STUDIES IN INTELLIGENCE. VOL. 1

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP78T03194A000100010001-2
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
C
Document Page Count: 
144
Document Creation Date: 
December 20, 2016
Document Release Date: 
May 5, 2005
Sequence Number: 
1
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
December 9, 2003
Content Type: 
SINT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP78T03194A000100010001-2.pdf19.83 MB
Body: 
For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 ":`.; is{(.a A!iLh vC.J & ittCUROS (L1 Il 1,04MiA RLY AMR USE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78T03194A000100010001-2 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY The Need for an Intelligence Literature Articles by Sherman Kent and the Editors I STUDIES IN Intelligence CENTRAL INTELLIGENCE AGENCY OFFICE OF TRAINING ? SEPTEMBER 1955 N MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY ' FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY MORI/HRP THIS PAGE All opinions expressed in the Studies are those of the authors. They do not represent the official views of the Central Intelligence Agency or of the Office of Training. Address all comments and inquiries to ... Office of Training ? ext. 2428 Subsequent issues will be disseminated widely throughout the Agency! To make sure of receiving copies, or to secure extra copies, please call the extension listed above. NTRODUCTION )y The Director of Training l N the two articles that follow, Sherman Kent and The Edi- tors explain in detail why we are starting this mono- graph series, Studies in Intelligence, and how we are going about the job. I should like first to explain the posi- tion of the Office of Training. Our chief responsibility here in Training is, of course, to teach. In order to do this effectively, we have to be very clear in our minds that what we teach corresponds to the best intelligence doctrine and method available. To train in- telligence officers, we must first define and clarify those basic principles which should be the common property of every member of the profession. The basic principles I have in mind concern the mission of intelligence, and the organiza- tion, techniques, and methods of intelligence activities. From the beginning, the Office of Training has necessarily been engaged in the production of written materials to be used in specific training courses. But it has become increas- ingly apparent to us that there is a need for a broader approach to the problem of building up a foundation of doc- trine and method which is basic to the intelligence profession and all its activities. It is also clear that we have a degree of responsibility for meeting this problem. I believe that the production of these Studies will be a step in the direction of creating a literature of basic doctrine and methodology useful both to the training activity and to the MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY Agency as a whole. In sponsoring this endeavor, I therefore urge your active participation and support so that we may all benefit in advancing the profession of intelligence by this means. MATTHEW BAIRD Director of Training FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY MORI/HRP THIS PAGE THE NEED FOR AN INTELLIGENCE LITERATURE by Sherman Kent I N most respects the intelligence calling has come of age. What has happened to it in the last fourteen years is extraordinary. Maybe our present high is not so ex- traordinary as our low of 1941. In that day the totality of government's intelligence resources was trifling. We knew almost nothing about the tens of thousands of things we were going to have to learn about in a hurry. As emergencies developed we round ourselves all too reliant upon British intelligence. Many of us recall important studies issued by US intelligence organizations which were little more than verbatim transcripts of the British ISIS reports. In 1941, the number of people who had had prior intelli- gence experience and who at the same time were available for new government assignments in intelligence was very small. There were few in Washington who could give any guidance as to how to go about the business in hand. What intelligence techniques there were, ready and available, were in their infancy. Intelligence was to us at that period really nothing in itself; it was, at best, the sum of what we, from our outside experience, could contribute to a job to be done. it did not have the attributes of a profession or a discipline or a calling. Today things are quite different. Let me briefly note the principal assets of today's intelli- gence community. To begin with, we are at strength. Per- MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 2 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY haps we are not as strong as the present volume of work requires, but by and large we have the staff to do the man- sized job before us. Again, we are not novices at our business; we have a lot of experience behind us. We are officered and manned by a large number of people with more than a decade of con- tinuous experience in intelligence, and who regard it as a career to be followed to retirement. By now we have order- ly file rooms of our findings going back to the war, and we have methods of improving the usefulness of such flies. We have orderly and standardized ways of doing things. We do most things the right way almost automatically. We have developed a host of new and powerful overt and covert techniques which have increased the number of things we can and do find out about. Most important of all, we have with- in us a feeling of common enterprise, and a good sense of With these assets, material and experiential, intelligence is more than an occupation, more than a livelihood, more than just another phase of government work. Intelligence has become, in our own recent memory, an exacting, highly skilled profession, and an honorable one. Before you can enter this profession you must prove yourself possessed of native talent and you must bring to it some fairly rigorous pre-training. Our profession like older ones has its own rigid entrance requirements and, like others, offers areas of eneral competence and areas of very intense specialization. g People work at it until they are numb, because they love it, because it is their life, and because the rewards are the re- wards of professional accomplishment. FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY MORI/HRP THIS PAGE FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY 3 Intelligence today is not merely a profession, but like most professions it has taken on the aspects of a discipline: it has developed a recognized methodology; it has developed a vocabulary; it has developed a body of theory and doctrine; it has elaborate and refined techniques. it now has a large professional following. What it lacks is a literature. From my point of view this is a matter of greatest importance. As long as this discipline lacks a literature, its method, its vocabulary, its body of doctrine, and even its fundamental theory run the risk of never reaching full maturity. I will not say that you cannot have a discipline without a literature, but I will assert that you are unlikely to have a robust and growing discipline without one. Let me be clear about this literature that we lack. First, let me say what I do not mean that we are lacking. I do not mean the substantive findings of intelligence. Manifest- ly, I do not mean those thousands of words we disseminate each day about past, present, and probable future goings on all over the world. I do not refer to the end product of all of our labors. We produce a great deal of this sort of literature and possibly we produce too much of it. It is not that literature that I am talking about. What I am talking about is a literature dedicated to the analysis of our many- sided calling, and produced by its most knowledgeable dev- at ?ec The sort of literature I am talking about is of the nature of house organ literature, but much more. You might call it the institutional mind and memory of our discipline. When such a literature is produced, it does many things to advance the task. FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 4 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY The most important service that such a literature performs is the permanent recording of our new ideas and experiences. When we record we not only make possible easier and wider communication of thought, we also take a rudimentary step towards making our findings cumulative. We create a stock of relatively imperishable thinking which one man can ab- sorb without coming into personal contact with its originator and against which he can weigh and measure his own origi- nal ideas. His large or small addition to the stock enriches it. The point is reached where an individual mind, capable of using the stock, can in a day encompass the accumulated wisdom of man-decades of reflection and action. Consider such disciplines as chemistry or medicine or eco- nomics and ask yourself where they would be today if their master practitioners had committed no more to paper than ours. Where would we be if each new conscript to medicine had to start from scratch with no more to guide him than the advice of fellow doctors and his own experience? Where would we be in medicine if there was nothing to read and nothing to study, no text books, no monographs, no special- ized journals, no photographs, no charts, no illustrations, no association meetings with papers read and discussed and circulated in written form? Where would we be if no one aspired to the honor of publishing an original thought or con- cept or discovery in the trade journals of his profession? It is not impossible that blood letting would still be considered a valuable panacea and exposure to night swamp air the specific for syphilis. The point is that in the last few centuries we have accumu- lated an enormous amount of knowledge. And the fact that this accumulation has taken place since the discovery of FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY MORI/HRP THIS PAGE printing from movable type is by no means merely coinci- dental. The translation of new thought into words, and the commission of words to the permanence of print, more than anything else has made possible a progressive and orderly advance in all disciplines and all areas of learning. In our calling, I am saying, we do not do enough of it. To be sure we do do some writing. We have produced a good many Training Manuals of one sort or another. We have done a good bit of chronicling of interesting case studies with an educational end in view. We have made transcripts of oral presentations at training centers. If you ransacked the "libraries" of intelligence schools you would find quite an amount of written material. Even so there is a very con- siderable difference between this volume of written material and the systematic professional literature I am talking about. It is hard to define such a literature, and I will not try to do it in a sentence or two. As a starter I will note what I think to be three important aspects of it. To begin with, the literature I have in mind will deal with first principles. A portion of it will 'certainly have to deal with the funda- mental problem of what we are trying to do. What is our mission? And as soon as that question is submitted to care- ful analysis, there is no telling what will emerge. One thing I think is certain: that is, that we have many more than a single mission and that many of us have been confused not only about the number and character of the many missions, but also how each of the many relates to the others. Another first principle that will have to be elaborated is how we are going about our mission - what is our method? Here again we will find out, when the question is systemat- MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 6 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY ically answered, that there is not a single method, but that there are dozens of methods; and from further examination or discussion we will confront a good many new concepts which will speed our task and enrich our product. Let no one feel either that we are necessarily sure of the nature of our first principles or that dispassionate examina- tion of them would be a waste of time. In recent months the intelligence community has had to wrestle with such funda- mental concepts as "national intelligence objectives" and the criteria for the selection of such objectives; the nature of "warning"; the role of "indications" and so on. The results of these discussions have been generally praiseworthy, but the amount of time consumed and the consequent delay of important decisions quite otherwise. An analogous situa- tion might be a consultation of surgeons deadlocked on a discussion of the nature of blood, preliminary to handling the emergency case presently on the operating table. This takes me to a second thing which I would expect from a systematic literature of intelligence: a definition of terms. Hastily let me add that I am not proposing that we write a dictionary. Words which stand for complicated concepts cannot be defined by a dictionary. Words like "liberalism" and "democracy" require the equivalent of scores of diction- aries, or scores of shelves of dictionaries. You cannot define those as you define "paper" and "ink." So with our own words that stand for complicated concepts - such as "evalua- tion," "indicator," "capability," "estimates," and so on. As of today we use these words easily and often - yet one won= ders if they are always understood in exactly the way in- tended. For example, we would be almost tongue-tied with- out the word "capability"; we use it perhaps more often than FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY MORI/HRP THIS PAGE any other of our semi-technical words. Yet a little reflection on the matter shows that we use it indiscriminately to mean one of three quite different things: a feasible course of ac- tion, a raw strength, and a talent or ability. Can we be sure that we are always conveying an intended sense?* If we do not rigorously define our terms we are likely to find ourselves talking at cross purposes; and such discussion, we all realize, risks being more of a fruitless dispute than an elevated debate. This takes me to a third point. The literature I have in mind will, among other things, be an elevated debate. For example, I see a Major X write an essay on the theory of indicators and print it and have it circulated. I see a Mr. B brood over this essay and write a review of it. I see a Commander C reading both the pre- ceding documents and review them both. I then see a revitalized discussion among the people of the indicator busi- ness. I hope that they now, more than ever before, discuss indicators within the terms of a common conceptual frame and in a common vocabulary. From the debate in the litera- ture and from the oral discussion I see another man coming forward to produce an original synthesis of all that has gone before. His summary findings will be a kind of intellectual platform upon which the new debate can start. His platform will be a thing of orderly and functional construction and it will stand above the bushes and trees that once obscured the view. It will be solid enough to have much more built upon it and durable enough ak... I in the oust gu Sv that no one need get bath utc bushes and earth to examine its foundations. Editor's Note: In our next monograph, one of Mr. Kent's colleagues, Abbot Smith, takes up precisely this: problem in his article Capabilities in National Estimates. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY Now if all this sounds ponderous and a drain on time, I can only suggest that, so far, we of the Western tradition have found no faster or more economical way of advancing our understanding. This is the way by which the Western world has achieved the knowledge of nature and humanity that we now possess. These are only three things that I would expect from this literature. There are many others. It could and should record such things as new techniques and methods, the history of significant intelligence problems and accomplishments, the nature of intelligence services of other countries, and so on. But the three items that I have singled out remain the most important. There are perils of going forward in our profession without laying down such a literature. First, there are the obvious perils of denying our calling the advantages I have discussed above. There is, however, another peril and one we should heed for strictly utilitarian reasons. As things now stand, we of the intelligence profession possess practically no per- manent institutional memory. Our principal fund of knowl edge rests pretty largely in our heads; other funds of knowl- edge are scattered in bits through cubic miles of files. Whatj happens to our profession if we are demobilized as we were after the two world wars? What happens to it if our heads} and files find themselves in the middle of a nuclear explosion? The answer, I fear, is that a new beginning will have to bel made virtually from scratch. Most of what we know will go when we go; only a very small part will be left behind. A ence is a reasonable insurance policy f intelli t li g ure o tera against repetition of two demobilizations of intelligence that have occurred within our memory. FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY 9 In highlighting the desirability of producing a literature of intelligence and stressing the perils of not producing one, I do not wish to seem to close my eyes to problems and difficul- ties. The first of these is probably the matter of security. One can expect the question: "Do you want to put all the secrets of the profession in writing and bind them up in one great book so that your enemy's success with a single target will at once put him abreast of you?" The answer comes in two parts. In the first place, many of the most important con- tributions to this literature need not be classified at all. They could be run in the,daily press and our enemies would get no more good from them than from the usual run of articles published in our professional journals. Surely the enemy would benefit in some degree; he would benefit as he pres- ently does from his reading of The Infantry Journal or Foreign Affairs. On the other hand, another type of contribution would deal with delicate trade secrets and would have to be classified. But is this reason not to write or circulate it? Every day we have to decide on the correct security pro- cedure with respect to sensitive materials. Why should the literature at instance be necessarily more delicate or sensi- tive than the last cable from Paris, and why should its proper handling be more difficult or dangerous? In this case, as in the more familiar one of the sensitive report, we must again equate the value of exposing many minds to a problem with Ihn increasing danger of disclosure. The plain fact is that .t?curity" and the advance of knowledge are in fundamental conflict. The only reason we get anywhere is because we do not demand either perfect security or unlimited debate about secrets of state. We do get somewhere because the FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY MORI/HRP THIS PAGE MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 10 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY necessity for compromise at both ends is well and fully under- stood. There is another difficulty and a very practical one. How is such a literature to be written if most or all of the potential authors are practicing members of the profession, already burdened with seemingly higher priority tasks? I know of no magic formula by which a man can do two things at once. The question that we face is the familiar one of priorities. Surely one of the guiding principles to a solution is the de- sirability of investing for the future. Taking Mr. X off the current task and giving him the time to sort out his thoughts and commit them to paper will more than repay the sacrifice if what Mr. X puts down turns out to be an original and per- manent contribution. If it buttons up a controversial matter and precludes thousands of hours of subsequent discussion, the cause has been well served. It has been well served even though one of Mr. X's would-be consumers had to get along without his advice on another matter. What we are faced with in this case is nothing more complicated than the value and pain of capital formation. A third problem. How may the Mr. X's be paid for work- time spent in the creation of this literature? If what has gone, before is the fact and the Mr. X's of the calling are really creating intelligence capital, then it seems to me that they are entitled to their wage exactly as if engaged upon thei regular assignments. Indeed, in logic, if what Mr. X pr duces contributes to the solution of the next hundred prob lems, he should be paid more than if he spent his time merely solving the single assigned problem before him. FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY MORI/HRP THIS PAGE FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY 11 