 160,448 200J 51.0 1950 511,000 201 154,624 202 30.3 1951 557,500 20l 101,011 202 18.1 1952 971,943 110,603 202 11.4 1952 b 971,943 203 240,617 203 24.8 a. Does not include interzonal trade with the French Zone of Germany. b. The share of East=West trade in the total imports and exports in 1952 is higher when East German figures for the East-West trade are used than when US Department of Commerce totals based on official Western sources are used. See also Table 5, foot- note c, p. 43, below. c. Based on the results for January-September. - 41 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T achieved despite the payment of a substantial portion of East German production to the USSR on reparations account, which account is excluded from the totals treated in this section. For the period 1948-50, East German foreign trade statistics were originally calculated in dollars and then converted to marks at the official exchange rate (to August 1950, 1 RM/DME equals $0.40 and after. August 1950, 1 DME equals $0.30). In recent years the same practice is reported to have been followed, except that the dollar figures are converted to rubles at the rate 1 ruble equals $0.25. 205 Therefore, these exchange rates are appropriate for converting the East German foreign trade figures as reported in marks or rubles to dollars, and the question of whether these rates ade- quately reflect the internal purchasing power of the mark or the ruble is beside the point in this connection. 1. East German Trade with the West. East German trade with the West increased substantially during the period 1948-52. Western Europe accounted for the major portion of this East-West total (see Table 5).* For the years 1948-49 and 1951-52-, over 90 percent of East German exports to the West went to Western Europe, and over 98 percent of all imports from the West came from that area. 206/ Trade with North America came second, and the remainder of East German trade with the West was .widely scattered. The largest part of this Western trade was with the nearby countries of northwestern Europe. West Germany, the Netherlands, Sweden, Norway, and Denmark accounted for about 86 per- cent of total exports to the West in 1951 and about 60 percent in 1952. As in the case of exports, neighboring countries of northwestern Europe dominated the import field and accounted for almost 90 percent of total imports into East Germany from the West in 1951 and 75 percent in 1952. Although exports were fairly evenly divided among the fore- going countries, West Germany was a more important source of imports, accounting for 38 percent in 1951 and 23 percent in 1952. The decline in trade with northwestern Europe in 1952 was largely replaced by an increase in trade with France and Finland. The commodity composition of East German trade with the West underlines the East German emphasis on industrial development at Table 5 follows on p. 43. -42- S-E-C-R-E-T I Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 j Approved For Release 1999/09/02: CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Value of the Trade of East Germany with the West by Countries, 1948-49 and 1951-52 Exports Total West Germany Netherlands Sweden Norway Denmark Switzerland Finland Austria France Other Western European Countries Other Western Countries 1948 207 I 23,519.0 J N.A. 8,318.2 813.0 2,961.5 2,052.6 3,465.4 413.4 687.5 42.2 4,125.6 639.6 1949 1951 38,795.8 J 112,964.0 / N.A. 29,185.0 9,126.9 10,388.0 4,175.2 18,442.0 1,132.8 6,625.0 7,140.2 12,449.0 5,915.8 6,089.0 1,342.4 5,489.0 1,791.6 7,442.0 423.6 1,523.0 5,922.0 12,118.0 1,825.3 3,214.0 1952 20 123,731.0 19,335.0 11,067.0 20,007.0 9,768.0 14,046.0 4,270.0 8,531.0 8,259.0 6,006.0 -10,866.0 11,576.0 1948 212 31,857.7 N.A. 8,459.7 1,064.7 2,109.1 1,535.9 1,489.2 132.2 5,066.6 16.6 11,697.9 285.8 1949 2t3J 100,287.6 af N.A. 24,220.4 6,802.0 3,838.4 7,423.6 4,064.0 1,436.0 2,708.0 254.4 47,493.2 2,047.6 1951 101,011.0 35,291.0 13,025.0 12,238.0 6,292.0 16,596.0 5,189.0 1,797.0 4,114.0 348.0 6,046.0 75.0 1952 21 110,603.0 35,016.0 14,057.0 16,273.0 7,329.0 12,479.0 7,960.0 2,908.0 5,648.0 2,916.0 4,630.0 1,387.0 a. Totals for 1948-+59 do not include trade with the French Zone of Germany. b. Countries not separately specifying East or West Germany not included. '''/ c. The following breakdown of 1952 exports and imports (in current thousand $ US) is taken from an official East German source. / Some measure of the magnitude of illegal trade may be deduced from a comparison of these totals with those of Table 5, which were derived from official Western sources. Other Western Other European Western (1952) Total West Germany Netherlands Sweden Norway Denmark Switzerland Finland Austria France Countries Countries Exports 174,567 N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. Lap its 240,617 23,713 34,726 31,184 7,808 25,575 28,159 9,076 8,579 7,771 41,626 22,400 43 S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T the expense of production of food and other consumers' goods. Table 6* presents the commodity composition of East German trade with the West for 1948, 1949, and 1951. Over 60 percent of East German exports to the West in 1951 consisted of industrial products, while almost 50 percent of East German imports were composed of food, beverages and tobacco, and fats and oils, with food alone comprising most of this amount. Restrictions on trade with the West, whether designed to promote Soviet Bloc.autarky or to conserve supplies of Western cur- rency, appear to have been relaxed to some extent in late 1952 and 1953. Evidence to this effect rests chiefly on an increasing number of trade agreements with the free world and on the comparative volume of trade in 1952 and 1953. The agreements with Egypt in February of 1953 and with Argentina are cases in point. Comparative data on East German trade with Western countries, excluding West Germany, for the first 6 months of 1952 and 1953 are as follows: January to June 1952 January to June 1953 Current Thousand $ US Exports 51,817 69,325 Imports 44,009 48,968 At the beginning of 1953 it was estimated that. East Germany owed West Germany DMW (Deutsche Mark West) 35 million to DMW 40 million. There were earnest efforts to reduce this balance in March, April, May, and June of 1953, but a reversal of this trend had resulted in an increase of the deficit by almost DMW 5 million on 1 September 1953. 2. East German Trade with Other Soviet Bloc Countries. East German trade with the Soviet Bloc amounted to about 75 percent of the total foreign trade of the country for 1951-52. For the year 1952, total foreign trade turnover with the Satellites amounted to about $1.3 billion. Both imports and exports were nearly Table 6 follows on p. 45. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :4 CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 6 Commodity Composition of the Trade of East Germany with the West aJ 1948, 1949, and 1951 Thousand $ US 1948 f 1949 217 b 1951 218 Food 5.4 2,551.6 4,387.0 Beverages and Tobacco 0.0 280.4 254.0 Raw Materials, Inedible 8,462.2 1,739.3 13,841.0 Mineral Fuels and Related Materials 638.4 95.2 19,489.0 Animal and Vegetable Oils and Fats 0.0 0.0 91.0 Chemicals 1,796.5 2,901.2 ?.9,779.0 Manufactured Goods 5,908.1 14,433.6 13,693.0 Machinery and Transport Equipment 3,261.9 12,120.4 13,296.0 Miscellaneous Manufactured Articles 3,422.5 4,639.6 2,164.0 Miscellaneous Commodities and Transactions 23.6 34.5 14,409.0 23,519.0 38,795.8 101,403.0 Imports 1948 219 1 1949 220 b 1951 221 Food 2,154.8 14,463.2 42,366.0 Beverages and Tobacco 555.5 731.2 205.0 Raw Materials, Inedible 12,415.1 5,877.2 11,448.0 Mineral Fuels and Related Materials 2,819.9 3,515.2 5,862.0 Animal and Vegetable Oils and Fats 3.0 9,659.2 1,725.0 Chemicals 1,971.5 56,415.2 7,191.0 Manufactured Goods 11,347.5 7,272.0 14,487.0 Machinery and Transport Equipment 222.4 897.2 3,496.0 Miscellaneous Manufactured Articles 3.56.0 1,417.6 732.0 Miscellaneous Commodities and Transactions 12.0 39.6 7,073.0 Total 31,857.7 100,'287.6 94,585.0 a. Table 6 cannot be reconciled with Table 5, because each is the US Department of Commerce. b. Totals for 1948-49 do not include West Germany. - 45 - compilation by S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T seven times as great in 1952 as in 1948. The percentage increase in trade with the Bloc exceeded the percentage increase in trade with the West, and in dollar terms the increase was several times greater. Table 7* shows the relative importance of Soviet Bloc countries in the trade of East Germany with the Bloc in the period 1948-52. The USSR accounted for about half of East German exports to the Bloc for the 5 years and was the source of a slightly larger proportion of imports. Poland ranked next, accounting for about one- fourth of the exports and imports of East Germany to the Bloc. Czechoslolakia, Hungary, Rumania, and Bulgaria followed in that order. Trade with Communist China, although relatively small, shows a marked increase from 1951 to 1952. 222 Imports of Chinese foodstuffs became especially important in the-last quarter of 1952. A detailed year-by-year comparison of the commodity compo- sition of the trade of East Germany with the other Soviet Bloc coun- tries over the postwar period is made difficult by the lack of comparable statistics. Table 8** shows the composition of this trade for 1949. Exports in 1949 consisted chiefly of inedible raw materials, about 40 percent of the total; machinery and transport equipment, about 20 percent; and other manufactured goods, about 16 percent, with chemicals and miscellaneous other categories comprising the remainder. On the import side, manufactured goods, excluding machinery and trans- port equipment, accounted for about 46 percent of the total; mineral fuels and lubricants, about 20 percent; and inedible crude materials, about 13 percent, with food, machinery, and other lesser categories accounting for the remainder. Beginning in 1950, exports and imports were classified by industry rather than by commodity groupings as in the earlier years. In 1952 the machinery construction industry contributed 38 percent of total East German exports to the Soviet Bloc countries; chemicals, about 20 percent; and electrical engineering products and precision equipment, about 21 percent. A complete breakdown of im- ports is not available, but large imports of food and agricultural and industrial raw materials suggest that East Germany is becoming increasingly dependent on Bloc sources of supply. 223 Table 7 follows on p. 47. # Table 8 follows on p. 48. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 7 Distribution of the Trade of East Germany with Other Soviet Bloc Countries 1948-52 Exports Total USSR Poland Czechoslovakia Hungary Bulgaria Rumania Albania China 1948 100.0 48.4 39.7 9.9 1.7 0.2 0.1 0 0 1949 100.0 67.2 22.4 8.3 1.0 0.8 0.3 0 0 1950 100.0 55.5 28.5 11.0 2.9 1.2 0.9 0 0 1951 100.0 55.2 22.4 11.0 4.3 1.7 2.2 0.3 2.9 1952 100.0 51.5 19.2 10.0 7.2 1.9 3.4 0.4 6.4 Imports 1948 100.0 56.8 31.5 11.1 0.1 0.5 0 0 0 1949 100.0 63.9 18.1 11.7 3.5 1.8 1.0 0 0 1950 100.0 54.5 24.4 11.8 6.9 1.4 1.0 0 0 1951 100.0 55.1 23.3 8.6 3.8 2.7 2.2 0 4.3 1952 100.0 52.8 18.9 8.0 7.1 1.9 3.7 0.4 7.2 - 47 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Commodity Composition of the Trade of East Germany with Other Soviet Bloc Countries 1949 Exports 224 Total USSR Poland Czecho- slovakia Hungary Bulgaria Rumania Albania China Food 11,592 1,158 431 3 0 0 0 0 Beverages and Tobacco 1,211 1,211 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Raw Materials, Inedible 84,889 44,469 32,142 7,765 507 0 6 0 0 Mineral Fuels, Lubricants, and Related Materials 17,932 14,924 2,681 327 0 0 0 0 0 Animal and Vegetable Oils and Fats 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Chemicals 13,516 7,843 2,271 2,727 270 388 17 0 0 Manufactured Goods 25,175 19,800 3,170 1,527 215 329 134 0 0 Machinery and Transport Equipment 42,785 34,941 3,316 2,525 1,035 734 234 0 0 Miscellaneous Manufactured Goods 7,511 3,170 .1,866 2,079 73 226 97 0 0 Miscellaneous Commodities and Transactions 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Total 204,611 137,516 45,877 16,953 2,100 i,677 488 0 0 Imports 225! Food 11,088 676 1,708 1,016 3,926 2,379 1,383 0 0 Beverages and Tobacco 1,300 824 0 0 476 0 0 0 0 Raw Materials, Inedible 19,318 16,401 1,614 712 238 270 83 0 0 Mineral Fuels, Lubricants, and Related Materials 31,95q 2,216 18,975 10,122 6646 0 0 0 0 Animal and Vegetable Oils and Fats 6,747 6,747 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Chemicals 3,297 2,015 626 481 127 48 0 0 0 Manufactured Goods 69,884 61,315 4,974 3,581 0 14 0 0 0 Machinery and Transport Equipment 10,100 8,067 0 1,993 40 0 0 0 0 Miscellaneous Manufactured Articles 435 292 0 143 0 0 0 0 0 Miscellaneous Commodities and Transactions 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Total 154,128 98,553 27,897 18,048 5,453 2,711 1,466 0 0 S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999109/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T B. Role of East Germany in the Soviet Bloc Economy. As long as East Germany remains under'Soviet control, its total production must be considered in estimating the economic capa- bility of the Soviet Bloc for particular courses of action.* In terms of GNP, East Germany in 1952 represented about 8 percent of the Bloc total, or about i4+ percent of the GNP of the USSR. Among the European Satellites, East Germany comes first in size of GNP, ranking slightly ahead of Poland. 226 The pattern of specialization of the East German economy in the Bloc may be appraised in the light of the commodity composition of the trade of the country with other members of the Bloc.** In brief, East Germany as an advanced industrial area is an important supplier of machinery, chemicals, electrical engineering products, and precision equipment and in return receives primarily agricultural and industrial raw materials, food, mineral fuels, lubri- cants, and certain manufactured products. East Germany has been supplying to the USSR an estimated one- fourth to one-half of the uranium available to the Soviet atomic energy program. This is considerably more than is produced by all the other Satellites combined. The rate of production in East Germany is being maintained by deeper mining and by increasing the exploitation of very low-grade ores at a greatly increased cost in capital invest- ment and operating expenses. Significant changes in this production rate are not expected to occur by 1955. 