Beyond these rather fundamental matters, there are hun- dreds of other problems. If a large proportion of the Mr. X's are sure to come from intelligence staffs, where do they work? Are they to have secretarial help? Will they keep regular hours? Must they be in residence? How will their findings be reproduced? How circulated? What editorial controls will be exercised over their output? These are really easy questions. The hard ones are to find the Mr. X's in the first place, and to induce them to undertake the most difficult job of all: original creative writing. FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 12 FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY THE CURRENT PROGRAM FOR AN INTELLIGENCE LITERATURE by The Editors WE agree with the basic ideas set forth by Mr. Kent. We agree that there is a need for a written litera- ture of intelligence theory and methods; that this literature should attempt to define, criticize, and improve on the "first principles" of, intelligence; and that this literature can only be written by experienced officers, presenting their own personal views. This monograph series, Studies in In- telligence, is a first modest attempt to meet these needs. We will, from time to time, publish articles that seem to us to carry forward the purposes that Mr. Kent has attributed to a professional literature. Some articles will deal with methods of analysis and operations, some with critical defini- tions, some with problems of organization, and some with the special contribution of particular disciplines to the intelligence; effort. Taken all together, we hope, these studies may get' us started on the systematic examination of basic intelligence theory and methods. It is hard to pin down precisely what we mean by basi theory, but we can identify its services to the intelligence effort and the way it gets formulated. By theory we mea that body of hypotheses that guides the intelligence office in his day-to-day practical activities, that lends some co sistency to these activities and gives him a basis for measuring how he is doing on his job. Mr. Kent calls this body of by FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY MORI/HRP THIS PAGE FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY 13 potheses "first principles" and says that with them as a basis, the intelligence community makes best use of its experience and develops professional expertness. Such first principles are not rigid; they are always subject to change or, at least, refinement; and they are built up - or have been, by the academic disciplines - through a process of cumulative in- dividual contributions by members of the profession. It is just this building process that we want to stimulate. What, then, is the practical upshot of this? First, the Office of Training will act as sponsor only. Our job will be that of generating interest in the program, getting studies written, exploiting some studies that already exist in personal and office files, exercising and coordinating editorial judgment, and finally providing the publication medium for contribu- tions to this literature. Second, the studies will in every case be the contributions of identified Agency officers (sometimes we will have to use pseudonyms, for security reasons, but the general rule will remain the same) and will represent only their own best views. And third, these views will in no case be put forward as Agency or Office of Training doctrine. Naturally, we will be responsible for the good sense and factual accuracy of what we publish, but not for the sub- stance of the arguments and criticisms and opinions ex- pressed. We will operate on the premise that the enterprise is worth doing but that its quality will depend entirely on the interest of Agency people - and on their personal contribu- tions. Background and Charter Over the past seven or eight years, there have been any number of suggestions for "professionalizing" the intelligence MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 business - including everything from a trade journal to a graduate school of intelligence. Common to all of them, though, has been some such major premise as the one that Mr. Kent so persuasively states above, that intelligence will .come of age as a profession only if it recaptures its experi- ence and the refinements of its methods in a permanent literature. In September 1954, the Director of Training con- vened a group of senior Agency officers to consider how best to go about the job. This monograph series is a direct re- sult of last year's discussion. There are, the conferees agreed, two quite different sorts of intelligence literature. One comprises overt material which, whatever its stated purpose, in effect contributes to our think- ing about intelligence and its methodology. Some of this material is, in fact, avowedly about intelligence - in the bulk of cases about clandestine operations. But there is still more overt literature which can sometimes be studied with profit by intelligence officers - books, for example, about social science methodology or about national policy-making proc esses. Most issues of our Studies in Intelligence, therefore will have a bibliographic section, devoted to spotting and r viewing some of this material. Occasionally an entire stud will be given over to a collective discussion and critique c a whole bloc of overt material - as, for example, a stud now being written for us on the current state of social scienc methodology, with the emphasis on science, and its possibli relevance to the intelligence process. The second major category of intelligence literature is whd we are primarily concerned with. This is the material the can only be prepared by experienced intelligence office and will usually be classified because of references to tl% MORI/HRP THIS PAGE FOR OFFICIAL USE ONLY 15 mission and product of the intelligence community. Many officers have formulated, even though vaguely, certain prin- ciples or methods drawn from their experience in dealing with a succession of problems or cases. Or, conversely, they have come to feel that their experience challenges the valid- ity of a commonly-held concept. These ideas occasionally become the subject of an office memorandum or get dis- cussed informally; more often they simply evaporate in the heat of current business. In any event, they are not care- fully thought through and then presented for the enlighten- ment and serious consideration of interested associates. We hope that the Studies series will provide a vehicle through which such experienced officers can systematically speak their minds. Organization and Procedure Our current procedure for obtaining contributions to the series is simply to encourage various Agency officers to pre- pare studies about the problems in which they are especially expert, which they deal with continuously in their work, and which they think are so fundamental to so much of the busi- ness of intelligence as to be appropriate subjects for a basic literature. Thus, when we wanted an article on "capabili- ties" analysis in the estimative process, we turned to Abbot Smith of the Office of National Estimates - whose study, by the way, will appear soon in this series. When a study arrives at our desk, we first send it out to a number of other men whose experience qualifies them'as critics and advisers, and ask: Is this piece worth publishing? Should it be revised? If so, precisely how? After the advice and criticism is in, however, it is up to the author to decide MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 what he wants to sign his name to; and it is up to us to decide whether to publish at all. When we send out articles for comment, we are certainly not seeking "coordination." We will be happy enough if our preliminary readers will agree that the author's point of view is sound and knowledgeable; we surely do not count on agreement about substance. Nor do we imagine that one article will necessarily exhaust a subject. When we can pre- dict that a subject will clearly break down into two or more conflicting points of view, we will try to find representatives of each and publish a symposium. Usually, though, we will depend on reader-reactions, in the form of letters to the edi- tor (which will be published) and suggestions for further studies. To borrow again from Mr. Kent's terminology: we will never avoid debate but concentrate on keeping it "eleva- ted." Our dependence on soliciting studies is, we hope, only tem- porary. If the project is worth anything, one proof will pre- sumably be the amount of interest it arouses - and the num- ber of unsolicited suggestions received. The address is 2204 Alcott Hall; or call C. M. Lichenstein at ext. 2428. We wel come comments on the first studies,and prospectuses for more. To be more specific about our publication program, thes are some of the studies now underway, all of which shout appear before the year is out: "Capabilities" in National Intelligence Estimates The Nature and Role of Economic Intelligence - an Some of its Methods of Analysis MORI/HRP THIS PAGE The Scientific Method and the Intelligence Process Administration in Intelligence Theory of Indicators - and a Case Study "Readability" in Intelligence Publications Scanning this list, one will see that we are not in the sub- stantive intelligence business; we are not competing with any producing Agency office; indeed, we will not publish finished intelligence at all. On the contrary, we want to publish studies that could not possibly appear as finished intelligence analysis or as opera- tional support under official Agency auspices (but might be prepared as preliminary, methodological working papers); studies that deal with the way an intelligence officer does his job, with the techniques and methods he uses. To each pro- posal we will apply the criterion: will this paper contribute to the professional theoretic literature, as best it can be defined? Rather than prepare a list of possible study topics, then, we want to review each prospectus or manuscript that reaches us against this criterion. After we have been publishing for a time, we hope that our own experience and the criticism of many readers will have sharpened understanding of the exact nature of this basic literature and how best to get it written. Certainly the sub- stance of the publications and our own operating procedures are equally subject to change for the better - and, in both cases, the major share of the burden seems to us to be on the people who have made intelligence a respected profes- sion. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 MORI/CDF THIS PAGE MORI/CDF THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 EDITORS INTRODUCTION ecting the;Ivataonal material contains, information aff Defense of the',United States" within the';meaning o` 2lie ,espionage laws, :Title 18, USC,7Sees. 793 and 794, the trans- 'mission or`revelation of which to an unauthorized person~is prohibited by law. Office ??of. Training- Subsequent-issues willbe disseminated end y s. pg P. ~ he pg ~y~~'~ol~make~ sure of frecei~ o ecure ,extra copies, please call; the extensio MORI/CDF THIS PAGE sag= Central~Intelligence Agency ~i of the Otfice~of sTraininng N September, the Office of Training issued the introductory number of Studies in Intelligence. Our purpose, we said, was to stimulate thinking and writing about the f unda- mentals of intelligence work, and to sponsor the beginnings of a professional intelligence literature. We especially empha- sized two requirements basic to the production of such a litera- ture: first, all that we publish will be entirely unofficial and will represent only the opinions of the individual author, second, the success of the project will depend on participation by the whole intelligence community. Successive Studies, that is, to sav, will appear only as worthwhile manuscripts reach our ii ly d a a what esk; and we will be able to judge himpact of w`11aL we pub- iish only as we receive reader comments. presenting this issue on "capabilities" we call your atte n tion to a concept whose applications extend to nearly every aspect of intelligence work. Just about everyone, at one time or another, is in the capabilities business, from the case officer who keeps current and reports on the "capabilities" of a nation- al Communist Party to the Board of National Estimates which turns out exhaustive studies on the "capabilities" of the Soviet Bloc. One of the classic definitions of intelligence is, indeed, "the analysis of the capabilities and vulnerabilities of foreign countries, relevant to US security interests." Both authors tackle the subject at its most basic: what do we mean by the word and, if our meaning is not always clear and consistent, what should we mean? What experience do we draw on in analyzing "capabilities" and how, in specific cases, does the R llai'cic r,rnnnoA9 born Abbot E. Smith and Harold D. Kehm bring to bear on the subject an abundance of experience in intelligence (spe- ally r. capabilities analysis) and related fields Mr. Smith, it Rhodes Scholar and a distinguished historian, has taught at MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Bard College and Columbia University. During World War II, and immediately after, he served in the US Navy in a variety of roles: as Acting Chief, Naval Division, Allied Command in Austria; as Chief of the Historical Section, US Naval Forces in Europe; and as a member of the Historical Section, Joint Chiefs of Staff. Since 1943, Mr. Smith has been with CIA. Col. Kehm has been an Instructor in Economics and Govern- ment at West Point and Chief of Instructor Training at the Command and General Staff College, G-2 of the Ninth Army during World War II, Army Attache in Dublin, and Assistant Commandant (i.e., Chief of the School) at the Strategic In- telligence School. Col. Kehm joined this Agency in 1954. The two articles that follow by no means exhaust the subject at hand - it is much too broad and involves too many side- issues for that. At least two directly related problems, each worth a Study in itself, have occurred to us as we have reflected on Mr. Smith's and Col. Kehm's contributions. One is the problem of the special characteristics of national, as distinct from departmental, intelligence. To put it in the form of a question: to what extent is the experience and the methodology of, e.g., military intelligence directly applicable to the produc- tion of national intelligence? The terminology has carried over, to be sure; but in Mr. Smith's and Col. Kehm's articles there are differences in usage of the capabilities concept that may result in part from basic differences in the problems the national and the military intelligence officer are asked to solve. Then, too, there is the problem, raised in both articles, of the lack of a national G-3 - which may, again, complicate the process of applying the systematic and time-tested methodology of the military intelligence officer to national intelligence. And surely there are many other problems of "capabilities" that could usefully be addressed in subsequent issues of this series; these are but two of the more obvious. We invite suggestions and prospectuses, therefore, for some of these unwritten Studies and comments on the present one - comments which we would like also to publish in subsequent 4 SECRET issues. To repeat something we think hears a lot of repeat- ing: if indeed these Studies in Intelligence are to help in the airing of intelligence principles and methods, in the recaptur- ing of experience, and eventually in the building of authorita- tive doctrine, then we are going to need the advice and the participation of every member of the intelligence profession to do the job well. CONF1DENT'P Spow MORI/HRP THIS PAGE MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 NOTES ON "CAPABILITIES" IN NATIONAL INTELLIGENCE by Abbot E. Smith W HEN CIA was established with the mission of producing "national" intelligence it perforce drew heavily for doctrine upon the military intelligence agencies. Over the years, the intelligence organizations of the armed forces had developed a well-tested routine. Formulas were available to meet various requirements. Agreement had gradually been reached on what needed to be known about the enemy, what data were necessary for the estimate, why they were necessary, and how they could most usefully be presented. CIA had no counterpart to this doctrine. It therefore frequently borrowed from the military, and in no instance was this borrowing more conspicuous than in the matter of "capabilities." The doctrine of enemy capabilities is one of the most charac- teristic and useful that military intelligence has to offer. A capability is a course of action or a faculty for development which lies within the capacity of the person or thing concerned. More particularly, in military intelligence, enemy capabilities are courses of action of which the enemy is physically capable and which would, if adopted and carried through, affect our own commander's mission.* In short, a list of enemy capabili- "'capabilities, enemy -Those courses of action of which the enemy is physically capable and which if adopted will affect the accom- plishment of our mission. The term "capabilities" includes not only the genera! courses of action open to the enemy such as attack, defense, or withdrawal but also all the particular courses of action possible under each general course of action. "Enemy capabilities" are considered in the light of all known factors affecting military operations including time, space, weather, terrain, and the strength and disposition of enemy forces . . ." Dictionary of United States Military Terms for Joint Usage, issued by the Joint Chiefs of Staff. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 2 SECRET ties is a list of the things that the enemy can do. It is there- fore apt to be the most significant part of a military intelligence officer's "Estimate of the Enemy Situation." It is true, of course, that a military intelligence officer col- lects and transmits to his commander a great deal of other information. He reports on the weather, terrain, and com- munications in the zone of operations. He may set forth the politics and economics of the area. He collects and evaluates data on the enemy's order of battle, logistical apparatus, equip- ment, weapons, morale, training and the like. All this is made known to the commander, but it is still not a statement of enemy capabilities. Only when the intelligence officer has ac- quired all this information, and constructively brooded over it, can he set about describing the courses of action open to the enemy. It is this list of capabilities that tells the commander what, under the conditions existing in the area, the enemy can do with his troops, his weapons, and his equipment to affect the commander's own mission. The enumeration and description of enemy capabilities is the ultimate, or at least the penulti- mate, goal of military intelligence. It is one of the character- istic modes to which the great mass of intelligence information available is bent, in order to give the commander the knowledge of the enemy he needs to plan his own operations. Adaptation of this doctrine to the requirements of national intelligence presents at first no real difficulty. Courses of ac- tion may be attributed to persons, organizations, parties, na- tions, or groups of nations as well as to military units, and to friendly or neutral, as well as to enemy, powers. They may be political, economic, psychological, diplomatic, and so on, as well as military. It is true that a national intelligence estimate* is not made for a military commander with a clearly defined * Throughout this paper the term "national intelligence estimate" is used generally to mean not just the solemnly coordinated "Na- tional Intelligence Estimates" approved by the Intelligence Advisory Committee, but any estimate, great or small, made by any office or person producing national intelligence. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE mission, to which enemy capabilities may be referred to ascer- tain if they do in fact "affect" the carrying-out of that mission. An equivalent for the commander's mission is not far to seek, however, since national intelligence is obviously concerned only with foreign courses of action which may affect the policies or interests - above all the security interests - of the United States. It is by no means as easy to be clear about all the poli- cies and interests of the United States, and to perceive what might affect them, as it is to understand the mission of a mili- tary commander, which is supposed to be unequivocally stated in a directive from higher authority. But this is one of the reasons why a national intelligence estimate is apt to be more difficult to prepare than a military estimate of an enemy situa- tion. In national intelligence, then, capabilities may be defined as courses of action within the power of a foreign nation or organ- ization which would, if carried out, affect the security interests of the United States. It is probably unnecessary to argue that statements of capa- bilities are useful as a means of organizing and presenting na- tional intelligence. The parallel with military intelligence doc- trine seems perfectly sound. High policy-makers doubtless want to be supplied with authoritative descriptions and anal- yses of the politics, economics, and military establishments of various foreign nations, together with explanations of the ob- jectives, policies, and habitual modes of action of these nations. They need to have the best possible statistics, diagrams, pic- tures, and data in general. But when all the labor and re- search has been finished, the results collated and criticized, and the conclusions written down, it will still be worthwhile to go on to a statement of what each foreign nation or organiza- tion can do to affect the interests of the United States. This is the statement of capabilities. In recognizing, formulating, testing, and presenting foreign capabilities, intelligence doctrine comes into its own. Apart from the special function of intelligence operations in collecting MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 4 SECRET data, most of the preliminary spade-work for intelligence esti- mates is the province of other disciplines than that specifically of intelligence. This spade-work of course takes nine-tenths of the time, trouble, and space devoted to any estimate. Political scientists analyze the structure of government and politics in a foreign state; economists lay bare its economic situation; order- of-battle men reveal the condition of the military establish- ment; sociologists, historians, philosophers, natural scientists, and all manner of experts make their contribution. When all this has been done it is the peculiar function of intelligence itself to see that the learning and wisdom of experts is directed towards determining what the foreign nation can do to affect US interests. Thereby the major disciplines of social and natural science are turned to the special requirements of intelligence estimates. Let us be careful not to confuse this with the function of prophecy. To predict what a foreign nation will do is a neces- sary and useful pursuit, albeit dangerous; it rests on knowledge, judgment, experience, divination, and luck. To set forth what a nation can do is a different matter. One still needs judgment, experience and luck as well as knowledge, but soothsaying is reduced to a minimum. There is an element of the scientific. The job can be taught, and its techniques refined. It can be reduced to doctrine. Generally speaking, in military usage an enemy capability is . stated without reference to the possible counteractions which one's own commander may devise to offset or prevent such action. The Navy's handbook entitled Sound Military Decision puts it this way (italics added) : "Capabilities . . . indicate actions which the force concerned, unless forestalled or pre- vented from taking such actions, has the capacity to carry Out." MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Here are three examples: a. The Bloc has the capability to launch large-scale, short- haul amphibious operations in the Baltic and Black Seas. b. The USSR has the capability to launch general war. c. The Chinese Communists have the capability to commit and to support approximately 150,000 troops in Indochina. These statements give no estimate of what the effects or results of any of these courses of action might be. There is no indication for example that the United States or some other power might be able to make it difficult or impossible for the Chinese Communists to support 150,000 troops in Indochina, or that the West might possess such strength that a Soviet decision to launch general war would be tantamount to suicide. The statements simply lay down what the nations concerned could do, without regard to any possible opposition or counter- action. Such unopposed capabilities are frequently referred to as "gross" or "raw" capabilities. They are the kind of enemy capabilities which are reported to a military commander by his G-2, in the "Estimate of the Enemy Situation." The high policy-makers for whom national intelligence is designed, however, are not in the comparatively simple position of military commanders facing an enemy. They have broader fields to cover, and more numerous problems to face. They need to have a picture of the security situation in the world as a whole and in various areas of the world. This picture ought to show not only the multifarious forces which exist, but also the probable resultants of these forces as they act upon each other, or as they might act upon each other if they were set in motion. The policy-makers need, in short, to know about net capabilities, not merely about gross or raw capabilities. This is well understood and accepted as long as the courses of action of foreign nations alone are concerned. Nobody would think of enumerating the capabilities of France, for example, without giving due consideration to the frequently opposing capabilities of Germany, and to the tangential capa- MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 bilities of Great Britain and other powers. Even in the purely military sphere, statements of net capabilities occur in national estimates. For example: a. In Israel, an army of 49,000... is capable of defeating any of its immediate neighbors. b. The Chinese Communists have the capability for conquer- ing Burma. c. We believe that the Chinese Communists are capable of taking the island of Quemoy if opposed by Chinese Nation- alist forces only. It is an intricate and difficult operation even to attempt to work out the probable resultants of the enormous forces actu- ally or potentially at work in the world - political, economic, military, and the like. Without such an operation, however - sometimes called "war-gaming" when limited strictly to the military sphere - national intelligence estimates of capabilities would lose much of their usefulness for the particular purpose they are designed to serve. Obviously no estimate of the security situation anywhere in the world will be worth much unless the capabilities of the United States are taken into account and their effect weighed. At this point, however, grave practical difficulties arise. We of the intelligence community are solemnly warned that we must not "G-2 our own policy." Military authorities are shocked at the suggestion that we should indulge in "war- gaming." We are told that it is the function of the commander, not of the intelligence officer, to decide what counteraction to adopt against enemy capabilities, and to judge what the success of such counteraction may be. It is pointed out that no ade- quate estimate of net military capabilities can be made without a full knowledge of US war plans, and a long and highly tech- nical exercise in war-gaming by large numbers of qualified experts. Since intelligence agencies as such quite properly have no knowledge of US war plans, and possess no elaborate machinery for war-gaming, they are estopped from making MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 SECRET 7 an estimate of net capabilities where US forces are significantly involved. As a result there is, for instance, no statement in any national intelligence estimate of how the military security situation on the continent of Europe really stands, i. e., of the probable net capabilities of Soviet forces against the opposition they would be likely to meet if they attempted an invasion of the continent. This state of affairs is unfortunate, and the value of national intelligence estimates is thereby reduced below what it ought to be. The difficulty is really not one of intelligence doctrine, however. Practically nobody doubts that high policy-makers ought to be supplied with estimates of net capabilities even in situations where the US is actively engaged. It is agreed that they ought to have the best possible opinion on the security situation on the continent of Europe, and that they must be informed not merely of the gross capabilities of the USSR to launch air and other attacks on the US (the subject of an annual National Intelligence Estimate) but of what the USSR could probably accomplish by such an attack against the defenses that the US and its allies would put up. In one way or another policy-makers get such estimates of net capabilities, even if they have sometimes to make them themselves, off the cuff. The question is, then, not whether estimates of net capa- bilities are legitimate requirements, but simply who shall make them. This problem is outside the scope of a paper on intelli- gence doctrine. It may be suggested, however, that the diffi- culty has probably been somewhat exaggerated. The jealous prohibition of "war-gaming," on grounds that to conduct it requires a knowledge of US war plans and an enormous appa- ratus with numerous -personnel, is overdone. In four out of five situations where an estimate of net military capabilities is needed the judgment of wise and experienced military men, based on only a general knowledge of US war plans, is likely to be about as useful as the most elaborate and protracted piece of war-gaming. Such exercises have too often given the MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 wrong answer - they are really no more dependable as guides to the outcome of future wars than research in economics is dependable as an indicator of the future behavior of the stock market. This does not mean, of course, that economics and war-gaming are useless pursuits. Gradually, indeed, the difficulties respecting estimates of net capabilities are disappearing. In the most critical situations - air attack on the United States, for example, and perhaps the security situation in Europe - it may be necessary to establish special machinery for the most careful playing-out of the problems and ascertainment of net capabilities. In less critical situations the trouble is solving itself. Military men are be- coming a little less shy of making an educated guess as to net capabilities, even when US forces are involved, and the com- munity is not as distressed as it used to be at the accusation of "G-2-ing US policy." A doctrine is gradually being evolved by trial and error, which is as it should be. Some day it may be desirable to commit the evolved doctrine to writing, but the time has not yet arrived. Of course any foreign nation of consequence is physically capable of a vast number of courses of action which would affect the security interests of the United States. One task of intelligence (after the spade-work is complete) is to recog- nize these capabilities; another is to test them against known facts to make certain that they are real and not imaginary; a third is to test them one against another to see how many could be carried out simultaneously, and how many may be mutually exclusive; a fourth is to work out in reasonable detail the implications, for the nation concerned and for the United States, of the actual implementation of each important capa- bility. I propose to pass over all these tasks without further discussion, and to concentrate on the problem of selecting from SECRET 9 among the capabilities those which are to be included in the formal estimate. For even after all the testing is finished there will still remain far too many capabilities to put into any document of reasonable size. Considerations of space, time, and the patience of readers make it imperative that some principles of exclusion be adopted, so that the list of capabili- ties presented will be useful rather than merely exhaustive. Capabilities are excluded from national estimates for one of two reasons: either because they are judged unlikely to be actually adopted and carried through, or because they are con- sidered to be so insignificant that they could be implemented without more than minor effect on the security interests of the United States. For short we may say that they are excluded on grounds either of improbability or of unimportance. The second of these criteria does not require much discus- sion. Clearly it would be a waste of time and paper to fill a national estimate with lists of courses of action which, even if carried out, would affect the security interests of the United States only to an insignificant degree. One applies common sense in this matter, and forthwith rejects a great number of capabilities from further consideration. Along with common sense, however, there ought always to be plenty of specialized knowledge available. Everyone knows that an expert can sometimes point out major significance in things which are to the uninformed view negligible, and conversely that experts will sometimes inflate the importance of things which common sense and general knowledge can see in juster proportion. Out of discussion and argument on these matters comes the best verdict as to the importance or unimportance of a given foreign capability, and the best guidance as to whether it should be put into the formal estimate. To reject any foreign capability because we judge it unlikely to be implemented is a more serious and difficult matter. Here indeed we part company with military doctrine, which frowns upon the exclusion from an estimate of any enemy capabilities whatever, and especially condemns any exclusion on grounds MORI/HRP THIS PAGE MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 10 SECRET of improbability. There has been much debate, among the military, on whether an intelligence officer should presume to put into his formal estimate an opinion as to which of the enemy capabilities listed is most likely to be implemented. It has been said that such a judgment is for the commander alone to make, and some have even held that the commander himself must not make it, but must treat all enemy capabilities as if they were sure to be carried through, and must prepare to deal with them all. This latter doctrine is somewhat aca- demic. It is doubtful that any intelligence officer, or any commander worth his salt, has ever acted strictly in accordance with it. Yet it remains that according to the more rigorous teachings of military intelligence no enemy capability of any consequence may be omitted from the list presented to the commander. The disasters which can result from even a care- fully considered exclusion have been frequently pointed out. Nevertheless, in a national intelligence estimate we must for the reasons already stated exclude many foreign capabilities because we judge them unlikely to be carried out. The unlike- lihood is in turn generally established on one or more of three grounds, namely, that implementation of the capability (a) old objec- would be unrelated to, or incompatible with, national tives tives of the country under consideration; (b) occompulsions counter to the political, moral, or psychological ~ou d under which the nation, or its rulers, operate; entail consequences so adverse as to be unprofitable. The most obvious capabilities to exclude are those which, if implemented, would serve no objective of the nation under consideration, or would clearly run counter to some of that nation's objectives. Thus we do not bother about the possi- bility that the British might conquer Iceland, although they certainly could do so and if they did US security interests would be affected. The conquest of Iceland, however, would serve no British objective that we know of, at least in time of peace. Again, it is clearly within the power of the USSR to give up its Satellites, renounce its connections with Commu- MORI/HRP THIS PAGE SECRET 11 nist China, and retire modestly into isolation. Or the British might, in order to improve their economic condition, abandon all armaments and cease to be a world power. We do not give such capabilities serious consideration, however, because we believe them manifestly contrary to the fundamental aims of the Soviets and British respectively. By applying this sort of standard we can immediately reject a great number of courses of action which lie within the power of the nation concerned and which would affect US security interests. One must be careful in using this test, however, for national objectives change, sometimes with changes in government, sometimes without. It is, for example, impossible to be sure about the objectives which will determine West German policy in years to come. Even the Soviets do not always appear to the Western view to act in such a fashion as to serve what we estimate to be their real aims. Moreover, all nations have various objectives, many of which are to some degree incom- patible with each other. Sometimes one is governing, some- times another. Nations can even pursue simultaneously several conflicting objectives, to the confusion of their own citizenry ,LS well as of foreign intelligence officers. We must be very certain, before rejecting a foreign capability as incompatible with a national objective, that the objective is genuine, deeply- felt, and virtually certain to govern the nation's courses of action. The political, moral, or psychological compulsions which operate on a nation, or on its rulers, make the implementation f some of that nation's physical capabilities unlikely or even impossible. Thus, for example, it would probably be judged that the US is unlikely to undertake a strictly "preventive" war against the USSR because such an action, under any foreseeable US government, would be politically and morally unthinkable. It may similarly be true that the Soviet rulers are psychologically unable to establish a genuine state of peaceful coexistence with capitalist states even though they mac proclaim their desire to do so and may judge such a MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 12 SECRET course of action conducive to the ultimate aims of Communism. There are some things that nations cannot do, despite the fact that they are physically capable of doing them and might serve their national objectives thereby. To be sure, if a nation is politically, morally, or psychologi- cally incapable of pursuing a given course of action that course of action is not a capability at all, and we need not worry about it. The trouble is, however, that while physical incapabilities can generally be pretty satisfactorily established the same is rarely true of political, moral, or psychological incapabilities. One must depend more on judgment and less upon demonstrable certainty for an estimate in the matter. Not many would have estimated, before the fact, that Tito would be psychologically capable of turning against Stalin, or that the Germans would be morally capable of supporting Hitler, or that the United States would be politically capable of abandoning isolationism. Experience warns us against un- due confidence in our estimates of national character, and it will be safer to consider as capabilities all courses of action which a nation is physically able to carry through, rejecting many as improbable but none as impossible. Finally, we reject from our estimate those capabilities which would, if implemented, lead to such adverse consequences as to be unprofitable. There are, curiously enough, very few foreign capabilities which will pass the tests already mentioned,! and then have to be excluded on this ground. This is because most courses of action having indubitably dire consequences will by reason of that fact alone run counter to the objectives or to the political, moral, or psychological compulsions of the nation. Those few which are left are generally military in nature and are apt to be so important that we include them in the estimate anyway. Thus it is clear that general w with the US would be hazardous and perhaps disastrous fo: the USSR. It therefore seems highly improbable that th Soviets will deliberately run grave risks of involving themselves in such a war, yet no national estimate on the USSR would' MORI/HRP THIS PAGE SECRET 13 omit mention of the capabilities of that nation for conducting war with the US. The same holds true for the capabilities of the Nationalist Chinese to invade the mainland, or of the South Koreans to attack North Korea. We may judge such capabilities improbable of implementation, but we do not exclude them from our estimate. By applying the tests of importance and of probability, as described above, the vast number of capabilities of any foreign nation will speedily be reduced to manageable proportions. The process of exclusion will at first be almost unconscious - most capabilities will be rejected forthwith, without doubt or debate. When this stage has been accomplished, however, there will still remain a formidably long list which will require more serious consideration. Exclusion becomes more difficult, and begins to require longer discussion and maturer judgment. The same criteria of choice continue valid, but are applied with more deliberation. This is the point at which preparation of the estimate gets interesting, for the choice of capabilities to include or exclude may prove to be the most crucial decision made during the estimating process. Though we have departed from the military doctrine in allowing a rejection of capabilities judged unlikely of imple- mentation, we may still return to it for an important lesson. Like the military commander, the high policy-maker is entitled to something more than intelligence's opinion of what foreign nations will probably do. He is entitled to be informed of various reasonable alternative possibilities, and to be given some discussion of these alternatives - of their apparent ad- vantages and disadvantages, and of the reasons why intelli- gence deems them respectively to be less or more likely of implementation. National estimates sometimes discuss only the particular foreign capabilities which the intelligence com- munity in its wisdom believes will actually be carried through. 