227 The advanced industrial character of East Germany and certain specializations imposed by its small area are shown by an examination of its array of basic raw materials and intermediate and final prod- ucts, in relation to the production of the Soviet Bloc*** as a whole and the USSR in particular. As may be seen from Appendix A, Table 10,**** East Germany is not an especially important producer of ferrous'metals, being limited in this respect by lack of high-grade ores and coking coal. In nonferrous metals, East Germany contributes 39 percent of secondary copper and almost 10 percent of refined lead. * For a discussion of Soviet takings from East Germany in the form of reparations and other uncompensated deliveries, see I, A, and I, C, above. ** See A, above. *** Including Communist China. ****. See this table (p. 61, below)-for production in physical or value units and for comparable totals for the Soviet Bloc and the USSR. - 49 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Although completely lacking in crude petroleum production, East Ger- many has an important synthetic liquid, fuel industry which accounts for about two-thirds of the total output of the Bloc. This repre- sents, however, only a little more than 2 percent of the combined output of the Bloc of natural and synthetic petroleum products. East Germany is a particularly important producer of chemicals, accounting for the following approximate percentages of total Bloc production: ammonia, 29; nitric acid, 17; chlorine, 37; calcium carbide, 55; caustic soda, 29; refined phenol, 59; and synthetic rubber, 22. Among agricultural products and fibers, sugar and rayon are important contributions of East Germany to the production of the Soviet Bloc, representing, respectively, about 11 percent and 53 per- cent of the Bloc totals. On the other hand, the country is deficient in grains, vegetable oils, and natural fibers. East Germany is an important producer in the Soviet Bloc of certain types of industrial products, especially machine tools, which account for 16 percent of the Bloc total, and certain types of electrical equipment, particularly turbines and transformers, which account for 16 to 18 percent of the Bloc total. This enumeration of leading commodities produced by East Germany as a percentage of the Soviet Bloc total should be supple- mented by other items in the production of which East Germany does not rank so favorably. For this purpose, see the more complete list in Appendix A, Table 10.* Taking all economic factors into consideration, however, it is clear that.East Germany represents a rich prize among the Satellites for economic reasons alone. If the Soviet cancelation of reparations and suspension of other uncom- pensated deliveries are not replaced by new exactions, the Soviet economic benefit from this area will be smaller than in the past and will be measured by the advantages derived from trade. If, how- ever, Soviet control over East Germany remains secure, the resources and production of this area must be counted among the elements con- stituting Soviet capabilities for hot or cold war. * P. 61, below. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T IV. Labor and Population. A. State Control over Labor. In the administration of labor policy, as well as in other aspects of the centrally planned economy, the East German government. tries to assume the appearance of democratic procedures. Actually it relies essentially on government regulations which may impose direct restraints on the factors of production or indirectly influence their allocation through the market mechanism by means of government- controlled prices and wages. To achieve the appearance of democracy, it is pretended that governmental measures are taken only in response to popular demand as voiced by democratically operated organizations. The numerous public, quasipublic, and private agencies which seemingly participate on an equal footing in the conduct of public business are in fact puppets, responding to the instructions of a relatively small inner circle of the government. Since these so-called mass organiza- tions are under the leadership of the same small group that runs the government, it is possible to evoke the appearance of popular enthusi- asm for particular governmental measures and to have these measures appear to be demanded by the public. Public policy in the field of labor is administered chiefly by the Ministry of Labor. Other economic ministries, however, especially those directly concerned with production, and local agencies participate in the implementation and control of labor policy. Measures taken by the various organizations are coordinated in the over-all economic plan which establishes the objectives for the econ- omy as a whole and for the principal sectors. The Ministry of Labor exercises jurisdiction in general labor matters and collaborates with the other economic ministries in the execution of manpower plans. If necessary, the Ministry of Labor may issue mandatory directives for carrying out government-approved.plans for the allocation of labor to projects of special economic significance. The Ministry, through its departments and local agencies, is primarily concerned with procurement of labor for basic industries and important enter- prises, research on manpower requirements and supply, attempts to in- crease the percentage of women in the. working force, supervision of labor reserves and juvenile workers, promotion of the activist move- ment and socialist competition, formulation of wage policy, develop- ment and introduction of wage group classifications and technical work norms, drafting of new social legislation, and labor statistics. S.-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T The executive organs of the local governments are subordinated to the ministries of the central government in carrying out labor policies. These agencies replace the traditional labor exchange offices, which were dissolved. In addition to certain functions in confirming and supervising collective wage "agreements," the local agencies have the following duties: to utilize the local labor reserves, to organize the allocation of workers among the various establishments and administrative districts of the country, to assist nationalizes enterprises in the recruitment of labor, and to maintain registers of employed and unemployed workers. Managements of local enterprises are required to report at frequent intervals the number of workers employed, new additions, and workers discharged, giving details for changes of status of individual workers. In carrying out the allocation of workers to particularly important establishments, the local agencies may issue compulsory work assignments. The government utilizes the training facilities of the educational system in planning the supply of labor to meet the re- quirements of economic plans. Vocational training receives great emphasis. The production ministries arrange for apprentice training and factory vocational schools. Free unionism of the Western type does not exist in East Germany today. The Labor Code asserts: "In our new democratic order in which the key enterprises belong to the state, the right of wage and salary earners -- the decisive power in the state -- to partici- pate in the determination of the conduct of the economy is realized through the organs of the democratic state." 228 Accordingly, the unions cannot strike against state-owned enterprises, and they have been deprived of the right to negotiate the basic conditions of employment and of other rights which under traditional Western and German thought are considered part of the freedom to organize. Only one union organization is allowed to exist -- the Federation of Free German Unions -- which is composed of 20 affiliated unions with a total membership of more than 5 million persons. Its primary function is to carry out the policies of the government and the SED rather than to represent the specific interests of }workers with respect to management or even the government. Performance of this duty is secured by placing reliable Communists in the leading positions in the unions and in the government. The most important functions of the unions in the nationalized enterprises are to promote increased productivity at lowest possible costs, to organize "cultural pro- grams" for indoctrinating labor with the Communist ideology, and to administer the social insurance system. At most, the role of S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T unions in the management of the publicly owned sector is advisory, and though the trade-union shop representative may use his partici- pation in "People's Control" to complain about irregularities, action on complaints will occur only with the consent of the public administration, the Party leadership, and the top command of the union. The latter, however, are unified through the device of identical, Communist leadership, and action will be taken only when it is expedient in the view of this leadership. Administration of the social insurance system by the Federa- tion of Free German Unions has increased the strong pressure on workers to become and remain members of the unions. This again brings out the quasigovernmental character of the union organization. Union officials, instead of working for changes in policies con- sidered undesirable by workers, are obliged to help in the enforce- ment of such policies. For this reason, most of the important union activities are in practice initiated and carried out by the executives of the Federation rather than by the member unions. One of the aims of. the regime is to indoctrinate the youth of the country and re- educate adults to accept the new concept of the union as an executor of public policies. At present, opposition to this concept is still strong. In the declining private sector of the economy, unions are expected to safeguard the interests of workers and to promote the conversion of private enterprise to socialist forms. Apart from the enforcement of the "right to codetermine" business policies in private enterprises, the Federation of Free German Unions points out that the tasks of the unions should include checking'of tax payments, control of price policy, and supervision of the performance of contracts with publicly owned enterprises. But lower union officials and mem- bers, instead of supporting the policy of the Federation, have, not infrequently, helped private employers to ward off the breakdown of their business. In such instances, union officials have followed the policy of demanding concessions on the basis of the employer's ability to finance them out of profits after taxes without endanger- ing the existence of the firm. As a result, employees in the private sector sometimes have been more favorably paid than in the public sector and sometimes less so. Federation leadership has criticized this as a violation of the principle of equal pay for equal work and has urged that skilled workers in the private sector should not be paid more than those in the public sector, since their skills are necessary for "building socialism." At the same time, it is strongly S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T urged that wages in the lower categories should be raised in the private sector. Beyond that, Federation leadership has demanded that any remnants of class harmony between workers and private em- ployers should be extirpated. B. Manpower and Labor Planning. The current Five Year Plan 229 sets the goal for employment in the national economy at 7.1 million persons by 1955: that is, 13 percent above the 1950 level, or a gain of about 800,000 workers. Of the total, 2.77 million are to be women, and 4.33 million are to be men. The plan also provides for a 60-percent increase in labor productivity during the same period. In view of the available pool of manpower, the Plan does not appear unfeasible quantitatively. The requirements for highly skilled labor, however, may be difficult to meet. As a means of achieving the planned expansion of the de- pendent* labor force, the plan envisions an increase in the propor- tion of employed women, improvement of vocational training and schooling, and location of new plants in the less industrialized regions. To these measures should be added the transfer of self- employed persons to hired status and the absorption of the unemployed. In mid-1950 there were probably about 260,000 unemployed in East Germany, 230/ and early in 1952 official. unemployment probably still exceeded 200,000. This number does not include individuals who have refused to accept jobs offered to them and who are therefore not of- ficially recognized as unemployed. The total employment rose about 300,000 from 1950 to 1952. 231/ Since in February 1952 about 10.6 mil- lion persons were registered under the regulation requiring all persons between the ages of 14 and 65 and able to work to register, it appears that the manpower pool is great enough to meet the planned expansion of employment.. Difficulties may be experienced in getting women to leave household duties in favor of other employment, in curtailing the flight of people to West Germany, and in transferring the self-employed to a hired status by the liquidation of private enterprises, but, given the powers available to the government, it appears that the employ- ment goal is not unattainable. Evidence of the scarcity of qualified engineers, technicians, and other specialists is found in the cur- rent emphasis on the creation of new training facilities and on efforts to halt defections of these specially skilled personnel by raising wages and salaries, 232/ by improving the professional and Wage and salary workers as distinct from self-employed. -5!.- S -E -C -R-E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T social position of the "technical intelligentsia," and in the com- prehensive program to recruit West German scientists and other specialists. 233 In view of the relatively high proportion of skilled and professional manpower in prewar Germany, the present scarcity probably is caused by defection to the West and perhaps also by Soviet recruitment for service in the USSR. C. Labor Force and Population. As a result of the influx of refugees and expellees from the east and the return of prisoners of war, the population of East Ger- many, including East Berlin, increased between 1946 and 1949 from about 18.5 million to 19.1 million, but it has declined since then to the 1946 level and has remained at about that level to the present time. 234 The principal factor in the decline has been the flight of refugees to West Germany. Persons gainfully employed in East Germany on 1 February 1952 totaled 7,855,000, of whom 1.5 million were nonagricultural self- employed, including family helpers. The distribution of the remainder and the goals for 1955 are shown in Table 9.