'I'bis is going too far in exclusion. Intelligence must winnow the mass of capabilities down to two or three or half a dozen MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 14 SECRET in each situation examined, but it is the responsibility of policy- makers, not of intelligence agencies, to decide which among these few last alternatives shall in fact constitute the intelli- gence basis for US policy. Looking back over old national estimates one is apt to feel that the borrowing of military terminology was sometimes a little over-enthusiastic. The word "capability," for example, offers an almost irresistible temptation to all of us who compose governmental gobbledegook. It is a long, abstract noun, of Latin derivation, and it has a pleasing air of technicality and precision. It will appear to lend portentousness to an other- wise simple statement. Perhaps this is why the word appears in estimates so frequently, unnecessarily, and sometimes even incorrectly. One trouble is that the word has a perfectly good, non- technical meaning, signifying a quality, capacity, or faculty capable of development. It is commoner in the plural, when it usually denotes in a general way the potentialities of the possessor, as when we say that a man "has good capabilities." This usage is frequent in estimates: a. The air defense capabilities of the Bloc have increased substantially since 1945. b. Chinese Communist and North Korean capabilities in North Korea have increased substantially. c. The capabilities of the new fighter aircraft are superior to, those of the old. No valid objection can be taken to these examples. Indeed, the usage is virtually the same as that of the technical term,: for the statements are about the things that the possessors of. the capabilities can do. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE One can find, however, a good many examples of slipshod usage: a. Satellite capabilities for attack on Greece and particu- larly on Turkey are too limited for conquest of those countries. b. The Tudeh Party's capabilities for gaining control of Iran by default are almost certain to increase if the oil dispute is not settled. There is no good reason for using the word "capabilities" in either of these statements; in the first the word should prob- ably be "resources," in the second, "chances" or "prospects." If one really insists on talking about capabilities then the statements ought to be rephrased: "The Satellites are not capable of conquering Greece or Turkey," and "If the oil dis- pute is not settled, conditions in Iran will be such that the Tudeh Party may acquire the capability to gain control of the country." It will be perceived that the immediately foregoing examples are statements of net capabilities, and it is in connection with such statements that imprecise drafting most frequently occurs. It must be remembered that in a relationship be- tween two nations (or other organizations) the gross capa- bilities of one side can be increased or decreased only by an increase or decrease in the strength, resources, skills, etc., of that side; what happens on the other side is irrelevant. The net capabilities of one side, however, may be altered either by a change in its own strengths and resources or by a change In those of the other side. For example, suppose that the strengths and resources of the United States and the USSR both increase in the same proportion. Then the gross capa- bilities of each side will have increased, but the net capabilities will have remained unchanged. But, if the USSR should grow weaker, while the United States made no change in its strength, then the net capabilities of the United States would have in- creased although its gross capabilities remained unchanged. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 This is simple enough, but it needs to be understood if drafting is to be accurate and clear. Consider the following example: In South Korea and Taiwan where US commitments pro- vide both physical security and political support of the established regimes, present Communist capabilities for political warfare are extremely small. If the US commit- ment and physical protection were withdrawn for any reason, substantial and early Communist political warfare successes almost certainly would occur. The first of the two sentences in this quotation can only be understood as a statement concerning gross capabilities, al- though to be sure the word is used in its non-technical sense. But the second sentence reveals that Communist gross capa- bilities, far from being "small," are in fact very considerable. The two sentences together constitute a statement of net capa- bilities, but the drafting is poor. Perhaps a rule to govern this problem may be formulated in this way: when the word "capa- bility" or "capabilities" is used in its non-technical sense, signifying in a general way the qualities, faculties, or potential of the possessor, it must be used only to refer to gross, and never to net capabilities. If there is any question, doubt or difficulty, the word ought to be avoided and a synonym chosen. Finally, even when using the word in its technical meaning of a specific course of action, the drafter ought always to make clear whether he is referring to gross or net capability. For example: We estimate that the armed forces of the USSR have a . the capability of overrunning continental Europe within a relatively short period: b. The Party almost certainly lacks the capability for seizing control of the Japanese government during the period of this estimate. The first of these statements is unclear because the word ' . "overrunning" does not indicate beyond doubt (as "conquer MORI/HRP THIS PAGE SECRET 17 or "defeat" do in some examples previously quoted) whether the statement is or is not one of net capability. Does the sentence mean that the armies of the USSR can overrun Europe against all the opposition that the West may put up? Or does it mean only that the USSR has enough men and logistical apparatus to spread into all of continental Europe within a relatively short period if unopposed? The second example is clearer, but still it does not indicate beyond doubt whether the Party is unable to seize power because the Japanese govern- ment is strong enough to prevent it, or whether the Party simply lacks the men and talent to take over the job of govern- ing Japan even if no one opposed its doing so. Apart from such suggestions for clarity in drafting as those given above, it would be premature to lay down rules for the statement of capabilities in a national intelligence estimate. Sometimes it may be desirable to list them seriatim, as the military generally do in their estimates of the enemy situation. This might be a wholesome exercise while drafting an estimate even if it were not retained in the -final version, for it would tend to promote precision, to reveal inter-relationships and produce groupings of related capabilities, and thus to prevent the indiscriminate scattering through an estimate of state- ments of capabilities in bits and pieces. On the other hand, the number and complexity of courses of action which have to be presented may often be so great that extensive listing tisouid be tedious, and attempts at grouping misleading. A connected essay (in which, incidentally, the word capability ()r capabilities need never appear) may convey the material far more adequately. These matters will be improved by experimentation, and by the talent of those who draft estimates. Improvement is worth trying for, in this as in other aspects of estimating capabilities. It is a great and responsible task to survey the whole political, economic, and military strengths of a nation, to ascertain its objectives and the moral and political compulsions that govern its conduct, to weigh all these matters in the light of that MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 18 SECRET nation's relation to other nations, to perceive what that nation could do to affect the security interests of the United States, and to select from among these manifold courses of action those sufficiently important and feasible to be included in a national estimate. The techniques of this task are still in a formative stage. They will develop through experience, through trial and error, through discussion and argument, and perhaps, from time to time, through purely theoretical and doctrinal investigation. NOTES ON SOME ASPECTS OF INTELLIGENCE ESTIMATES by Harold D. Kehm MEMBERS of the intelligence community will obviously find useful reading in the articles by Abbot Smith and Col. Kirtland.* These studies deserve the attention of other groups as well. They are of particular value to military commanders and planners and to their civilian counterparts in both government and private life. The executive and the planner are the prime consumers of the intelligence product. Furthermore, since they and not the intelligence officer are ultimately responsible for action taken, they are and should be the sharpest critics of that product. These consumers, therefore, need to understand the various kinds of approaches which the intelligence officer can make to his problem. In consultation with him, they should develop an agreed approach - embodying doctrines either as discussed in our military and other staff manuals or possibly as modified by ideas developed in these papers. Business executives and planners were mentioned above along with military and government officials because study of modern business organization and practice makes it quite clear that the more effective enterprises engage in intelligence activities in one form or another. To bring out the parallel with national and military intelli- gence, we may note that business intelligence comprises eval- .iated information concerning such matters as: the actual and potential users of the goods and services the business produces; the actions and plans of competitors; related goods and services; and other factors which bear on the production, marketing, and use of the product. Among the "intelligence MORI/HRP THIS PAGE MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 activities" in which most business organizations engage we can include market analysis, research and development, and the collection of general business information. Market analysis is essentially an intelligence activity, for it covers not only what the product may or might do but also what other firms and products may do or are doing. Credit information on firms and individuals is perhaps the most direct form of intelligence used by business. Research and development is an intelligence activity in the sense that it yields information on which to gauge the value of one's own product as well as that of actual and potential competitors. Research and development have become so im- portant that investment analysts now consider the size and quality of this effort an important factor in determining the value of a security. Finally, no business of any stature can plan without giving at least a quick glance at political, economic, and sociological data. It is inconceivable that either Ford or the UAW in 1954 planned for 1955 without considering international affairs, the domestic political situation, and the sociological "climate" which might make it propitious to raise the issue of the guar- anteed annual wage. The tremendous growth in the number of trade and commercial publications is an indication of the interest in business intelligence information. This is not the proper place to pursue this matter further and discuss whether or not business would improve its lot by openly recognizing its intelligence requirement and organizing more specifically for it. It is useful to note, however, that World War I taught business leaders the value of the line and staff principle of organization and that World War II has already given them clear object lessons in operations;; analysis and on research and development. "Business intelli-, gence," full-fledged, may well be the next important step. It has seemed worthwhile to mention this point because we want to go along with Mr. Smith who believes that military" MORI/HRP THIS PAGE SECRET 21 intelligence doctrine has application in national policy proc- esses. In fact, we want to go further and assert that the basic concepts - not necessarily all the detailed precepts and pro- cedures - have application to any form of human activity: political, economic, scientific, or sociological. There is some reason to suspect that both Mr. Smith and Colonel Kirtland have misinterpreted or misunderstood some of these basic concepts. We propose to deal with these mis- understandings as they come up in our discussion of the two papers. At this point, it is useful to cover one matter which both seem to have failed to keep clearly in mind. It is the fact that both the intelligence officer and the commander (or policy-maker) are in the estimating business. The Intelligence Function and the Command Function The intelligence officer is the "expert" on the enemy. Ac- cordingly, he is charged with giving the commander, the staff, and subordinate commands the best information and esti- mates on the enemy situation. The end product of his estimate is enemy capabilities and - let us not forget - where available information provides a basis for such judgment, the relative probability of adoption of them.* This is a full-time job, particularly when one considers that the intelligence officer must also continuously provide his command - and, in addition, assist in providing subordinate, adjacent, and senior commands - with the information and intelligence they require for their day-to-day operations as distinguished from that needed for estimates. It is for this reason, rather than any slavish devotion to doctrine that, as Mr. Smith points out,** some persons hold that the intelli- ? FM30-5 and Principles of Strategic Intelligence, AC of S, 0-2 (Feb. 50). ?? As Smith puts it: "We are told that it is the function of the com- mander, not of the intelligence officer, to decide what counteraction to adopt against enemy capabilities and to judge what the success of such counteraction may be." MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 gence officer should not deal in the capabilities and lines of action of his own side. Mr. Smith is correct in saying that some persons oppose this from wrong motives, but that is not a fault peculiar to the military. It should also be pointed out that many planners have a supercilious view of intelligence and intelligence officers. They fancy themselves equally competent in intelligence matters. Indeed, most of them are, but the reverse is also true. Most intelligence officers are fully com- petent planners. Since each has a full-time job, however, each needs to tend to his own knitting to get the job done well. There needs to be, and in good commands there is, continuous close liaison at all levels in the intelligence and plans sections. Historically it is true that many commanders have leaned as much or more on their intelligence officers in planning matters as they have on their planners. In even more cases, after the whole staff was thoroughly informed about the enemy, the role of the intelligence officer appeared to be less prominent. It is noteworthy that this usually occurs on the side that is winning or has a preponderance of force. When things are tight, the intelligence officer is in great demand and, we might note, his neck is way out. We noted above that the commander also makes an estimate. His estimate takes the enemy capabilities - presumably as developed by the intelligence officer - and, in the light of each capability, studies each line of action open to the com- mand to determine the one that best accomplishes the mission. He determines the lines of action open to him by having full information about his own forces - their position, condition, morale, supplies, supporting forces available and so on. Just as the intelligence officer contributes the information about the enemy, so many other staff officers contribute this other' information which the commander must have to make a sound decision. Let us then keep clearly in mind that, in military usage, they intelligence estimate sets forth the enemy capabilities. The; commander, for his part, uses that estimate in conjunction MORI/HRP THIS PAGE SECRET 23 with other information (there may be a logistics estimate, an air estimate, etc.) and makes a final "policy" estimate to deter- mine the line of action which will best accomplish his mission. The Military Theory of Capabilities Many of the difficulties which Mr. Smith points out in the application of military usage in the field of national policy stem from the fact that in the national field we do not have the same common understanding of staff and command func- tions that obtains in the military. This is true both because the "staff" in national policy affairs, though to a degree com- parable, is not a close parallel to a military staff, and because many of our policy-makers are not experienced in or familiar with staff functioning. Against this general background, we can now examine.-Mr.. Smith's advocacy of the concept of "gross" and .`.'net'.' capa- bilities and his contention that war-gaming should be used to improve the usefulness of our intelligence. In reference to the first matter Mr. Smith points out the need to recognize that enemy capabilities are one thing when we study them in the light of one of our own actions and quite different when we consider them in the light of another. To indicate these differences he uses the expressions "gross capabilities" and "net capabilities." Use of these terms brings to mind the idea of a fixed measurable quantity like the gross income of General Motors and, similarly, that a "net capa- bility" is like GM's net income. It is quite clear that such a concept is not accurate. Pursued to the logical end, gross capabilities would be capa- bilities, as it were, in a vacuum. Such capabilities have no practical meaning, both because they are limitless (without ?;)liosition the Soviets can do almost anything) and because there are no true vacuums in world affairs. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 In a sense capabilities are always "net." But they are fixed only in reference to one given set of conditions. As these con- ditions change, the capabilities change. They are a moving picture, not a still photograph. The Soviet "net capability" to induce a peripheral war in Thailand is one thing if Thailand has the political and other support of Burma and the SEATO states and quite a different thing if it does not have such sup- port. Indeed, the timing and extent of such support changes the "net capability." In military usage capabilities are always what Mr. Smith calls "net." The intelligence officer deter- mines the enemy's capabilities as of a given time and in the light of given circumstances.