* 235 These figures show the dominant role of nonagricultural employment in 1952 and the relative, but not absolute, decline scheduled for agriculture by the end of 1955. D. Incentives and Other Devices to Increase Output. The East German government, through the public enterprises, employs the majority of the wage and salary workers in the country. The government uses three basic types of methods to increase output per worker: economic incentives, ideological indoctrination, and coercive and penal measures. The techniques employed under each method are constantly refined, and the pressures intensified. Eco- nomic incentives are applied by the use of differential wages for the various job classifications and by piecework rates and premiums on the quantity and quality of work produced. Individual and. group incentives are designed to increase output per worker and per pro- duction team. In establishing norms of output, there is a strong tendency to use the results achieved by outstanding employees and to set the Table 9 follows on p. 56. - 55 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 9 Employment in East Germany by Sectors 1952 and 1955 Plan Branch Male Female Total Industry 1,525,000 928,000 2,453,000 Building Trades 211,000 143,000 354,000 Agriculture and Forestry 1,lo6,ooo 1,018,000 2,124,000 Transportation 431,000 104,000 535,000 Public and Private Service Employees 714,000 175,000 889,000 Male Female Total 1,685,000 1,185,000 2,870,000 245,000 180,ooo 425,000 1,200,000 1,100,000 2,300,000 450,000 130,000 580,000 750,000 175,000 925,000 Total 3,987,000 2,368,000 6,355,000 4,330,000 2,770,000 7,100,000 norm considerably above the statistical average attained by a given group of workers. Ideological propaganda seeks to convince the workers that such procedures are necessary to increase the welfare of the country. Because of large allocations of the increment of national product to investment and other nonconsumption uses, however, the enthusiasm of the workers for constant upward revision of norms with wages fairly constant has failed to come up to the planners' expectations. Indeed, the attempt to raise norms has met with grow- ing resentment on the part of the workers. Following the decision of the Council of Ministers on 28 May 1953 that all norms must be raised again at least 10 percent by 30 June 1953, without provision for commensurate increase in wage rates, there were demonstrations in mid-June, first by construction workers in Berlin and subsequently by workers in other centers, which grew into broad protests against the oppression of the Communist regime. These events forced the government to repeal officially the decision of 28 May and to decree that wage calculations in the socialized sector, as of 1 June 1953, should be based on the working norms valid on 1 April 1953. Although the government thus found it expedient to modify its immediate objec- tives, it has not forsaken the ultimate goal. The Politbuero of the - 56 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T SED on 16 June 1953 repeated-the arguments in favor of raising work norms.and declared that the 10-percent increase should be carried through not by order of the ministries concerned but "solely on the basis of persuasion and voluntary decision." This, however, is not a fundamental change in policy, as the government has always been careful to maintain the impression that its decisions are motivated by the demands of the workers. In the application of economic incentives, the government has sought to direct workers to priority sectors of the economy by offering higher average wages in these areas. In order to cause workers to increase their skills, it has introduced classifications of jobs by difficulty and by necessary skills, with corresponding wage differences.. Extraordinary merit and achievement are rewarded by prizes and honorary titles, and longevity in service is recognized by premiums. As a complement to the financial incentives, the East German policy makers have pursued a program of ideological propaganda to win the support of workers for economic objectives of the regime. The principal devices used in this endeavor are "cultural programs, socialist competitions, and the activist movement, although the latter contains financial incentives as well. It corresponds to the Soviet Stakhanovite program. Meritorious group performance is rewarded by expenditures for collective benefit from the "Director's Fund," which is based on profits of the enterprise. Although it is impossible to trace separately the effects of the various incentives employed in increasing productivity, the presence of an assortment of penal provisions for violations of labor discipline and the provision for compulsory assignment of individuals to particu- larly important segments of activity indicate that the incentive schemes in themselves have not sufficed to reach the objectives set in plans. The continued migration from East Germany to West Germany is further evidence of the inadequacy of economic incentives. E:. Migration. After the first flare-up of defection at the beginning of the postwar period, the number of refugees from East to West Germany declined steadily until mid-1952. In the second half of 1952 it began to increase again, and in the first half of 1953 it reached unprecedented proportions. Beginning in June 1953, the influx of refugees from East Germany dropped sharply to reach a low of less S-E -C-R-E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T than half the rate which prevailed earlier in the year. In recent weeks the number of refugees arriving in West Berlin and other reception centers has again begun to increase. Details of the East- West migration are shown in Appendix A, Tables 10* and 11**. There is no reason to assume that the large drop in defec- tions has been entirely, or even chiefly, caused by the introduction of the "new course." Although a number of persons may have given up or postponed defection because of hope for improvement of their lot under the "new course," it is probable that more people have been pre- vented from fleeing by more effective border controls. F. Scale of Living. Analysis of the trend in the scale of living in East Germany from price-wage. statistics is complicated by the presence of coupon rationing and a two-price system of rationing under which scarce goods are sold for very high prices in state-owned stores called HO's. The basic needs of the low-income sectors of the population can theoretically be met by the private retailers and consumers' cooperatives, which must sell at controlled prices. During the past 3 years the prices in HO stores have been lowered a number of times, and controlled prices have been raised, with a resultant lowering of the gap between the two, but the gap is still considerable. The scale of living in East Germany rose gradually from very low postwar levels up to 1952, when per capita consumption is estimated to be still substantially below the prewar level. Poor agricultural harvests in 1951 and 1952 sharply reduced the availability of food supplies in the 1952-53 food year. Follow- ing the announcement of the "new course" in June, the situation was relieved in part by drawing on state reserves and by supplemental food imports from the USSR. 236 The average daily caloric intake per capita in East Germany stood at 2,612 in the period from 1933 to 1937, 2,081 in the food year 1951_52,#** and 1,917 in 19.52-53, 237 or, in percentages, 1952-53 was about 73 percent of prewar and 92 percent of 1951-52. Reduced availabilities of milk, cheese, eggs, P. 61, below. P. 65, below. The food year extends from 1 July to the following 30 June. - 58 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T vegetables, and legumes probably account for a lesser percentage of total calories consumed in postwar than in prewar years. The consumption of manufactured consumers' goods presents a more difficult problem for analysis than food alone. Per capita production of a representative sample of manufactured consumers' goods, which includes an estimate of manufactured food items, indi- cates that East Germany has been able to attain a postwar high of about 70 percent of the prewar level in 1953.