* This idea is readily applicable in national strategic intelligence. What Mr. Smith calls gross capabilities could perhaps better be thought of as "basic" capabilities. For example, intelli- gence officers can readily estimate that by 1959 the Soviets could have a stockpile of X hydrogen bombs, Y rounds of atomic artillery ammunition, Z intercontinental bombers, W army divisions, and V major naval craft, and could still meet the industrial requirements of their civilian economy, provided they give no more than the current level of military aid to Red China and the Satellites. On the other hand, if they curtailed production of equipment for the Red Army and Navy they could contribute more to the armament of China and the Satellites. These are capabilities. They are basic capabilities to produce or take general action not normally subject to interference. Further analysis and research can develop what, under various assumptions, the Soviets can do with these resources and thus can determine their capabilities to act. Perhaps it is this distinction that Mr. Smith has in- mind when he speaks of "gross" and "net." Even if this is, the case we would still be loath to accept the concept because,' in the general sense of the term, even such "gross" capabilities 'See quotations from Dictionary of US Military Terms for Joint Usage, cited by Mr. Smith; also the description used at the Strategic MORI/HRP THIS PAGE are "net." Rather than adopting misleading terms like "gross" and "net" we seem to be better off if we stick just to "capa- bilities" and understand it to apply, as in basic military doctrine, to a stated set of circumstances. The second point in Mr. Smith's thesis that we wish to examine is the matter of war-gaming. He laments the fact that accepted practice frowns on having intelligence officers war-game the plans of their own side. We do not concede that this "frowning" is as prohibitively effective as Mr. Smith contends. To the extent that it does exist, it is directed against the idea of having the intelligence officer play both sides. This is logical. The intelligence officer cannot be -expert" on his own, resources and plans as well as on those of the enemy. As pointed out earlier, the latter is a full-time job. To the extent that he thumps for joint war-gaming by intelligence and plans personnel as a device to assist in im- proving the usefulness of intelligence estimates, however, Mr. Smith is emphatically right. War-gaming for this particular purpose is not used as widely in the military as it might be. But the concept of war-gaming for other purposes with all staff elements participating is well established. It could easily be used in the more complex field of national estimates. War-gaming has been modified radically in recent years with the employment of advanced mathematics and electronic com- puters. These techniques leave much to be desired in the military field and many of them could, at the current stage of development, be used to only a very limited extent in reference to the "imponderables" of national policy affairs. The more conventional type of war-gaming, on the other hand, could certainly be used across the board and with every possibility of making our intelligence estimates more useful. Mr. Smith's observation that national policy-makers have a more complex problem than military leaders is valid, and it has an important bearing on the activities of the intelligence MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 services which support them. The national policy-maker must consider a great variety of "capabilities" which interact on each other. For example, a sociological change in Germany may have an important repercussion in the political capabilities of France. Furthermore, it is always difficult to determine the "facts" in many areas of interest. The military leader usually knows how many and what kinds of guided missile squadrons, atomic bombs, fleets, and army troops he and his opponent have. The political leader is always far less certain about his "forces" and those of his allies. There is even more uncer- tainty about the resources the enemy can bring to bear. To illustrate, we can be sure that Khrushchev's advisers have many a headache estimating how effective the Satellites and Communist China really are and what assets the West actually apply in various situations. In such a field, therefore there can be no one "net" capability. There are as many "net' capabilities as there are variant situations. Mr. Smith appears to think that intelligence officers should compute these "net' capabilities by their own efforts. It would seem more logical that they should be worked out in conjunction -and we do not mean concurrence - with the planners. Intelligence offi- cers and planners must sit down together and thrash out a the angles. This is precisely what happens in an efficien military staff in time of war. The formal estimates of capa bilities appear only when a radical change in one's own or the enemy situation takes place. For example, after "The' Bulge," 21st Army Group conducted an extended and more or less "conventional" campaign to gain the Rhine. It was obvious that crossing that formidable obstacle would call for different types of action and support. An estimate of the situation was essential.' This, in turn, meant that intelli gence forecasts and estimates had to be produced. At such, times a new "stock-taking" is in order. At other times, day to-day close coordination by the working intelligence officers planning. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE and planners, with a check on interpretations of major impor- tance by the senior intelligence and plans officers, is the best modus operandi. It keeps all concerned aware of enemy capa- bilities applicable to the prevailing conditions. In the national field, a similar condition could obtain. Un- happily the lines of demarcation in staff organization are not as simple and clear as in the military. Instead of overall planners like those in the Joint Staff or in an international staff such as the Combined Staff Planners of World War II, we have political planners in State, military in Defense, eco- nomic in agencies like OES, propaganda in USIA, etc. Each of these has some form of intelligence support of its own. These intelligence agencies are tied together by CIA for national purposes and planning is brought together in the NSC. How- ever, there is still a vast amount of "sprawling." Parentheti- cally, it should be noted that this statement is a description of a condition; it is not to be construed as an unfavorable criticism. This is not the occasion for such criticism; and it is by no means certain that highly centralized planning and intelligence would be best, or even better, for the country. Here, we want simply to note that close integration of intelli- gence into planning is difficult because of the decentralized planning and operating mechanism in the US government. A great deal of informal coordination on the working level clues take place. This is all to the good and should be encouraged. This complexity of organization and operations in the national field results in a greater need for formalized 1sstimates and is, in itself, a justification for the use of the war-gaming principle. However, with all due respect for the .,kill, wisdom, and judgment of our intelligence community, we should not leave war-gaming as a basis for decisions to then alone. The danger here is at least as great as it is to have the planners do it alone. We have suffered on both the military and the national plane from an unwillingness (or inability) to accept and understand available intelligence. We III ecl not repeat such gross errors. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 With little or no information of our own plans and resources, the intelligence officer can still tell the, planner what resources the enemy can have at a future date and the general kinds of action he can initiate with them. If the commander an planner want to know what results the enemy can achiev with these resources and actions, the intelligence officer must have knowledge of his own resources and plans. Applying this notion to the current situation, we can expect national intelligence officers to tell us what resources th Soviets will have for peripheral wars by 1959 without much guidance as to our own resources and national plans an policies. But they can tell us where and with what likeliho of success the Soviets can use those assets only if they kno the opposition which the Soviet action is likely to meet. Join war-gaming would provide such interchange of informatio It should make for a healthy interplay between intelligent' and planning and probably result in improving both. Estimating Enemy Intentions In Colonel Kirtland's paper we have a more restricted an therefore more specific subject for consideration. He objet to what he describes as "unrealistic resistance" to the use intentions-analysis as opposed to capabilities-analysis in Intel ligence estimates. He holds that we need to consider bot By inference, he is most directly concerned with combat in ligence. He makes clear, however, that his conclusions appl; to strategic intelligence as well. After analyzing what Colonel Kirtland has to say, we agree with his main thesis that both intentions and capabiliti need to be considered. However, he has not hedged his p posal with essential safeguards and his arguments ag the "capabilities doctrine" contain very serious weakness We will review these arguments and then develop our o conclusions. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE In order to evaluate Colonel Kirtland's contentions, it is important that we have a common understanding of the meaning of "the capabilities doctrine." The burden of this concept is that in a combat intelligence estimate, the intelli- gence officer should present to the commander his best estimate of the enemy's capabilities rather than the enemy's intentions. The doctrine goes further: it holds that the commander in his estimate should consider each of the lines of action open to him in the light of each of the enemy capabilities in arriving at his final decision on a course of action. It is important to keep in mind that the doctrine has these two aspects: first, the intelligence officer is to determine capabilities; and second, the commander should make his decision only after considering all the capabilities. An elaboration of this doctrine which is too often forgotten is that the G-2 is expected to give the commander his con- clusion as to the relative probability of the exercise of any of the enemy capabilities, where there is evidence to support such a conclusion.* Earlier doctrine had held that the task of the intelligence officer was to estimate the mission of the enemy and, from that, deduce the lines of action the enemy might take and then to determine their effect on the courses open to his own side. This doctrine invited a refined form of guessing as to the enemy mission and encouraged consideration of intentions in the deduction of enemy lines of action. The new capabilities doctrine was developed after World War I because it was felt that earlier doctrine introduced too much clairvoyance into military problem-solving (which is what decision-making really is), and that it came too near urging officers to guess the worst the enemy could do and to ,;take everything on that. It was believed that the "capa- lnlities" system was more "scientific" and more nearly in accord with the facts of life. This conviction was illustrated MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 at the Command and General Staff School just b f e ore Worli , War II, when one of the instructors "clinched" the argumen in favor of b asing estimatb es on capailities by showing tha in World Wa I r von Kluck hadhd cange his mind four tim in one day and actually issued three different orders. A concomitant of the acceptance of the capabilities doctrin one wh an d y o a voc e, basing estimates on enemy intentions just hasn't been brough nA,,..__- ~. un nrnnarlcr T o come to be considered the equal of advocating mind-readiin or th e use of a ouija board. Advocates of intentions-analys like Colonel Ki tl r and object m t thi oreos anti-intentions prej dice than to th e capabilities doti crne per se. In marshaling support for the thesis that our doctri ne ne review and, in particular, needs to give more consid ti era on intentions, the critics tend to make some amazing misinterpr tations and t o neglect some cil ft rucaacs. We agree that o doct i r ne needs recasti bt ngu we must, in fairness, keep record acc t ura e and logical . Colonel Kirtland's objection to current doctrine i s ,, on three main points: first, "a nation or a comma d n er m w have a preponderance of force if he bases his decisions o: conservative"; and third, the enemy's potential capabilities ai t no adequately considered.* We will examine each of th points in some detail. The statement that the capabilities doctrine is useable onl when you have a preponderance of force is clearly erroneo It is a very practibl dt caeocrine when you are on the defens and even when you are the hunted in a pursuit. To ho. th o erwise is like saying you cannot use the principles of are ? The third point is paraphrased because the actual statement is n very precise. However, subsequent explanation makes clear that means what h--.. . - - MORI/HRP THIS PAGE metic when you are in debt. The capabilities doctrine - and, for that matter, any other doctrine - gives you a discouraging picture in such cases, but that is the picture you must face. In an adverse situation, the doctrine is designed to indicate which line of action would have the least adverse result. In other words, it indicates the course of action which would get your nose least bloody. The second criticism, that application of the doctrine gen- crally results in conservative action, is to a large extent true; but it is true because, in matters of life and death, leaders generally tend to be conservative. Usually they should be. The criticism is justified only to the extent that the going doctrine makes it easier for leaders to be conservative. This is particularly true when officers take the view which an allegedly bright and "successful" officer (he later got a star) expressed when he said: "I teach my officers to select the line of action which gives them the best chance against what tliey figure is the enemy's most dangerous capability." It is this use of the capabilities doctrine that brings on the ,-ritirism of conservatism. Actually it is a reversion to the elder doctrine. It is, in fact, a form of intentions-analysis because the user assumes that the enemy will exercise a given capability. Such use does not condemn the doctrine itself, any more than the fact that some men get drunk justifies the rondemnation of all whiskey. Current doctrine holds that the commander shall select the course of action which, in the .`are of all the estimated enemy capabilities, insures the most c !7ecf ire accomplishment of the mission. This is not the same thing as saying that he should select the one that gives the greatest certain.ty~ of accomplishing the mission. Cleariy the . most certain course might be the most bloody while a slightly more risky line of action would be less costly and might accom- plish the mission in a shorter time or have some other advan- tage. The selection of a line of action requires a balancing of costs and gains under the various possibilities. It also calls MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 . Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 for what is known as "military character." No matter wheth _. we use capabilities or intentions, the decisions will reflect tha The third argument is that use of the doctrine prevents con sideration of potential capabilities, meaning those that develo between the time the estimate is made and the action tak place. This, of course, is woven of the very flimsiest clot The doctrine is based on the use of capabilities which tk enemy will have at the time of the action for which one planning - not the capabilities at the time the decision made. It is the capabilities forecast for the action-time . one accepts the argument, he must also accept the conch, sio , that if intentions were used in the analysis, one could no use forecasts of intentions. On this score, then, one woul be as badly off under one system as under the other. One other serious error in Colonel Kirtland's paper that must bring out is the failure to show that Army doctrine h for years made clear that in strategic intelligence-as tinguished from combat intelligence - both intentions an capabilities are considered. Official doctrine and teaching a the Strategic Intelligence School and at Army schools ha emphasized this point at least since World War II. The Role of Intentions in Intelligence Estimates So far we have been concerned with showing that the ments presented against the capabilities doctrine are not v good or conclusive. This is not the same as saying that, are trying to build a case against intentions-analysis. Ac, ally, we do not intend to do so. We will weasel but, we belil with good reason. We agree that use should be made of bo capabilities and intentions in developing estimates, but we Ii that one must be equally objective and "scientific" in de mining either of them. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Having noted that the common arguments against the capa- bilities concept are not too decisive let us note a few of the weaknesses of that system and indicate some of the strengths of the intentions approach. The faults of the capability system are two-fold. First it tends, as Colonel Kirtland points out, to cause intelligence officers to include remote possibilities as capabilities. They forget that the doctrine calls for the consideration of only those capabilities which bear on the accomplishment of one's own mission. Second, and despite strong language to the contrary in Army training, the doctrine seems to justify lazy intelligence officers to feel that they have done their bit when thev have made one- forecast of capabilities. This is most unfortunate. Intelligence officers must keep capabilities under continuing study to narrow them down. For example, in September of 1943 the predicted capabilities of the Germans vis-a-vis the Normandy landings were of a given order. As time went on, the Allies developed certain techniques and equipment and new forces became available. On the Axis side, Italy was knocked out of the war, and the Germans committed some of their forces in new areas. Consequently, the enemy capabilities changed continuously so that by June 1944 they were far more limited than could possibly have been predicted in September 1943. SHAEF intelligence kept a con- tinuous spotlight on these capabilities during this period. So it should be in all operations. The good intelligence officer keeps on the ball as long as there is time to influence his own side's line of action. In many cases the situation develops so that at a point the enemy has only one capability. This hap- lxened at Falaise and in the Ruhr. Eventually, the Germans could no longer disengage their forces. They had to stay and fl~,lht. This idea was also illustrated in General Eisenhower's statement to the effect that after a given time he could no banger influence the course of the Juggernaut that became the Normandy assault. For a considerable period he had only one capability. Just how long the German G-2 was useful MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 by keeping tabs on that has not been made clear. Our teat ing does not emphasize this concept as clearly and firmly as should. As we have already noted, World War I provided a startlingi effective case to bolster the capabilities doctrine. Similarl the Civil War and World War II give us particularly fine cas for defense of intentions-analysis. In the Civil War, oppos commanders often knew each other personally. They used knowledge in their planning. They knew the training, abi _ ties, and personalities of their opponents and, hence, coul determine the line of action the enemy was most likely to tak In a sense, of course, this too is an assessment of capabiliti but there is no point in splitting any unnecessary hairs. ordinary language, such an evaluation results in a predictio of intentions. There is a grey zone where capabilities slid into intentions, but for our purposes, we will lean to the co servative side and call the borderline cases intentions. The World War II support for intentions-analysis is in so ways even stronger. It stems from the fact that the Japan M tendency`to fight to the death was so effectively ingrained that. to a very marked degree, capabilities to take other lines action were not meaningful. To a lesser extent this s situation applied in the European war where Hitlerism mold capabilities. One can make a very good case for the contention t enemy intentions should properly be considered under tl capabilities doctrine because they are a factor in the comb efficiency of the enemy. To accept such an interpretati without clearly labeling it, however, would simply be a wa of getting around the intent of the doctrine and have tli disadvantage of not calling intentions by their true name. Experience in all walks of life shows clearly that a failur to make a thorough study of one's opponent to determin his motivations and his mental and psychological reactio as a basis for estimating his future action is worse th MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 unwise. The press is full of stories that the USSR is very active in this field and has attained great successes, perhaps as a concomitant of progress in brain-washing and psycho- logical matters generally. In our zeal to make sure that training will make commanders and intelligence officers "ob- jective" and "scientific," we may have gone so far that we have tended to overlook the obvious. Certainly, the mental makeup and attitude of the enemy is as much a "fact" as is his training, his morale, his organization, or his weapons. Surely then it is logical to consider intentions. Equally surely, it is important to do so objectively and to know what you are doing. If you are an intelligence officer, it is most important that you alert your chief to the fact that you are considering intentions. In the discussion so far we have used examples and applica- tions in the purely military field. The conclusions are valid in national intelligence as well. In fact, intentions of a nation or a government can be determined with more accuracy than those of an individual commander. These intentions are shaped by many clearly observable facts such as past actions, sociological conditions, cultural characteristics, internal politi- cal pressures, economic circumstances, and a host of others. The British exploited their understanding of German inten- tions in both World Wars and it was not uncommon to hear their intelligence officers use such expressions as: "the Hun Is sure to - - - -," and "the German probably appreciates." They personified the enemy government and high command. On the other hand, the Germans seem consistently to have missed the boat. They clearly either did not or could not evaluate US and Russian national intentions properly in either of the World Wars. The evaluation of national intentions in- volves a more comprehensive field of thought than does the evaluation of the intentions of an enemy commander. How- ever, the task is no more difficult. Even if it is, it must be done because the rewards for success and the costs of failure are too great to permit neglecting the job. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Where does all this get us? It seems is i di n , cate that Colonel Kirtland says, a proper doctrine would be to inclu both ca bilit pa ies and intti i enonsn all estimates as we now in th t e s rategic estit H mae.owever, we should expand princi le p will impress on all .concerned that they need't i o apply the m e rigid tests to all evidence bearing on intentions and that co cIusions bas d e upon themllh ceary sow that this is the Since all concepts and doctrines wind up in a "form" of so enrf - -1-4. _ ,. as In the military field the solution is eas . All l y we need to do i the commander's estimate * is to insert a paragraph on "enem tntPntinne- mi- statement, either to the effect that there a n re o reliai indications of enemy intentions or that certain stated e dente i di t n ca es an intti t enono exercise one or more of th ca abiliti p es . In the intelligence estimate, we need merely insert ti>a "cnmhat G{~ ninr ..11 characteristics which shape or have a major infl on uenc ru actions. In addition, we should add a paragraph on enem estimate. This one should also present the ucriticallle der upon which th e estimatef itti onenons is founded. Such a detailed analysis of combat intelli ence d t g oc rine warranted at this juncture because, as Mr. Smith points o so much of the concept and procedure of . . int process. The additions to military command and intellllge estimates which we have Vt~ r p oposed here could b e paralleled our training for nati onal strategic itlli negence. Our current doctrine probably goes too far in playing d intentions-analysis. Going all out the +,,e_ .. o MORI/HRP THIS PAGE iuly be worse. It would encourage clairvoyance and, in ddition, might discourage the continuous effort to seek for ew indications of capabilities. The stress on measurable hysical facts is justified. While we are making important strides in understanding and measuring motivation and mental processes, we are not yet far enough along in that field to measure intentions as precisely as we can capabilities and, as Colonel Kirtland notes, the danger of deception is a very real one. Even so, since decision-making is so inevitably bound ^p with consideration of the personal element, it is the better part of discretion, and of valor as well, to consider intentions. They are so often the sparkplugs of human action. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 SECRET 39 EnrroRs NOTE: Whenever books or articles ap- pear that have a close relation to the subject of a monograph, we plan to include a Bibliographic Section. This will have the primary purpose of directing the reader's attention to items in the existing literature, overt and classified, which in our judgment make a contribution to the devel- opment of sound intelligence doctrine. We think the following is one such item. (bt. Sanford H. Kirtland, Jr., "The Hazards and Advantages of Estimates of Enemy Intentions." Thesis, Air War College, Air University, Maxwell AFB, April 1954. Mss. CONTF. 50pp. also summary in Air Intelligence Digest, January 1955. In this paper, Col. Kirtland comes frankly and vigorously to imps with the caveat in traditional military intelligence doe- -ine against estimating enemy intentions-or, to put it a:11 ither way, against breaking down the distinction between :'.emy capabilities and enemy intentions. Col. Kirtland is 'xr from contemptuous of this doctrine; indeed, he makes an client case for it, emphasizing the dangers of second- -ssing and of assuming that the enemy will choose to do rrtty much what a US commander would do, in a similar '.'?a lion. He emphasizes, too, the danger of writing up an mate of the Situation from even the shrewdest guess of my intentions, thus inviting disaster if the guess turns out ,c shrewd but wrong. In brief, this thesis is no hatchet job. MORI/CDF THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 40 SECRET What it is, on the other hand, is a most sensible investiga tion of the traditional doctrine and an invitation not to f into a variety of naive traps where the estimative process concerned. First of all, the author points out that the distin tion between capabilities and intentions is sometimes synthetic The line can be more easily drawn in the abstract than it can in real situations - especially, we might point out, in situ ations that count the most, when a US commander has to spread out thin resources to meet a variety of possible enemy, moves. Any intelligence officer (as Mr. Smith argues above?1 obviously works from estimates of intentions in that he ex? eludes from his situation-estimate a whole series of outlandish and, from the enemy point of view, self-defeating gross capa bilities. If the clear enemy objective is to seize a piece of land] it is not very instructive to point out that he is capable of ail immediate, orderly retreat. A Second, according to Col. Kirtland, the intelligence officer is forced into estimating intentions (or probable courses o[ action) precisely because the US is no longer in a position of undoubted preponderant power from which it can prepaie for and can thwart any and all enemy capabilities. Which is to suggest that the traditional doctrine is outdated. As Mr. Smith says: There has been much debate, among the military, on whether an intelligence officer should presume to put into his formal estimate an opinion as to which of the enemy capabilities listed is most likely to be implemented ... Some have even held that the com- mander himself must not make it, but must treat all enemy capabilities as if they were sure to be carried through, and must prepare to deal with them all This latter doctrine is somewhat academic. (Emphasis added.) Col. Kirtland and Mr. Smith both seem to be saying that these days the intelligence officer may pay lip service to the traditional military doctrine - may insist that he is follOW6 MORI/CDF THIS PAGE SECRET 41 ing the book on the distinction between capabilities and intentions - but cannot possibly keep the distinction clear in practice. Finally, the author concludes that there is no inherent drawback in estimating intentions: to do so with reliability simply puts the burden on finer judgment, on better back- ground and training, and on better personnel selection of estimators. He might also have added that since estimating intentions is what the intelligence officer in fact does, some of the time at least, it would be well that he do it consciously. The real danger is that the estimator might think he is dealing with relatively sure and scientific capabilities data (claiming :dative certainty for his conclusions, therefore) rather than with speculative premises about enemy intentions. Col. Kirtland is writing, of course, strictly about military :ntclligence. But most of what he says can be translated into frame of reference of the civilian intelligence agency - as 1t r. Smith's paper demonstrates -with some valuable instruc- t:on for all of us. This is, at the least, a thoughtful contribu- -en to the subject. MORI/CDF THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 MORI/CDF THIS PAGE MORI/CDF THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 pto a pressed in the Sfud~e ' offiga e utha T eyooepresent .tin intelligence Agency o of thee~ ce o i ` ... erecting" the atrial contiatns information efense f the United States within$'the$meanin~ ;pianage laws, Title 18 ;USC; Secs 793 and 794; tlie; fission orevelation of which to an nnauthoed Pe rabbi} by law: *4 S..,JS ' a 'yp Y t ~f + X 1 d '~ '~" 3+ ~< Subs ", a issues will be disssemmated1wlde y' o%g, gegcy To make,~sure~cfrecen~ng }~~a 44ra~copes! pfieasettwll~tf extensionk EDITORS INTRODUCTION BACK in 1951 when the Office of Research and Reports was just being set up, the then Assistant Director, Max F. Mil- likan, wrote a long paper for his staff on the functions and methods of economic intelligence. In it, he spelled out the reasons for ORR's existence, its major and minor tasks, and the methods by which these tasks might best be performed. The paper was, in effect, marching orders for a new organiza- tion as it embarked on its job. We have here printed the greater part of Dr. Millikan's paper, without any substantial changes and without any attempt to bring it "up-to-date." Why? First of all, not because Dr. Mtil,ikan was the first AD/RR; and second, not because the pa )er was an official document defining ORR's operating prin- ?ples. Indeed, recalling that Studies in Intelligence will pub- :..sh only unofficial, individual contributions to basic intelligence ,ioctrine, we are printing Dr. Millikan's paper in some sense respite these facts about its author and its original purpose. our reason for publishing the paper is this: it is, we feel, a d:stinguished contribution to the study of intelligence analysis methodology. And its application is by no means limited to economic intelligence; the same order of analytic problems, the ume problems of sources, extent of information, competing :!-quirements, liaison and coordination arise in any intelli- o nce activity. The same problem Dr. Millikan addresses, t:at of building authoritative knowledge out of fragmentary -.uces, is perhaps the central problem of the intelligence ;:( ess as a whole. ?here is no need to rehearse in detail Dr. Millikan's quali- ,tions for tackling such problems. He was for several years -' nior official of this Agency and is now Director of the Center . International Studies at M.I.T., an organization that has ',nda.cted important research on Soviet and World Communist 41"w -s since its inception in 1951. MORI/CDF THIS MORI/HRP THIS PAGE PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 ii SECRET Howerton's paper complements Dr. Millikan's, on Mr . levels. On the level of economic intelligence research, it give l yz a current view of the methods devised since 1951 for ana in successive approximations to the complete picture, thus, in effect, a case-study of t economy; it is i S , ov e d of successive approximations described in broad tei th o me by Dr. Millikan. On a more general level, Mr. Howerto of racani rovides a s _- . -., paper p ues available to the intelligence analyst and of i h n q tec potentialities of overt (or, at least, easily obtainable) inf, t to An with 't h a mation - if only the analyst knows w resources available to him. Mr. Howerton joined this Agency in 1951 afteTTa career nd re e a r- co po a a unique combined competence in chemistry, mathemat=i e of natio* and languages and is fellow of more than a scor Hower M r. and international professional associations. lli t g e is, at present, Assistant to the Deputy Director/In (Planning) . In this issue we also inaugurate a continuing featurl d Common D -r--- Notes an l 11 ber of letters on the first two issues - many, in themset tions t ib --------- r u Substantial con ciples and methods. Of these, we here publish two, both ana the to i e " C r v and respons the subject of "capabilities -1- Studie Into + ?.- issue of is Director of Intelligence, U. S. Air Force; Mr. Alan J. P- is JIC (London) Representative to this Agency. We are l to both for permitting us to publish their comments. f u we very much hope that, as subsequent issues appear, we estii1l u d s gg keep on receiving your coiiments, criticisms, an ou th what k y now publishable or not. We would like to the series. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE THE NATURE AND METHODS OF ECONOMIC INTELLIGENCE by I-lax F. Millikan D URING the first half of 1951, ORR was engaged in taking an inventory of its ignorance concerning the economy of the Soviet Bloc. The main purpose of this inventory u::s to establish a basis for planning a program of basic research to which ORR should address itself. Such a program mist spring from a clear conception of why the US Govern- nnwnt needs foreign economic intelligence, what foreign eco- nomic intelligence is, what role ORR should play in the total ,i-onomic intelligence effort, and how the peculiar character ,,, the Soviet economy and of our information about it influ- cnces the methods that we use. This introduction is devoted to some comments on these four topics. 4V hv does the solution of our national security problems depend in part upon adequate foreign economic intelligence? Foreign economic intelligence serves at least five purposes the design of policies to preserve our national security. T!,cse five purposes, which should be kept continuously in in planning our economic research program, are as ..Ows: To estimate the magnitude of possible present or future or other threats tovur52iveS and our allies. A pv~2n- a' enemy can undertake successfully only those military ,,; y : at ions which its economy is capable of sustaining. In the - ' Y short run, its strength may be measured in terms of the ::-%po%k-er which it can mobilize and the stocks of finished ";L;x,ns of war and military supplies which it has on hand. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 SECRET 3 SECRET however, military potential f Increasingly in modern times, has come to depend upo11 aigns m p inudin anything but the briefest ca ,,, ces available to a nation, es well civilian economy those necessary to support, the instruments sary to produce and operate the of w neces picture of the magnitude of the present and pons A clear p' guide us as to 1 t is needed to threa future military or other over-all magnitude of the defense effort in which we m ur freedoms in the event of a reserve o engage in order to p d location of possible pr acter an 2. To estimate the char or other threats. Decisions which the USS or future military make with regard to how tl or any other potential enemy will allocate their resources limit litanthey can choose to y installations in If they elect to invest lag y corr Far East, their potential for attack in Europeri their in# of j d This 16 no li mitdn ingly restricte. 'hatations are place o i n ns ng decisio tions but rather of see in the future by to them courses of action open lu onnrat,inn of their total resou they mare wu?y the character A principal purpose of thus estimating possibly r own defense effort so that ii g ou guide us in designin is tog dangers protect us against real rather than imaginary e of the in g, --- potential en{ 3. To assist us in es-Lima ble, the intentions of the USSR or and their presentd of bution permit him to select, any _ range certain xxn+-hin this f nr& probable coursesu indicat ions as to which alte i n0mic events may __.,_ an,~ where and when. its - ---- the Sov tions may be veryimp01 f inten rJ u +n mee, Ainat'ons o~ These ul~, w r re ara,l0 a us to adjust our defense pp assisting most probable -0- 4. To help policy-maker s decide what we can do to ? r other threats by imps o possible or probable military them out. This enemy's economic capabilities to carry SECRET MORI/HRP THIS PAGE measures that can be taken to weaken him in advance of hos- tilities and thus delay or prevent his decision to engage in them, as well as measures to weaken or destroy the economic basis of his military power should he choose to commit it in general war. Economic intelligence can help in suggesting such measures, in estimating their effectiveness, and in forecasting the enemy's probable reaction to them. 5. To assist in estimating the probable development of the relative strengths of the East and West over the next few rears if global hostilities are avoided. A major purpose of these comparisons is to guide US policy-makers. The preced- ing four objectives are concerned with steps which the United States can take to defend itself against actions of a hostile power. Equally important is the design of that political policy which will have the' best chance of achieving our objectives without hostilities. Essential to the planning of such a policy is the most accurate estimate possible of the relative economic strengths of both sides. There are equally grave dangers in a serious underestimate and in a serious overestimate of future Soviet economic strength. Either will produce policies more likely to bring on war than will an accurate estimate. The evaluation of Soviet strength implicit in various of the pro- posals for US policy now being advanced in this country varies widely from great economic weaknesses to very considerable economic power. A prime goal of authoritative economic intel- ligence is to provide the information that will narrow the "guess area." % 'hat is economic intelligence? Briefly, economic intelligence is intelligence relating to the basic productive resources of an area or political unit, the goals and objectives which those in control of the resources wish then; +w serve, and the ways rn wu &Li and the effi l trueness with which these resources are in fact allocated in the service of these various goals. There are a number of confusions as to the nature and limits of economic intelligence which call for cluiflcation. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 there is sometimes a tendency to reg In the first place , the whole of economic intelligence as encompassed in a mi begin to be employed broadly in production, they bee and development phases. When these techniques and o , , draw. In very rough terms, scientific in a ig precise lines between the segment's are r...pos "op follon t 11' ,J s..- -- ---- - - of dividing it are somewhat arbitrary analytic invert 4 m C Ano er p 91 leaves off and political, military, and scientific mtel th roblem relates to where economic intellil as with the physical inventory of the resources serve, and the ways in which they are related to ea h;, coal to operate the railroads. Thus economic m e g y a e by the steel required for the machinery necessary to mine t11 ence+ steel from steel plants to tank plants, or, more rem, er available to make the rails and the freight cars nee from which to manufacture the tanks but also by then plex interrelations in balance. Thus tank production, , - ,_-- 41.... .,,.-;1shill+4 nf p capacities of the economy may be limited less by the ove 4.. 1...nn o11 1-ha r corn lex web of interconnections among its various parts. Furthermore, a modern economy is characterized by a hig as of low or negligible priority. steel must be allocated to many uses which the Soviets re g so its minimum goals, even in a time of crisis like the preset' hly misleading. For the United States to achi is hi about capabilities, vulnerabilities, or intentions. The Allli Powers have a total steel capacity which is more than. fo which they are designed to serve or of the methods employ 4,.11 ....U m but only a part of the total economic problem. An invents struments of production. This inventory is a necessary p inventory of available resources of labor, raw materials; MORI/HRP THIS PAGE SECRET 5 province of economic intelligence. Military intelligence is con- cerned with the character and capacities of the military estab- lishments of foreign countries and with foreign targets for our own military efforts. Where the character of the military establishment depends upon rates of production or where the target of our military effort is the economy of the poten- tial enemy, the lines between military and economic become blurred. The output of final military equipment and the physical targets on which our military forces must concen- trate are clearly a prime concern of military intelligence. On the other hand, economic analysis is required to portray the complex nexus of economic support on which military produc- tion depends and to pursue the economic chain reactions which might result from the destruction of particular producing facilities. The overlapping between political and economic intelligence is even greater. One of the best ways of studying the goals which a collectivized state wishes its economy to serve is to examine the institutional machinery that it establishes to guide economic processes. Thus certain of the institutions of government, although in a sense political phenomena, may have profound economic significance. On the other hand, eco- nomic conditions are of course an important determinant of the attitudes, loyalties, and composition of politically impor- tant groups. In these borderline areas, it is the purpose and object of investigation rather than the disciplines employed that determine whether intelligence is properly to be termed economic or political. A final point of importance which the analyst must keep in. mind is that economic intelligence is not always the same thing as economic information. Even the most basic economic intelligence should always be produced in relation to the t>otds of some intelligence consumer. The Central Intelligence Agency is charged with producing foreign economic intelligence Mating to the national security, and the consumers of its product are those US Government officials charged with guard- ft the national security. A vast amount of information - $ d ed, almost all information - about foreign economies may MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 6 SECRET nt to national security problems, but it is not econo l eva be re intelligence until its relevance to those problems is made el ed e know g l It is the function of intelligence not to pursue o its UWll bane Nut .,-?