* 238 Although the present area produced a surplus of consumers' goods end items prior to the war, it is thought that present levels of production fall well short of local requirements. Ample evidence indicates that shortages of consumers' goods are very real to the residents of East Germany. Under the "new course" the output of agricultural and light industrial products has received more favorable attention than in the past. Increased imports of manufactured consumers' goods and food items will depend upon the availability of export commodities. With the apparent relief from the burden of reparations and other uncompensated deliveries to the USSR, it would appear that East Germany has a favorable opportunity for increasing the scale of living. This, however, will depend on the possibility of new forms of Soviet exactions and the sincerity of the local regime in its de- clared intention of improving the lot of the people. Based on 1953 production estimates made early in the year. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T APPENDIX A TABLES Table 10 Production of Selected Commodities in East Germany, the USSR, and the Soviet Bloc 1952 1952 23 1952 240 1952 241 Total Bloc USSR East Germany East Germany (Thous send (Thousai3d (Thousa d as Percent East Germany as Percent Commodity mt) b mt J mt) J of Total Bloc of USSR Iron Ore (50% Fe) 62,783.0 55,000.0 330.0 0.5 0.6 Pig Iron 31,979.0 25,100.0 654.0 2.0 2.6 Raw Steel 43,917.5 34,300.0 1,800.0 4.1 5.2 Metallurgical Coke 45,288.0 33,000.0 265.0 0.6 0.8 Rolled Steel 32,317.0 25,100.0 1,362.0 4.2 5.4 Manganese Ore 4,547.6 4,200.0 20.0 0.4 0.5 Chromite (mt) 750,700.0 650,000.0 0 0 0 Primary Copper 303.2 287.0 10.4 3.4 3.6 Secondary Copper 70.0 39.0 27.0 38.6 69.2 Refined Lead 197.7 117.0 19.0 9.6 16.2 Refined Zinc 267.0 130.0 N.A. N.A. 0 Antimony 14.5 3.0 0 0 0 Bauxite 1,865.0 625.0 0 0 0 Primary Aluminum 251.2 220.0 9.2 3.7 4.2 Secondary Aluminum 81.5 72.5 7.0 8.6 9.7 Fluorspar 198.0 160.0 38.0 19.2 23.8 Petroleum Crude Petroleum 55,576.0 44,000.0 0 0 0 Liquid Fuels (from Synthetics and Shale Oils) 1,807.0 300.0 1,203.0 66.6 4ol.o Natural and Synthetic Petro- leum Products 53,300.0 41,580.0 1,300.0 2.4 3.1 Natural Gas (million cu m) 9,840.0 5,500.0 0 Footnotes for Table 10 follow on p. 64. - 61 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Production of Selected Commodities in East Germany, the USSR, and the Soviet Bloc a 1952 (Continued) 1952 239 1952 240 1952 241 Commodity Total Bloc (Thousand mt) USSR East Germany East Germany (Thousand (Thousand as Percent Mt) J rnt) J of Total Bloc East Germany as Percent of USSR Ammonia (Synthesis) 972.0 590.0 280.0 28.8 47.5 Nitric Acid (100 Percent) 1,686.5 1,172.0 246.1 16.6 21.0 Sulfuric Acid 4,619.0 3,627.0 362.0 7.8 10.0 Toluol 67.4 56.0 3.9 5.8 7.0 Chlorine 529.0 261.0 198.0 37.4 75.9 Calcium Carbide 1,256.1 300.0 69o.4 55.0 230.1 Caustic Soda 722.9 333.0 208.9 28.9 92.8 Crude Benzol 412.1 305.0 19.1 4.6 6.3 Refined Benzol 359.3 223.0 10.3 2.9 4.6 Refined Phenol 15.5 10.6 9.2 59.4 86.8 Synthetic Rubber 253.6 187.0 .56.3 22.2 30.1 Reclaimed Rubber 70.5 55.0 2.5 3.5 4.5 Rubber Tires (thousand units) 12.84 10.0 0.8 6.2 8.0 Bread Grains (million mt) 103.71 61.29 3.3 3.2 5.4 Other Grains (million mt) 48.18 29.91 2.2 4.6 Potatoes 148,506.6 8,880.0 10,162.0 6.8 12.9 Sugar 4,568.4 2,267.0 511.0 11.2 22.5 Meat 9,930.0 3,485.0 619.0 6.2 17.8 Animal Fats 2,409.0 851.0 195.0 8.1 22.9 Vegetable Oils 2,809.7 885.0 52.3 1.9 5.9 Wool (Grease Base) 235.31 150.9 3.7 1.6 :2.5 Rayon 184.o 41.2 97.5 53.0 236.7 - 62 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Production of Selected Commodities in East Germany, the USSR, and the Soviet Bloc a/ 1952 (Continued) 1952 239 1952 240 1952 241 Total.Bloc (Thous nd Commodity mt USSR East Germany East Germany (Thou~s~'nd (Thous,d as Percent mt J mt) J of Total Bloc East Germany as Percent of USSR Anthracite and Bituminous 372,695.0 220,500.0 2,850.0 0.8 1.3 Lignite 325,404.0 85,500.0 178,080.0 54.7 46.3 Heavy Industrial Products Antifriction Bearings (million units) 131.3 115.0 6.8 5.2 5.9 Tractors (thousand units) 133.3 121.0 7.2 5.4 6.o Trucks (thousand units) 429.3 410.0 7.3 1.7 1.8 Passenger Cars (thousand units) 76.9 35.0 16.4 21.3 46.9 Steam Locomotives (units) 3,392.0 2,250.0 0 0 0 Electric Locomotives (units) 341.0 280.0 61.0 17.9 21.8 Freight Cars (equivalent 2- axle units 188,400.0 137,500.0 6,000.0 3.2 4.4 Railroad Passenger Cars (units) 4,380.0 2,800.0 620.0 14.2 22.1 Machine Tools (units) 138,590.0 80,340.0 22,000.0 15.9 27.4 Cori struction Materials Flat Glass (million sq m) 119.0 90.0 15.5 13.0 17.2 Gypsum 2,438.0 1,900.0 455.0 18.7 23.9 -6.3- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 10 Production of Selected Commodities in East Germany, the USSR, and the Soviet Bloc a/ 1952 (Continued) 1952 239 1952 240 1952 241 Total Bloc USSR East Germany East Germany East Germany (Thousand (Thousand (Thousand as Percent as Percent Commodity mt b mt) b mt) b of Total Bloc of USSR Construction Materials (Continued) Unglazed Bricks (million units) 21,300.0 15,990.0 1,680.0 7.9 10.5 Cement (Hydraulic) 19,150.0 14,500.0 1,620.0 8.5 11.2 Electric Power (million kwh) 179,634.0 117,000.0 23,400.0 13.0 20.0 Electric Equip- ment J Turbines (thousand kw) 5,085.0 3,600.0 1,809.0 18.1 30.0 Transformers (thousand kilo- volt amperes) 9,989.0 6,029.0 19,500.0 16.1 27.8 Wire and Cable (mt of copper) 121,360.0 70,060.0 445.0 7.5 10.5 a. The Soviet Bloc includes the USSR, the European Satellites, and Communist China. b. Unless otherwise indicated. c. Range of error, plus or minus 20 percent. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 ? CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Migration a/* between West Germany and East Germany, between West Berlin and East Germany, and between West Berlin and East Berlin, by Time Period 242 1948-52 Number of Persons Migrating. Number of Persons Migrating Time Period Net Migration To West Germany From East Germany To West Germany From East Germany From West Germany To East Germany Net Migration To West Berlin From East Germany To West Berlin From East Germany From West Berlin To East Germany Net Migration To West Berlin From East Berlin To West Berlin From East Berlin From West Berlin To East Berlin 1948 188 1 A N N A N.A. March N.A. N.A. N.A. 1,351 2,539 8 , 8 8 . . A N . . N A N.A 2d Quarter N.A. N.A. N.A. 6,011 9, 29 1 3, . . . . . N A 3d Quarter N.A. N.A. N.A. 3,751 7,264 8 3,513 N.A. N A N.A. N A . . N A 4th Quarter N.A. N.A. N.A. 5,359 ,329 2,970 . . . . . . Total (March- December) N.A. N.A. N.A. 16,472 27,961 11,489 N.A. W.A. N.A. 1949 4 4 81 2 N A N A N.A. 1st Quarter N.A. N.A. N.A. ,2-55 7,07 9 , . . . . 2d Quarter N.A. N,.A. N.A. 7,287 9,696 2,409 N.A. N.A. N.A. A N 3d Quarter N.A. N.A. N.A. 8,795 11,292 2,497 N.A. N A N.A. N A . . N A 4th Quarter N.A. N.A. N.A. 12,742 15,049 2,307 . . . . . . 000 220 000 2 000 35 33 079 43 111 10,032 N.A. N.A. N.A. Total , 55, , , , 1950 8 1st Quarter 41,943 49,740 7,797 9,552 11,689 2,137 86 2,810 272 5,095 5 467 5 2,2 195 2 2d Quarter 48,344 56,848 8,504 11,911 13,771 0 1, 3, , , 6 3d Quarter 57,781 b 65,287 J 7,526 J 12,141 14,270 2,129 3,865 6 041 , 2,17 2 1 2 4th Quarter 65,779 73,849 cf 8,070 12,181 13,835 1,654 4,402 6 653 5 , 4 4 246 2 / 088 1 32 45 785 53 565 780 7 14,349 23,256 8,907 Total 21 ,70 / ,79 2 , , , , * Footnotes for Table 11 follow on p. 66. 