__-_ quences of present or future action. Though the intelligeA __.- + +~?+lr etrivp to kA o a no 1. t analyst is --"J in mind the relevance of information to policy problems, wh{~ alone can transform information into intelligence. What is the role of ORR in foreign economic intelligence? Many US Government agencies are engaged in the prodii The enc lli t e. g e tion and collection of foreign economic in line, We mow.... f the foregoing statement of the purposes and na i s o bas ence alone. We must also consider how, intelli i c g g of econom activities can be made to reinforce rather than to duplicate they i n great amount of work which others must carry on __ ent survey of for rec Luial6c; J. -- economic intelligence throughout the US Government sug ti' focus of our ac a number of conclusions as to what the 11 should be. First, our survey revealed that one of the most urgent Go - - th e of e.....?---- -- economic intelligence collected and produced throughou In recognition of this need the National, s i ssue security . rity Council has directed that the Central Intelligence Ag Although this i on. shall perform this coordinating funct is directed at our production program, our plans for i nt of gence production within ORB must take full accou with ours n l g o coordinating responsibilities which go a tive effort. A second conclusion of our survey has been that th lli P' t g e conomic in most in need of substantial additional e o ' I n r because the fort is the Soviet Bloc. This is partly o iet has made awcoo -- partly because the Soviet economic potential is perha', MORI/HRP THIS PAGE most critical key to our national security, and partly because, for a variety of reasons, the economic potential of other areas crucial for our national security, such as Western Europe, has been much more extensively studied. The mature economies of Western Europe have long been an object of study by both academic and governmental economists. The European Re- covery Program has stimulated intensive analysis of the char- acteristics, needs, and prospects of the Marshall Plan coun- tries. Thus, the economic research effort in man-hours directed at the USSR and its Satellites has been vastly less than that applied to Western Europe, although, because of the Iron Curtain, the effort required to produce comparable under- standing is many times greater. For these reasons, we have concluded that the principal effort of ORR in intelligence production must be focused for the immediate future on the economic problems of the Soviet Bloc.* We began this research effort with an inventory of our knowledge of the USSR itself. This, of course, is only a part of the problem. The economies of the European Satellites, whose analysis was our second task, are likewise crucial to the Soviet economic potential. Recent events have highlighted the importance of China to our estimates .of Soviet strength and intentions. A final source of Soviet strength, which must be another object of our efforts, is the resources that the USSR could draw upon either now or as a consequence of future developments outside the present boundaries of the Bloc. A final weakness of the intelligence effort as revealed by our Inventory is that the demands which have been placed on the limited number of analysts working on the Soviet economy have been so frequent and insistent that analysts have had little or no time to do the basic research necessary to supply an.. veers in a confident and authoritative form. If our effort l1 to be useful at all, it must be on a sufficient scale and of ` The Soviet Bloc excludes Yugoslavia and Finland and includes the %uropean Satellites (East Germany, East Austria, Poland, Czecho- ciovakia, Rumania, Hungary, Bulgaria, and Albania) and the t: astern Satellites (Communist China and Communist Korea). MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 SECRET much firmer factual foundati sufficient depth to provide a for the estimating process than economic intelligence has b able to produce in the past. Peculiarities of economic intelligence concerning the Soviet Bloc There are a number of special characteristics Of the wa~sl e in imp ha p economic intelligence problem which s are n) h it d t o bese y u the methods that can be used to s . o diffic more k o he p e ever, all characteristics which ma r first some 011, r a than that of other areas. We m y our probthings about the Soviet economy which simplify factors which make it dif le _f s he w. t economy is centrally planned i e The fact that the Sov achieve the goals of a small group of men acting collecti>r __,-. s? +Hc free, economy Of facilitates analysis euuLwvu~.,. - United States the tastes and desiresfl~ P 160 on million e s ha unpredictable people al occurs. The behavior of major sectors f countless consum, 1 _Q greatly affected by the individual p uantita' hat unpr each with a different and somew plans which doming set of weight. In the USSR there is one -advertence that anything b ' y all others. Thus it is only iew of the master pla f v occur which, from the point o irrelevant or unimportant. This makes the second jog the elu b e namely economic intelligence described a , - tion of the goals and objectives reat deal easier. resources wish them to serve - a some clue. anything that happens can give us A related point, true to some extent offrvevery econom~~ thing d P nd' h e - especially true of t eise. The ir~tercenner_.tedness of the econom everything its subservience to the master plan mean that there are ~r%,inmic fact can be ascert different ways in which e timated directly from evidences Steel production can be the location and capacity of steel mills or indirectly frog dente of the manpower employed and of the iron ore:' 11 SECRET MORI/HRP THIS PAGE SECRET 9 or alloy metals or other inputs available, from the total output of all the products made with steel, or from the capacities of transportation facilities serving the steel industry. The lack of direct evidence on some of the things that we most want to know, as revealed in the results of our inventory of ignorance, emphasizes the very great importance of giving priority to the interrelations of the parts of the economy. Thus the third task of economic intelligence, to explain all the complex ways in which resources are in fact allocated to various uses, is peculiar- lv essential to building a consistent picture of the Soviet economy. A third fact that shapes our methods is that technology and the laws of nature are no respecters of iron curtains. The Soviets do many things differently from the way in which we do them, but in many other things they have no choice but to follow the only industrial technique that exists. Thus the electrolytic process which produces sodium hydroxide and chlorine inevitably produces them in the same ratio in the USSR as in the United States. We can learn many of the technical limitations on what they are able to do from a study of US industrial practices. But this must be done with care, since we know that in some cases the Soviets appear to be incapable of applying our techniques even where they know about them, whereas in other cases they have devised superior methods. Nevertheless, with appropriate caution, useful first approximations can be reached by the comparative method. One implication of this for research plans is that there must br present in our work a much heavier dose of technical and rngineering thinking than is customary in economic studies. A characteristic which has advantages and disadvantages it that prices, markets, and money flows, the stock in trade o! much economic analysis, have limited meaning in the USSR. We are spared the uncertainties of the capitalist business cycle, and monetary dislocations are of little significance. On the other hand, we are largely denied the benefits of money as a rrmmmon measure of otherwise incommensurable activities. 14ast of our thinking must be not in terms of rubles but of tons P:d bushels and bales, of numbers of machines of innumerable MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 10 SECRET of car-miles, kilowatts per hour, and the ds t ki n differen , To add all these things up to an index of capabilities, we m k of n o s' t s as concoct our own common measuring rod, a complexity. On the negative side is the obvious fact that informati ited inch li m currently coming out of the Soviet Bloc is very t ? his does no ted. Raall our knowledge is inevitably correspondingly limit+hp Rath, es do t e ng economic cha deal more ab' tion on earlier periods is a good and informa dant. Piecing this together with what we^arengetting f1 e ing .. exercising som known about the unknown (through the MiQq ec d .. -a economy), an formation through the channels available to. f i n pieces o ut together a surprisingly reliable ;p to ibl p e it is poss ture. What the scarcity of current informationnmeea s s nim ndo n are co that we ?e` - -o but rather that to find out what we need^to^know takes ng s of pa h our many more than would interpretation, and of fitting and adjusting a ei Thcum om e d con y.} p necessary in the study of an open of r sion i _ - tion of his wu~ru time required which were compiled by the various di during the course of the inventory- racteristic of the Soviet problem is that _i, nal a d difficulties of collecting information, t s an the cos of more time and thought must be devoted to Bete+rmining l rrriv.=?? --__ .. pieces of additiona we could secure them. This point should not be overe r disc/ t y o sized. As the inven to give the answers that we need about a good many sub MIS ashington. `J4T i l n e availab is believed to be largely m ! cases, what is needed is principally much mu-no e hnwev of a rather row-grain. - collection appears to be the only way of filling in certain? -nlrl nnrTn y p in d t g w.. y u gaps. III s expected to' for much more information than one expo MORI/HRP THIS PAGE SECRET 11 then sort out the useful parts when it came. When the cost of information in money and lives is high, however, much more careful consideration must be given to which pieces of informa- tion are the vital ones. One of the principal responsibilities of ORR is to give this kind of guidance to the information collecting agencies. The considerations set forth in this introduction do not determine the details of our research program or of our method of tackling it, but they do provide a framework of ideas within which the research program may be carried forward. The next task is to spell out method and content somewhat more precisely. The dilemma of the clamorous customer versus the basic study The central question of how we should allocate our time has already been referred to. The problems to whose solution we are asked to contribute are very urgent. Events will not wait for the orderly, patient, exhaustive research which alone Can give satisfactory answers to these problems. If we were to devote ourselves exclusively to amassing all the facts we nerd. we would have to tell harried policy-makers that we could be glad to advise them-beginning in about 2 years. We neither should nor can stay in an ivory tower that long. Earn if it were possible to devote ourselves exclusively to exhaustive and encyclopedic studies for the next 24 months, t is highly likely that at the end of that period many of the problems that we would be asked to help with would have changed so that our results would no longer be particularly applicable. On the other hand, if we succumb completely to the very pressure upon us to answer all current requests for prompt :r,'ormation, we will never have any information better than Ui- slim fragments that we can now supply. Thus our dilemma it. in a sense, whether to be encyclopedic and irrelevant or ;irrational and incompetent. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Clearly the only tolerable solution is a compromise betty" these two extremes. We must try to answer the most im tant of the problems put to us from day to day as quickly as competently as possible. But we must reserve a major of our energies for improving the foundation of knowl from which better quick answers can be given. The necessity for this compromise has two further impli tions. The first is that it is possible to pursue this twof objective only if we have a certain minimum of resear A resources substantially larger than that which the US Gove ment has allocated to these problems in the past. The other implication of our compromise is that since cannot hope to have enough resources fully to exploit all available information about the USSR, we must be very that we use our scarce research resources to fill in those ar of our ignorance which most seriously limit our estima ability. We must concentrate our scarce manpower on fin out those things that the US Government needs to know m' The identification of these priority areas is one of the n~ puzzling problems facing intelligence. How do we determine basic research priorities? The most seductive answer to this question is contain what we may call the "bottleneck fallacy." Since econo, cold or hot, was first thought of, economists warfare , sought for the bottleneck, the single critical item, the facility without which the enemy's military economy wo collapse. The history of the search for such bottlenecks< record of failure, confirming the economist's faith, that, g ` a little time resources are highly substitutable one for ano I ki This does not mean that economic warfare is bound t ineffective, On the contrary, the very fact that resources, uauu interchangeable means that to deny an enemy any reso is to weaken directly or indirectly his military potentiaL>,! is particularly true in an economy which, like the Soviet economic activity recognized by the Kremlin as not esig' MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 to these goals would have been abandoned long since. Thus wherever we make an economic attack upon the USSR, it is likely to hurt. But it is a delusion to expect that a limited attack upon a small segment of the Soviet economy will cripple Soviet strength. It is not the capacity of a particular facility or the availability of a particular commodity which ultimately limits the capabilities of the Soviets so much as their total resources and their ability to organize them effectively. This does not mean that all things are equally important. The selection of the more critical commodities and industries is one way of cutting the problem down to size. But when one has done all the pruning possible, the number of critical sectors of the economy remains too great to tackle them all exhaustively at once. A second method of determining priorities for research is to see what basic research would be most relevant to the problems to which we are being asked to give current answers now. The dangers in this problem-approach to priorities are obvious. It leads one always to concentrate one's research on yesterday's rather than on tomorrow's problems. Basic research, by definition, takes time. The problems which may tx~ urgent when the basic research that we start today is finished cannot be clearly foreseen and are almost certain to tx. different from those which are plaguing us now. Furthermore, any attempt to list even the most urgent of the problems facing us at the moment reveals how many there zre and how much of the total world economic picture is rele- vant to their solution. As part of our study of foreign economic intelligence for the National Security Council, the Central Intelligence Agency attempted to outline the requirements for such intelligence in terms of current problems. A very incomplete sample yielded a list of 42 top priority problems; u ne of them as broad as t USSR he totalmilitary potential of the R. Again, we cannot wholly discard this criterion We mu t s . "Y to foresee tomorrow's problems and guide our research accordingly. There are some aspects of the Soviet economy MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 14 SECRET which we can take the risk of neglecting. But we must do mewhat against ti broad enough job to hedge ourselves so errors in our own forecasting. is to take some aspect of the study lit y A third possibi each commodity and concentrate on that aspect alone for e could take so _ commodities across the board. Thus on ic Commodity Study used B as section of the Outline for a the preparation of the inventory and fill in that section A _ __ 4---o ,n,t;l later. One coil - in l g -- - ea every item 111s , ies of ORR to the study of require n devote the entire energ io ; production for example, or to techniques and methods of or to levels dustry h i , n to the organization and plans for eac YY This principle of selection is almost certain to be unsa ers to most of the questi+ factory by itself, since the answ which policy makers are going to ask involve putting togeth - 1W onc t at the a all of the parts of a basic study to ge nf the balsa iti i l an estimate of caps uirements to achieve whatever d re q between supplies an lans of the Soviet rulers. An estimate be the goals and p vulnerabilities involves a knowledge of the availability mate ofd --A -Ion o L . ~- rials at prese~it, pr goals and plans would be affected if that availability went int far below requirements. If be cut by our action to a po information at drawn l , y design of a basic study is proper ired to arrive at concluq all the parts of that study is requ if satisfactory el ti y r and no single part can be left out en ation of each of these methods of dete ti g The inves h time leads us back to the un< our researc priorities on able conclusion with which we started -namely, tha f most of the Da i ' o s encyclopedic and exhaustive analys in which we can the only wa i s the whole ecuriom y wers to the questions th sound and authoritative ans being asked. But we have already determined that we d g r have the time or the resources end. iHo to beg ng systematic basic studies from g dilemma? can we resolve this puzzling SECRET MORI/HRP THIS PAGE The answer is suggested by looking at the present state of our knowledge. What we have just proved is that we need to know something about most aspects of most sectors of the Soviet economy to make a sensible estimate of capabilities, vulnerabilities, or intentions. But we have not proved that we must know everything about every aspect. What we already know permits us to set certain outer limits to the area of the possible. We know the Soviet Union is at least capable of certain minimum actions, and we can set certain ceilings on what they are at most capable of. Our problem is to bring the "at least" and the "at most" closer and closer together. This calls for a research program guided by what we may call the Method of Successive Approximations. The Method of Successive Approximations The first step in the Method of Successive Approximations is to lay out in general terms the specifications of what you would like to know. What is the list of all the significant industries, commodities, and services which should be studied, anti what are the principal problems about them which we would like to solve? This was the first assignment in our inventory and resulted in the outlines produced as a guide to it. The second step is to see how much of the outline you can fU in and with what degree of precision. This will reveal that our information about some aspects of each of our problems better than our information about other aspects. It may not be very good. The best information that we possess may rave a very wide margin of error, but other parts of our outline will be still weaker. Our inventory was designed to bring us t i ough this second state - to tell us what we know and what do not know about each of our major problems with respect to thv USSR. It has revealed what it was intended to show- 4Wneiv. that our ignorance of certain important matters IS much greater than our ignorance of others. Tl1e third stage of our Method of Successive Approximations 11 to concentrate our most earnest efforts for a brief period Ci the important parts of our problem which we know least MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 16 SECRET This does not mean that we seek authoritative or t abou . answers in these areas of ignorance but merely that we foe hntil - on tem u to or somewhat better than our knowledge of the other pa of the picture. we have been working in this manner on weak spot Wh en for a period of 2 or 3 or 4 months, we must stand off and talc ot~ n to the ti l t ~ o a another look at where we are then in re The weak _ li e ne. "r - -- UUt else, or we may have gone far enough with them so the will the th ' y em, although we still do not know much about 1-+ a.nrlPnra s this o our second over-an look reveal tackle whatever other sectors of our problem are now tl1 a ain -- n g ot weaaw~, out everything about them, but only that we are going to wo tter re uir q . on them until our ignorance of some other ma 1;+4 i ng know more pressing attention. In this business, m n a ,7 about a great knowing everything about a very few things and nothing abo .,,.a. of iannran ach substantia others. +. tensive enough and substantial enough to pe i b n e must ress toward solutions and not merely l prog make rea us to hold our own. On the other hand, it must not be pursu+ areas th er with such perfectionist zeal that we neglect o i ous. which our ignorance may be only slightly less ser In summary, the Method of Successive Approximations 44- ? tarn - VU1ves a repeated -/ --- and several months' production followed by another in the light both of progress and of changes in the ch of the problems to be solved. Problems in applying the Method In attempting to apply the Method of Successive Appra whir i se tions, certain common problems and difficulties ar A particularly bothersome problem is that the things; W hich it is i ngs w we know least about, and thus the th MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 important to study, are likely to be the things on which we have least information. In general, we know more about rates of production of important commodities and products in the Soviet Union than we do about patterns of distribution of those products. This is partly because much more evidence is available on rates of production. The temptation is to study the material that we have and draw such generalizations from it as it seems to contain. In terms of getting answers to our vital problems, however, we cannot permit the available evidence to dictate the nature of our inquiry too completely. Several weeks spent searching for every possible way to button down an illusive fact by in;enious reasoning from other related facts, by working out limits on what its magnitude could possibly be from what we know about other parts of the economy, or by laying on collec- tion requirements may be worth many times the same amount time devoted to extracting, setting down, and presenting all the facts that may happen to be in a given body of documents. Both methods must be employed. Until we have systemati- cally examined the available material, we do not know what can be got out of it. But the material available was not (:rsigned to answer our questions, and it must be made to be nm servant of our investigation and not its master. An irritating feature of the Method of Successive Approxi- mations is that it may well involve us in going over the same material several times in search of the answers to a series of different questions. This repetition is unfortunate and can br avoided to some extent by investing some time in indexing and abstracting. If, however, we examine exhaustively all the material available to us for every implication that it contains the first time we study it, we will not complete our investigation ?'