65 S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T Migration J between West Germany and East Germany, between West Berlin and East Germany, and between West Berlin and East Berlin, by Time Period 242 1948-52 (Continued) Number of Persons Migrating Number of Persons Migrating Time Period Net Migration To West Germany From East Germany To West Germany From East Germany From West Germany To East Germany Net Migration To West Berlin From East Germany To West Berlin From East Germany From West Berlin To East Germany Net Migration To West Berlin From East Berlin To West Berlin From East Berlin From West Berlin To East Berlin 1951 1st Quarter 44,934 49,902 4,968 9,605 11,068 1,463 1,054 5,918 4,864 2d Quarter 40,445 45,976 5,531 12,233 13,547 1,314 5,109 6,159 1,o46 3d Quarter 44,449 51,748 7,299 13,873 15,575 1,702 4,458 5,507 1X04 9 4th Quarter 42,046 47,761 5,715 13,476 14,804 1,328 3,727 4,548 821 Total 171,874 195,387 23,513 4 187 54,994 5,807 14,348 22,128 7,780 1952 1st Quarter 25,447 30,009 4,562 8,398 9,980 1,582 2,794 3,628 834 2d Quarter 27,426 32,047 4,621 N.A. N.A. N.A. 2,509 3,260 751 3d Quarter 24,828 27,765 2,937 N.A. N.A. N.A. 3,323 4,134 811 4th Quarter N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. 4,732 5,550 818 Total N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. N.A. 13,358 16,572 3,214 a. Based on police reports of arrivals and departures. b. Period from 1 July to 13 September 1950. c. Period from 14 September to 31 December 1950. d. The totals for the four quarters are slightly different from the total for the year obtained from a later source. - 66 - S-E-C-R-E-T ? Approved For Release 1999/09/02 ~ CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :'CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Total Persons Passing Through the Emergency Acceptance Procedure in Berlin by Age and Sex ?L3/ January 1952-June 1953 1952 1953, First Quarter April 1953 May 1953 June 1953 Age Groups Total Percent Male Total Percent Male Total Percent Male Total. Percent Male Total- Percent Male Under 6 9,356 8.2 4,813 10,138 9.3 5,206 3,104 8.8 1,601 3,401 9.9 1,761 3,655 9.4 1,911 6 to Under 14 14,633 12.9 7,519 16,346 15.0 8,425 5,107 14.5 2,631 4,943 14.5 2,541 4,900 12.6 2,526 14 to Under 18 10,479 9.2 6,650 10,408 9.5 6,053 3,999 11.4 2,292 3,883 11..4 2,147 5,050 12.9 3,017 18 to Under 21 10,981 9.7 7,333 7,318 6.7 4,049 2,503 7.1 1,411 2,366 6.9 1,307 3,300 8.5 1,982 21 to Under 25 9,186 8.1 5,540 6,203 5.7 3,163 2,024 5.8 1,007 2,036 6.0 1,015 2,610 6.7 1,427 25 to Under 45 35,622 31.4 17,801 33,357 30.5 14,145 10,431 29.6 4,463 9,927 29.1 4,373 11,302 29.0 5,187 45 to under 65 21,411 18.9 12,390 22,999 21.0 11,147 7,146 20.3 3,593 6,769 19.8 3,410 7,320 18.8 3,797 65 and Over 1,751 1.6 957 2,569 2.3 1,215 873 2.5 425 819 2.4 405 832 2.1 397 Total 113,419 100.0 63,003 109,338 100.0 53,403 35,187 100.0 17,423 34,144 100.0 16,959 38,969 100.0 20,244 67 S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T APPENDIX B SOURCES Evaluations, following the classification entry and designated "Eval.," have the following significance: Source of Information Information A Completely. reliable 1 - Confirmed by other sources B - Usually reliable 2 - Probably true C - Fairly reliable 3 - Possibly true D Not usually reliable 4 - Doubtful E - Not reliable 5 - Probably false F - Cannot be judged 6 - Cannot be judged 'Evaluations not otherwise designated are those appearing on the cited document; those designated "RR" are by the author of this re- port. No "RR" evaluation is given when the author agrees with the evaluation of the cited document. 1. State, Publication 2783, Occupation of Germany, Policy and Progress 1915-)+6, Washington, D.C., 1947, pp. 1, 159. U. 2. Ibid., p. 81. 3. J.P. Nettl,.The Eastern Zone and Soviet Policy in Germany, 1 1+9 5-1950, Oxford University Press, 1951, pp. , 62. U. Ii. Ibid., p. 62. 5. Ibid.,.p. xvii. 6. Ibid., pp. 62, 123. 7. Ibid., pp. 61, 199.. 8. Vorstand der Sozialdemokratischen Partei Deutschlands, Die Reparationen in der Sow et-Zone von 1945-1952, p. 6. U. Robert Slusser (editor), Soviet Economic Policy in Postwar Germany, Research Program do the USSR, 1953, pp. 1-14. U. Nettl, op. cit., pp. 150, 160-165. 9. Nettl, op. cit., pp. 86, 174-177- - 69 - S E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T 10. Slusser, op. cit., pp. xiv, 93. Nettl, ok. cit., p. 181. 11. Nettl, M. cit., p. 157. Ministerium der Finanzen der Deutschen Demokratischen Republik, Das neue Preisrecht, pp. 11-19. U. 12. Nettl, . cit., p. 155. 13. Ibid., p. 211. 14. Ibid., pp. 160, 242. 15. Ibid., pp. 132, 134, xviii. 16. Ibid., p. xix.. 17. Ibid., p. 112. CIA, ORR Project 41.1, 28 Sep 1953, P. 5. S. 18. CIA, ORR Project 41.1, 28 Sep 1953, P. 5. S. 25X1 A2g 20. 21. Die Wirtschaft, No. 23, 5 Jun 1953, P. 22. Nettl, op. cit., p. 73- 23. CIA/RR IP-32 7 Organizational Structure of Soviet Control and Procurement Agencies in East Germany, 27 Jan 1953, Part II. S, US OFFICIALS ONLY. CIA, ORR Project 41.1, op. cit., p. 5. 24. Otto Walther, Verwaltung Lenkung and Planung in der Wirtschaft in der Sowjetischen Besatzungszone, Bundesministerium fuer gesamtdeutsche Fragen, Bonn, 1953, p. 20. U. 28. State, Publication 2783, op. cit., p. 161. .29. Nettl, og. cit., p. 44. 30. Ibid., p. 1717 31. Ibid., p. 160. 32. Vorstand der Sozialdemokratischen Partei Deutschlands, op. cit., p. 14. Nettl, off. cit., pp. 147, 202-206. 33. Vorstand der Sozialdemokratischen Partei Deutschlands, 2E. cit., p. 14. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C -R-E-T 34. 35. 36. 37. 38. Nettl, off. cit., p. 220. Ibid., p. 220. CIA, ORR Project 41.1, OP. cit., p. 32. Ibid., p. 30. Bundesministerium fuer gesamtdeutsche Fragen, Die Sowjetische Hand in der Deutschen Wirtschaft, Bonn, 1952, p. 71. U. 39. 25X1A 40. Die 60. 25X1 A+1 W Die Sow jetische Hand in der Deutsc en sc 25X1A 42. Np. 36 11. Netti, off. cit., p. 220. 25X1 A3 . New York Times 24 Aug 1953. U. 44. New York Times, op. cit. 45. New York Times, op. cit. 25X1 A 46. 25X1A2g 25X1A Die Sow etische Hand in der Deutschen Wirtsc a , op. cit., p- 7? Walther, op. cit., p. 33. 47. CIA, ORR Project 22.19, 1953, p? 9? S, US OFFICIALS ONLY. Walther, op. cit., p. 33. 48. Walther, 2.. cit., p. 33. 49. Die Sowjetische Hand in der Deutschen Wirtschaft, op. cit., p. 30. 50. Ibid., p. 51,. Ibid., p. 30. 31. 52. Die Sow e isc e an in aer Deutschen Wirtschaft, op. cit., 53. 54. 55. 56. 57. 58. - 71 - S-E-C-R-E-T p. 31. Ibid., p. 33. Ibid. Ibid. Ibid. I Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T 59. STATSPEC 60. 61. 62. 63. 64. 65. 66. 25X1A 67. 68. 69. 25X1A2g 70. .71. 72. 73? 25X1 A 74 . 75. 25X1A 76. 77. 78. 79. 80. 81. Ibid., p. 38. Ibid. CIA, ORR Project 41.1, op.. cit.., p. 44. Ibid., pp. 44-46. Nettl, op. cit . , pp. 225 ff. Nettl, op. ?cit . , pp. 225 ff. New York Times, . cit. Nettl, op. cit., p. 255. Vorstand der Sozialdemokratischen pp. 52 if. Partei Deutschlands, off. cit., Vorstand der Sozialdemokratischen Partei Deutschlands, op. cit., p. 21. New York Times, op. cit. Die Sowjetische Hand in der Deutschen Wirtschaft, op. cit., p. 87. New York Times, op. cit. Vorstand der Sozialdemokratischen Partei Deutschlands, Nettl, Ibid., Ibid. op. cit., p. xviii. p. 137+. Das Wirtschaftsjahr, 1953, _ - 9 4 25X1A Verlag Die Wirtschaft, Berlin, STATSPE. Gesetzblatt der Deutschen Demokratischen Republik,, May 1952, p. 07. u. Das Wirtschaftsjahr, 1953, op. cit., p. 111. U. 84. 25X1A -72- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release .1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 25X1A S-E-C-R-E-T 85. Das Wirtschaftsjahr,. 1953, op. cit., p. 112. 86. 87. Nettl, op. cit., p. 83. 88. CIA, ORR Project 6-51, The European Satellite Power Complex, 26 Sep 1951, p. 12. S. 89. Walter Ulbricht, "Lehren des xix Parteitages der KPdSU fuer den Aufbau des Sozialismus in der Deutschen Demokratischen Republik," Einheit, Dec 1952, p. 1306. U. 90. Das Wirtschaftsjahr, 1952, Verlag Die Wirtschaft, Berlin, 25X1X7 91. 1951, p. 103. U. Ibid., pp. 102-103. 93. CIA, ORR, DI contribution to Project 0.2 (1953). S. 94. Bartho Plonies and Otto Schonwalder, Die SowJetisierung des Mitteldeutschen Handwerks, Bundesministerium fuer gesamtdeutsche Fragen, Bonn, 1951, p. 7. U. 95. Ibid., pp. 9-20. 96. Ibid., p. 41. 97. Felix Poehler, Die Vermichtun des privaten Grosshandels in der Sowjetischen Besatzungszone, p. 34. U. 98. Ibid., p. 23- 99. Ibid.,. pp. 39-41. 100. Felix Poehler, Der Untergang des privaten Einzelhandels in der Sowjetischen Besatzungs zone, Bundesministerium fuer gesamtdeutsche Fragen, Bonn, 1952. U. 101. Berliner Zentralbank, The Economic Development in West Berlin and in the Soviet Zone, 2d edition, revised, Berlin, 1952, P. 53. U. 25X1X7102. Das Wirtschafts abr 1953, 0 . cit., p. 227. 25X1A 103' 104. 105. CIA FDD, u-4415, 21 Aug 1953. C. 106. K. von der Neide, Raiffeisens Ende in der Sowjetischen Besatzungszone,'Bundesministerium fuer gesamtdeutsche Fragen, Bonn, 1952. U. 107. Mathias Kramer, Die Landwirtschaft in der Sowjetischen Besatzungszone, Bundesministeriumn fuer gesamtdeutsche 25X1A Fr en Bonn. U. 108. 25X1A 109. Das Wirtschaftsjahr, 1953, ? cit-., p. 94. 110. 111. Walther, op. cit., p. 20. - 73 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T 25X1A2g 25X1A2g 25X1A 121. 113. Die Materialversorgung, Verlag Die Wirtschaft, Berlin, 1952, p. 33. U. 114+. Walther, op. cit., pp. 29-33. 115. Ibid., p. 30. 116. Ibid. 117. Ibid. 118. 119. 120. Die Wirtschaft, No. 22, Berlin 122. id. 123. 124. 125. 25X1 A 126. P. 1141. U. 130. Ibid., 22 Dec 1950, p. 1233, U- 131. Das Wirtschaftsjahr, 1953, op. cit., p. 138. 132. Gesetzblatt der Deutschen Demokratischen Republik, CIA FDD, Q592, 28 May 1953. S. CIA FDD, Q586, 15 May 1953. S. CIA FDD, Q517, 28 oct 1952. S. Walther, o.. cit., p. 30. "Die statistisches Berechterstattun.g zum Volkswirtschaftsplan 1951," Statistisches Praxis, Berlin, 1951, vol. 5. U. 127. Ministerium der Finanzen tier DDR, Das neue Preisrecht, Berlin, p. B 1. U. 128. Gesetzblatt der Deutschen Demokratischen Republik, No. 22, 21 Feb 1953, P. 31 4. U. 129. Gesetzblatt der Deutschen Demokratischen Republik, 6 Dec 1951, 21 Apr 1950, 133. 25X1A - 74 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T 134. Ibid. 135. Ibid., p. U. 25X1A Die Wirtschaft, No. 38, Berlin, 18 Sep 1953, p. 5? U. 25X1A 138. Ibid. 139. Ibid., p. 13. 140. 141. as r sc a s , 1953, op, cit., pp. 142. Gesetzblatt der Deutschen Demokratischen Republik, 2 Oct 1952, p. g b2. U. 143. Ibid., 31 Jan 1953, p. 165- 144. Die Wirtschaft, No. 5, Berlin, 30 Jan 1953, p. 2. U. 145. Gesetzblatt der Deutschen Demokratischen Republik, 146. 147. 148. 25X1A 3 Feb 1953, p. 175. U. Ibid., 27 Feb 1953, p.? 329. U. Ibid., 10 Mar 1953, pp? 392 if. U. Ibid., 14 Apr 1953, p. 543? U. 149. Die Wirtschaft, 22 May 1953, Berlin, p. 1. U. 150. CIA ORR estimate. 151. Die Wirtschaft, 13 Jun 1953, Berlin, p. 1. U. 25X1A8a 152. 153. 154. 155. 156. 25X1A ,STATSPEC 25X1A2g 75 - S-E-C-R-E-T 157. 158. 159. 160. 161. Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E?-T 162. 25X1A8a 163. 25X1A6a Die Wirtschaft, 11 Sep 1953, Berlin, p. 6. U. 164+. Economic Data on Potsdam Germany,. Office for Military Government US 1947. U. 25X1 X7 165- 166. 25X1A 167. 168. CIA, ORR Project 1 4.1, op. cit. 169. Colin Clark, Conditions of Economic Progress, 2d edition, 1951, pp. 90 ff. U. 17O. United Nations, National Income Statistics, 1938-48, 25X1 X7 171. . 80 ff . U. 172. Nettl, off. cit., p. xviii. 173. Ibid., pp. 2771ff. 174. Ibid. 17~ . CIA estimate. 176. Recomputed on a 1938 base from the following sources: a. International Financial Statistics, Jun 1953, p. 86. U. b. Statistisches Jahrbuch fuer die Bundesrepublik Deutschlands, 1952. U. c. Wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Institut der Gewerkschaeten, Deutschland in Zahlen, 1950, Cologne, Bund Verlag, 1951. U. 177. Statistisches Praxis, Oct 1953. U. 178. Wirtschaft and Statistik, Statistisches Bundesamt, Bonn, Jun 1953, p. 23 . U- 179. Das Wirtschaftsjahr, 1952, 2E. cit., p. 101. 180. Ibid., p. 115. STATSPE(~-81. Die Wirtschaft, Berlin, 20 Feb 1953. U- 82. 183. Die Wirtschaft, Berlin, 1 Aug 1953. U. Ibid., 1 Nov 1953. 184. Ibid., 1 Nov 1953- STATSPEC 185. 186. Ma. 1 c , p. . 25X1 A 187. Ibid., 30 Jul 1953, p. EE 21. 25X1A2g 188. 189. Ibid., p. 5. 190. -76- S-E-G-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T 25X1A 25X1A2g 191. 192. 193. 194. 195. 196. 197. 198. 199. STATSPEC 200. 25X1A2g 25X1 A 203. 201. 202. Contribution to ORR Project 0.2, The Economy of East Germany, Commerce, World Trade Compilation from Official Sources, 25X1A2g 2o4. 205. 25X1A2g 25X1A2g 25X1A Ibid., p. 5. Bundesministerium fuer gesamtdeutsche Fragen, Die Bevoelkerungsbilanz der Sowjetischen Besatzungszone, 1939 bis 1949, supplement, "Die Volkszahlung 1950," Bonn, 1951. U. Statistisches Jahrbuch fuer die Bundesrepublik Deutschland, 1952, Stuttgart-Cologne, 1953? U. CIA ORR, D/M/AG contribution to Project 0.2, 1953. S. Bundesministerium fuer gesamtdeutsche Fragen, Der Aussenhandel der Sowjetischen Besatzungszone Deutschlands, Bonn, 1953, pp. 4-6. U. Bundesministerium fuer gesamtdeutsche Fragen, Der Aussennancte der Sowjetischen Besatzungszone Deutschlands, Bonn, 1953, pp. 4-6. U. 206. CIA, ORR, S/TF, The Foreign Trade of East Germany, 19+8-52, 207. 208. 209. 210. - 77 - S-E-C-R-E-T pp. 5a passim. S. US OFFICIALS ONLY. This reference con- stitutes the source of all data on East-West trade of East Germany. Commerce, 1952, OP. cit. Ibid., 1951, 1952. Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 25X1A2g Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T 240. Ibid. 241. Ibid. 242. Bundesminister.fuer Vertriebene, "Ueb.ersicht.ueber_die Zuwanderer aus der Sowjetischen Besatzungszone and dem Sowjetischen Sektor von Berlin (S BZ) seit 1949," IV 2 a-8610-7043/53, 4 Jul 1953, p. 5- 243- West Germany: 1949: Wirtschaft and Statistik, Vol. 2, No. 3, Jun 1950, p. 77. 1950: Yearly total: Statistische Berichte, VIII/12/6, 5 Nov 1951; 1st quarter, ibid., VIII/12/1, 4 Sep 1950 2d quarter, ibid., VIII/12/2, 7 Oct 1950 3d quarter, ibid., VIII/12/3, 1 Mar 1951 4th quarter, ibid., VIII/12/4, 30 Apr 1951. 1951: 1st quarter, ibid... VIII/12/5, 14 Jul 1951 2d quarter, ibid., VIII/12/7, 8 Nov 1951 3d quarter, ibid., VIII/12/8, 6 Feb 1952 4th quarter,, ibid., VIII/12/9, 23 May 1952. 1952: 1st quarter, ibid., VIII/12/10, 1 Sep 1952 2d quarter, ibid., VIII/12/11, 2 Jan 1953 3d quarter, ibid., VIII/12/12, 25 Mar 1953. 1948: Berliner Statistik, Vol. 3, No. 12, Dec 1949, pp. 292-293. 1949: Ibid., Vol. 3, No. 12, Dec 1949, pp. 292-293 Ibid., Vol. 5, Nos. 7 and 8, Jul and Aug 1951, p. 169. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 S-E-C-R-E-T 1st quarter, ibid., Vol. 4, Nos. 5 and 6, May and Jun 1950,,P. 117 2d quarter, (,ibid., Vol. 4, No. 9, Sep 1950, p. 213 3d quarter, ibid., Vol. 5, No. 1, Jan 1951, p. 22 4th quarter, ibid., Vol--5, No. 6, Jun 1951, p. 149. 1951 and 1952: Migration between West Berlin and the Soviet Zone: Berliner Statistik, Sonderdienst, No. 33 7 Jul 1951 and No. 48 (31 Aug 1951) Berliner Statistik, Quellenwerk, Reihe Bev oelkerungswesen , Nos. 3 (26 Sep 195 6 ( 27 Nov 1951), 9 (22 Dec 1951), 11 (28 Jan 1952), 13 (21 Feb 1952), 15 (31 Mar 1952), 18 (7 May 1952), and 20 (4 Jun 1952). 1), Migration between West Berlin and East Berlin: Berliner Statistik, Beilage: Zahlenaus Verwaltung and Wirtschaft, Jan and Feb 1950- Feb 1953. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6 Approved Far Release I999i09102 : CIA-RDP79 Q1993Ab004E}O170001--6' OFFICIALS ONLY Approved for Release 1999/09/02 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000400170001-6