(3 many, many months. It is unfortunate that research by the Method of Successive Approximations involves some waste And some repetition, but it is better than being able to produce n, answers until 1954.* t.ditors Note: It is worth reminding the reader that this paper was I,-,f-pared in 1951. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 The natural instinct of the researcher who has plenty of tip is to follow the logical process of trying to build up a pictti of a whole sector of the economy by first getting an idea of ea of its smaller component parts. Thus the logical way to es mate the value of resources used in chemical production is find out what resources are used in the production of each, the many different kinds of chemicals. Again this logical involves breaking each particular chemical into the quantiti produced in each specific plant. This suggests that the f! step in answering the over-all question is to try to identify the physical producing facilities and their capacities and ra of operation. In many cases, however, a first approximate to the aggregate figure can be achieved by short cuts whi avoid the necessity of knowing what in detail it is made up Thus one can start, for example, with total resources engag in chemical production in the United States, or in the t economy of Nazi Germany, as a proportion of total resoun One can then consider known respects in which the proport in the USSR must deviate from these examples. Soap is i in the USSR, and every household does not have its DDT sp] Such estimates of the whole before you know the parts usuu have wide margins of error, but when current problems , pressing, they are frequently better than nothing at all Finally, for this Method to be effective, it should ideallj applied not simply to ORR's schedule of research produc but to that of the US Government as a whole. Our delinea' of areas of ignorance should be on a government-wide lx{ and our production to remedy these weaknesses should planned in collaboration with other agencies so that w not all concentrate on the same gaps at once. As the coo integrated with our production so that the Government) whole may approach more rapidly an adequate understan of the Soviet economy. SECRET 19 ECONOMIC INTELLIGENCE by Paul W. Howerton EDrrORS NOTE: This article is based on talks given by Mr. Howerton at the Industrial College of the Armed Forces in 1955 and 1956. % We are grateful to the Commandant of the College for making the transcripts available to us. T HE first order of business is to identify the problem of economic intelligence. It is a problem very like that of the college economics professor in the classic story about um examination papers that, year after year, ask the same questions. The punch-line hardly needs repeating: "in eco- ntnuics. we never change the questions, only the answers." This is the problem of economic intelligence. We in the !ntclligence profession have the questions, which remain rea- :.0uiabiy constant. It is the answers we have to change. Through a process of refinement, through successive approxi- mations, we hope to approach the true picture of the outlook ;u the economic sector of the various nations we are called on t+) study. Perhaps the best way to treat the subject of economic intelli- grnce is to borrow the journalistic breakdown into the five 's and the H: "who," "when," "why," "what," "where," and how-." The first question is what - what is economic intelli- I:rnce? It is the appraisal of the capability of a nation to '. ipi ort a war. This is, to be sure, a simplified definition, but t covers almost every important aspect of the activity. rile "Why" of Economic Intelligence The second question is why - why do we prepare economic Intelligence? We prepare it because we now recognize that MORI/HRP THIS PAGE MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 20 SECRET many of the operations undertaken during World War II wer to i th y ng not successful, or were unnecessarily delayed, ow f sound is in lack o speech made by General George C. Marshall on 9 Septembe, id : 1939, just a week after the war started. He sa The true philosophy of the maximum war effort of a, supply power as the nation can support. I suspect thi For some years now she has been devoting ov outlined . 50 per cent of the productive effort of her country, inclu ing men, plants, and materials, for the preparation of wa% r and now actual war. So it follows that she is now gea up to her maximum effort. that she was not able however tant to note , , It is impor reach this status overnight. It has taken her some fa ' or five years of intensive effort to develop the raw-ma acity to support her maximum effort. It is now g ca p erally accepted as a fact that it requires far more time' than it does to convert civilian manpower into soldiers This man was Chief of Staff of the US Army. He was alle be the best informed man in the country on the capabi t o of the potential enemy, and he said that Germany was th" +? St Th ra e in September 1939, geared to its maximum effort. t th a Bombing Survey conducted after the war indicated 1939 to 1944, in the fields of explosives, tanks, and air of the German economy was two to three times. The Bri .1-IL with a 200-year tradition of intelligence research behind said at the end of each war-year, "Germany has now i her peak." And during every successive year, that pe surpassed. This, then, illustrates the why of organized economic in Marshal Montgomery have listed the essentials for na MORI/HRP THIS PAGE security, based on their experience. Montgomery, in August 1947, said he believed these essentials were: 1. Strong national character. 2. Great development of scientific and industrial research. 3. Powerful and well-disciplined industrial power. 4. A regular army. 5. Preparedness. Three of these five essentials are economic intelligence targets: -great development of scientific and industrial research" (we have to know what intentions and capabilities may be for the future), "powerful and well-disciplined industrial power," and -preparedness" (both of these fall into the category of eco- nomic intelligence). Economic intelligence is, in sum, the appraisal of the capa- bility of a nation to support a war, also an estimate of its vulnerabilities and of its intentions. Economic intelligence is, Indeed, probably the best long-range indicator we have of Intentions. On the vulnerability side, the intelligence com- u:unity must have, necessarily, a consideration of exploitable ulnerabilities - a vulnerability is unimportant unless it can t?? exploited. "When," "Where," and "Who" When is economic intelligence produced? It is produced or both current and future use. The field of economics, broad. ac it is, requires an intensive study, sector by sector, in any f i? en country to determine the aggregate of its economic ;-trntial. Furthermore, economic intelligence depreciates at a constant rate of, roughly, 20 per cent a year. At the end of } cars' time, a piece of economic intelligence developed from date Published this year ll w, rtu only 35 yal wui be woiou Oruy a per cellt of its 1' -sent value. The intelligence community is charged, then, with keeping `urrcnt on economic developments within the countries under `tu(ly. These efforts are by no means confined to the study MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 22 SECRET of the economies of the Soviet-dominated world. It is equal important that we be equipped to understand the capabilitu of our friends and alleged friends. There is, for example, u: _-, ably no country more closely associated with the US in tl protection of North America than Canada. There is probabl no closer working relationship between any two nations in tj world. And yet we produce intelligence on Canada and o facilities for war. Where is this economic intelligence prepared? part of it prepared in CIA. Part, in the Department of State. The tary contributes. In National Security Council Directive N1 15, which has been interpreted by the Director of CIA as DC1 15/1, responsibility for economic intelligence research is all Bated to the various agencies. The Department of State d . with broad-gauge economic policy problems. CIA confines self to the Soviet Bloc and the peripheral areas which contribute to Soviet capabilities. The military compon contribute all the military-economic intelligence that is necessary to the proper understanding of the capabilities intentions of a potential enemy or friend. The interpretati, placed on the happenings of the day are contributed the-board, by all people who are competent to make such tributions. Consequently, no single organization can indeed, does) operate in vacuo to produce economic intellige; It i s far too important a subject to trust to a single or tion or a single individual. Techniques and Methods of Economic Intelligence Produ The next question is the one I will treat at greatest 1 how is economic intelligence produced? The chart (Economy of the USSR) * purports to analyze the economy of the USSR and most of the illustrations 3- use are drawn from studies of the USSR. The appiicatia the techniques. and methods discussed, however, is as b: as the subject matter of economic intelligence. I will * This chart was devised by my good friend, Bill Tidwell of Author's Note. 475 ?t MORI/HRP THIS PAGE METHODS OF DETERMINING THE ANSWERS - Statistics Factory Markings Sovmat Input-Output Tables- Gross National Product Index of Industrial Production Population Curve Index of Standard of Living SOURCES OF DATA Attache and Embassy Records Publications FBID Defectors Returned PW Commercial Contacts Travel Folder Program US Government Files Covert Sources Intelligence Services of Friendly Governments MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78T03194A000100010001-2 the ues- methods that avea been developed for answering makers and telli ence community by policy is put to the drawn Upon- tile sources of information . The chart, furthermore, breaks down economic analysis is into major subquestions. The first is that of qualitative analysis; the second and third deal with and the ::alysis; organization of the economy, fourth deals with the ora m th of the economy. subquestion, with the grow quantitative anal number of techniques are available to q u liih d by the First of all, there are the statithe USSR, stics published the statistics untry in question. In the casual cations discussed below, by and large and with the q intelligence agencies have carefully d alyzed these external , both for their internal consistency he Soviet can A;ticsics nce on the operations of the countries within the SThe consistency of components within an aggregate c luc. gainst announcements of future chancres in isily be checked against of individual compo well as changes e aggregate itself as The consistency of data on all levels, including and the :. ates of changes in the physical productive capacity outputs within the Soviet Bloc, has been verified R ~n;modity or a sufficient number of cases to convince us that the ~- in eneral, to distort their published sians are not attempting, 9 statistics. examples of precisely the Having said this, let me give a few opposite - cases where the Russians understand proper yed the where interpretation is necessary statistical analyses made by the Soviet Central Statistical Bu- reau. A Soviet rubber-produing plant turns out both rubber tires and rubber heels. An announcement came out of this plant saying that the goal for tires had been missed by 50 per cent but that the goal for heels hsda es meant dthat t e over- cent - which, according to the loo per cent! all production goal was met by Krokodil. Another example comes from the humor magazine, A cartoon appeared in this journal, some time back, which ger of a machine tractor station standing on showed the manager MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78T03194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 24 SECRET the porch sending off a deputy to the local commissar with the admonition: "Don't forget to tell him that half the plan is 100 per cent fulfilled." All of which demonstrates that Soviet statistics need care. ful analysis. They cannot be accepted completely on face value. But by such analysis, and by careful review of the aggregates that we are able from time to time to accumulate, we have come to the conclusion that the statistics are, by and large, valid. Input Analysis A second tool of quantitative analysis is the method of in- puts. There are certain basic relations, that is to say, that are constant throughout a given industry. For example, the floor space in an aircraft plant is proportional to the number of airplanes it can produce. This relationship has been checked out in a number of aircraft companies in the US and in friendly countries and found to be valid. Other methods have been developed to relate seemingly unrelated commodities - com- modities which seem to have a mutual control over one another. An example is steel and rubber. The Joint Intelligence Bureau in London developed this factor: the amount of steel produced in a given country is directly proportional to the amount of rubber consumed. This factor has been tested in the US, France, and Italy and found to be valid. These are w exam- ples of how factors can be developed so that, given a bit information collected by an observer in the USSR on some plant or industry, one can by deduction determine the approxi- mate production capacity of that plant or industry. Markings Analysis In intelligence, as in laboratory research generally, we try to verify our results by using a number of different analytic methods. One of the most useful of these methods is that of factory markings analysis - next item on the list of tools of quantitative analysis. Factory markings are those trade marks, inspectors' marks, or other stampings, that appear on most any finished product. These markings are unique a given plant or even for a given department or inspector for within a plant. Factory markings analysis might be called the Bertillon system for the identification of products and producers. Even though the field is in its infancy and was only devel- oped during World War II, some examples drawn from wartime experience demonstrate its enormous possibilities. The ver- age monthly production of tanks in Germany in the period th- hadintelligence 140-1942 was estimated, using conventional analyzed ethe ods, at 1550. The markings people, markings on captured tanks, set the figure at 327. When the Speer Ministry files were captured, the true figure was found to be 342 - 327 (markings analysis) against 342 (true figure) against 1550 (conventional analysis). During 1942 the con- ventional estimate of German truck production was 2 8000,0 00;. the markings estimate, 97,000; the Speer Mi Ministry figure, tires was The 1943 average German monthly production markings estimated by conventional methods at 1,250,000; by analysis, 175,000; the actual figure, 186,000. It is, of course, jlist as bad to overestimate production as it is to underestimate it. It has been said that the bof Europe was intelligence and, unnecessarily delayed a year especially, bad economic intelligence. Modern machine methods handle the raw data of markings analysis in the Joint Markings Center maintained by CIA in collaboration with the Army, Navy, and Air Force. Markings analysis is going to be one of the potent techniques of economic intelligence in the future. Its method is that of statistical analysis; and, consequently, the larger the sample, the more accurate will be the conclusion. With five MIG's available to US intelligence, markings analysis has produced an estimated monthly production to within one plane of the figure arrived at through other intelligence methods. Just to illustrate the dimensions of the markings effort, by the way, there are 36,000 distinctive markings on a MIG, of which 3,600 are significant for markings analysis. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE MORI/HRP THIS PAGE Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Approved For Release 2007/10/23: CIA-RDP78TO3194A000100010001-2 Input-Output Analysis A system of input-output analysis - or, inter-sectoral anah; ysis - is useful for quantitative estimation, because it sho*g the changes that can occur within an economy for any given stimulus. Take, for example, an input-output matrix for the Soviet petroleum industry (plotting products on the vertical, side and industry on the horizontal) : the agricultural sector within the USSR uses 23 per cent of total petroleum output; energy production uses 12 per cent; manufacturing, 11 per cent; transportation, 24 per cent; household uses, nine per cent; and the military, eight per cent. This adds up to 87 per cent. The other 13 per cent is that bit of petroleum the Russians have been using for barter with the West for scarce and necessary machine tools. input-output on electric power is another useful illustration of this technique of analysis. In their current plan, the Rus- sians hope to have 170 billion kilowatt hours of electricity production a year, which would require 83 million tons of coal to produce. For each kwh, 1.2 pounds of coal are required. If the USSR decides it is going to have, say, more aluminum and will therefore have to increase its power requirement to 200 billion kwh, 95 million tons of coal will also be required. This new coal requirement of 12 million tons must now come from new mining activity or must be reallocated within the present consumption pattern. As one further example of input-output analysis, consider a changeover in a given Soviet oblast from horse-drawn agricul- tural equipment to tractors. This sounds, at first, like a simple transformation; but, to increase requirements for tractors means much more than just an increase in tractor production; it means, as well, an increase in steel production, in electric power production, and in electronic control; and it means an increased demand for management and skilled labor. The reduced requirement for horses, on the other hand, will mean among other things a larger food supply for the people. It is just this sort of complex economic interrelationship that input- output analysis can help to clarify. MORI/HRP THIS PAGE In sum, the development of a matrix of input-output will